Skip to main content
Log in

Analysis of the determinants of fertility decline in the Czech Republic

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we analyze the decline in the total fertility rate (TFR) in the Czech Republic during the economic transition. To identify transition-specific features of this decline, we estimate a Heckman–Walker multistate model of the birth process using data from the 1998 Family and Fertility Survey. We find that the negative effect of transition on TFR is mostly driven by a sharply increased influence of higher education, limited ability to combine employment with childbearing and lack of adequate childcare facilities. We also detect a significant role of the increased use of contraception, motivated by both economic and demographic reasons.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For richer summary statistics calculating age- and cohort-specific fertility rates, refer to Billari and Kohler (2002). An overview of tempo-adjusted Bongaarts–Feeney rates can be found in Sobotka (2001).

  2. To avoid measurement error bias in the first cohort, we consider only those females who have completed their education. This simultaneously reduces the efficiency loss due to censoring.

  3. There are also some questions about the reasons for own fertility decisions, but very high nonresponse rates render these data useless.

  4. This assumption is particularly appropriate in our case since we do not have income data, and individuals are surely heterogeneous with respect to income.

  5. Identification of θ requires setting one of its elements to zero. Alternatively, one can suppress intercept term in x (see Heckman and Singer 1982, p.64).

  6. Keep in mind, though, that the effect of employment intensity is still negative and significantly contributes to the delay of first birth as described by Happel et al. (1984).

  7. This finding is more of a demographic nature and is quite similar to the results of Bonneuil (1997) on the dependence between fertility and urbanization. Analyzing cointegrating relationships between fertility and urbanization in France, Bonneuil (1997) demonstrates that with the fall of fertility rates, the positive effect of urbanization on birth postponement disappears.

  8. We also ran the model for the youngest cohort without the belief variables to see whether this would change the other covariates (particularly the employment and education variables). It has very little impact on them, so that the results for these variables are robust to inclusion or exclusion of the belief variables.

  9. Apart from purely economic reasons, the significant effect of the increased use of contraception may also have behavioral and demographic roots (see Bonneuil 1997).

References

  • Barmby T, Cigno A (1990) A sequential probability model of fertility patterns. J Popul Econ 3(1):31–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billari F, Kohler H-P (2002) Patterns of lowest-low fertility in Europe. Max Plank Institute for Demographic Research, Working Paper No. 2002-040, Koln

  • Burcin B, Kučera T (2000) Changes in fertility and mortality in the Czech Republic: an attempt of regional demographic analysis. In: Kuera T et al (eds) New demographic faces of Europe. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg New York, pp 371–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonneuil N (1997) Transformation of the French demographic landscape 1806–1906. Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cigno A (1991) Economics of the family. Clarendon, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Covas F, Santos Silva J (2000) A modified hurdle model for completed fertility. J Popul Econ 13(2):173–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • del Boca D (2002) The effect of child care and part time opportunities on participation and fertility decisions in Italy. J Popul Econ 15(3):549–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dempster A, Laird N, Rubin D (1977) Maximum likelihood from incomplete data via EM algorithm. J R Stat Soc Ser B 39(1):1–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Famoye F, Wang W (1997) Modeling household fertility decisions with generalized poisson regression. J Popul Econ 10(3):273–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson S (2001) Optimal age of motherhood. Theoretical and empirical considerations on postponement of maternity in Europe. J Popul Econ 14(1):225–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson S, Wetzels C (2000) Optimal age at first birth: Germany, Great Britain, The Netherlands and Sweden. In: Gustafsson S, Meulders D (eds) Gender and the labour market. Econometric evidence of obstacles to achieving gender inequality. MacMillan, London, pp 188–209

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustafsson S, Kenjoh E, Wetzels C (2001) A new crisis in European populations. Do modern family policies help? In: Pieters D (ed) Confidence and changes: managing social protection in the new millennium. Kluwer, The Hague, pp 119–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Happel S, Hill J, Low S (1984) An economic analysis of the timing of childbirth. Popul Stud 38(2):299–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Singer B (1982) The identification problem in econometric models for longitudinal data. In: Hildenbrand W (ed) Advances in econometrics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 39–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Singer B (1984) A method of minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models for duration data. Econometrica 52(2):271–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Walker J (1987) Using goodness of fit and other criteria to choose among competing duration models: a case study of Hutterite data. Sociol Method 17:247–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Walker J (1990a) The relationship between wages and income and the timing and spacing of births: evidence form Swedish longitudinal data. Econometrica 58(6):1411–1441

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J, Walker J (1990b) The third birth in Sweden. J Popul Econ 3(4):235–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotz V, Klerman J, Willis R (1997) The economics of fertility in developed countries. In: Rosenzweig A, Stark O (eds) Handbook of population and family economics, vol 1A. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 275–347

    Google Scholar 

  • Kantorová V (2003) Education and entry into motherhood: the Czech Republic during state-socialism and the transition period. Max Plank Institute for Demographic Research, Working paper No. 2003–037, Köln

  • Klasen S (1993) Human development and women's lives in a restructured eastern block: lessons from the developing world. In: Schipke A, Taylor A (eds) The economics of transformation: theory and practise in the new market economies. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg New York, pp 253–294

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster T (1990) The econometric analysis of transition data. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Mašková M, Stašová L (2000) Population development in the Czech Republic in the 1990s. In: Kuera T et al (eds) New demographic faces of Europe. Springer, Berlin Heidelberg New York, pp 88–102

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobotka T (2001) Ten years of rapid fertility changes in European post-communist countries: evidence and interpretation. Working paper, University of Groningen, Groningen

  • Sobotka T (2004) Is lowest-low fertility in Europe explained by the postponement of childbearing. Popul Dev Rev 30(2):195–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • UNECE (2003) Family and fertility surveys. Population activities unit. URL: http://www.unece.org/ead/pau/ffs

  • White H (1982) Maximum likelihood estimation of misspecified modes. Econometrica 50(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Michael Grimm, Siv Gustafsson, and the participants of ESPE 2004 and EEA 2005. Comments of an anonymous referee were especially useful. Funding from the German Science Foundation (DFG) within SFB 386: “Statistical Analysis of Discrete Structures” is greatly acknowledge.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrey Launov.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Allesandro Cigno

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Direction of the effect and marginal effects

Waiting time

First, consider the effect of the covariates on Weibull hazard function

$$h{\left( {t\left| {\theta _{i} } \right.} \right)} = \gamma {\left( {\exp {\left\{ {x\beta + \theta _{i} } \right\}}} \right)}^{\gamma } t^{{1 - \gamma }} $$

Since the first derivative with respect to x β is positive, the sign of the effect will always be equal to the sign of the estimated parameter. For instance, a positive estimated coefficient conveys that an increase in x leads to an increase in the hazard of having a child and, hence, to a reduction in the waiting time between births.

To compute the size of the effect, consider the expected value of a Weibull-distributed random variable

$$E{\left( {T\left| \phi \right.{\left( x \right)}} \right)} = \phi {\left( x \right)}^{{ - 1}} \Gamma {\left( {1 + \gamma ^{{ - 1}} } \right)},$$

where in our case, ϕ(x)=exp {x β+θ i }. In the presence of unobserved heterogeneity, this expectation modifies to

$$E{\left( {Tx,\theta } \right)} = {\sum\limits_i {\frac{{\pi _{i} }}{{\exp {\left\{ {x\beta + \theta _{i} } \right\}}}}} }\Gamma {\left( {1 + \gamma ^{{ - 1}} } \right)}.$$

Taking the first derivative of E(Tx,θ) with respect to x, we get

$$\frac{{\partial E{\left( {T\left| {x,\theta } \right.} \right)}}}{{\partial x}} = {\sum\limits_i { - \frac{{\pi _{i} \Gamma {\left( {1 + \gamma ^{{ - 1}} } \right)}}}{{\exp {\left\{ {x\beta + \theta _{i} } \right\}}}}} }\beta .$$
(A1)

As covariates enter E(T x,θ) nonlinearly, the marginal effect at the different levels of one and the same variable will not be the same (e.g., an additional year of schooling for a person with university education will cause a change in waiting time different from that caused by an additional year for a person with only secondary school education). To ensure correct inference, the marginal effects must be calculated for all possible levels of the explanatory variables.

Quit probabilities

Identical inference can be made about changes in quit probabilities. With parameterization

$$p = {\left( {1 + \exp {\left\{ { - x\omega } \right\}}} \right)}^{{ - 1}} ,$$

an increase in the value of the variable will cause an increase in probability of quitting after the realized birth, provided that the corresponding parameter is positive. The marginal effect of the covariates on the expected quit probabilities is

$$\frac{{\partial E{\left( {Px} \right)}}}{{\partial x}} = \frac{{\exp {\left\{ { - x\omega } \right\}}}}{{{\left( {1 + \exp {\left\{ { - x\omega } \right\}}} \right)}^{2} }}\omega .$$

.

Table A1 Estimated coefficients with parameterized quit probabilities: first birth cohort (born 1972–1982)
Table A2 Estimated coefficients with parameterized quit probabilities: second birth cohort (born 1963–1971)
Table A3 Estimated coefficients with parameterized quit probabilities: third birth cohort (born 1954–1962)
Table A4 Test of no increase in the negative effect on timing of births
Table A5 Test of no increase in the negative effect on exit from childbearing

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Klasen, S., Launov, A. Analysis of the determinants of fertility decline in the Czech Republic. J Popul Econ 19, 25–54 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0030-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-005-0030-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation