Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Can adult education delay retirement from the labour market?

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We examine whether adult education delays retirement to potentially increase labour force participation among the elderly, a mechanism suggested in the OECD strategy for “active ageing” and the “Lisbon strategy” of the EU. Using register data from Sweden, we analyse transcripts from adult education for the period 1979–2004 and annual earnings 1982–2004. We match samples of treated individuals, in adult education 1986–1989, and untreated on the propensity score. The timing of exit from the workforce is assessed by non-parametric estimation of survival rates in the labour force. The results indicate no effects of adult education on the timing of retirement.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. E.g., interest rate is below market price and required repayments never exceed 4% of earnings.

  2. Mixed results presented in Albrecht et al. (2004) and Ekström (2003) are reconciled in Stenberg (2009).

  3. In each period, an individual is assumed to compare the expected utility from immediate retirement with the utility from retiring at a future date. Workers remain in the labour force as long as the option value of work (alternately referred to as the option value of delayed retirement) is positive.

  4. However, Bartel and Sicherman (1993) find that workers in industries with high rates of technological change retire later to recoup the returns on late investments in on-the-job-training; nevertheless, a technological shock would (ceteris paribus) induce workers to retire sooner because of increased costs for re-training.

  5. On-the-job-training typically involves high-skilled individuals (Brunello 2003; Arulampalam et al. 2004).

  6. The policy until the mid-1990s was that in order not to generate perverse incentives, formal education was not offered as an active labour market program.

  7. Migration to another regional labour market is a very uncommon event in these age cohorts (Eliasson and Westerlund 2009).

  8. The average among untreated individuals is 8.5 credits. In the empirical section, the mean among matched comparisons never exceeds 20 credits (i.e. about 10 days).

  9. p it is the sum of part-time pensions, retirement (i.e. old-age) pensions, national supplementary pensions (ATP), and early-retirement pensions, including sickness pensions and various occupational pensions.

  10. Until 2004, the last year of observation, the proportion of censored individuals was below 4.5%.

  11. The macroeconomic background made the probability of retirement higher during the economic downturn at the beginning of the 1990s, but note that the regime under which individuals retire is the same for the treated and the untreated at different points in time.

  12. Blöndahl and Scarpetta (1999) estimate the average age of transition to inactivity in 1995. For Sweden, this was found to be 63 for males and 62 for females. The corresponding figures for the US were 64 and 62 years of age, and for Germany, they were 61 for males and 58 for females. Labour force participation and employment rates among 55–64 year olds are higher in Sweden than the OECD average. See also Eklöf and Hallberg (2004, 2010) and Karlström et al. (2004).

  13. We match on the propensity score, i.e. the probability of entering AE conditional on the covariates; see Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983) for a theoretical justification. Matching all covariates may be difficult due to “the curse of dimensionality.” That is, finding close matches on many dimensions is not possible.

  14. The stable unit treatment value assumption (SUTVA) is standard in the program evaluation literature. In a theoretical contribution, Albrecht et al. (2009) show that a large AE sector is detrimental for those who remain low skilled, but that general equilibrium effects and externalities would enhance economic growth in general. Assumption (A) would in that case be violated and the returns to AE overstated.

  15. Covariates are here variables assumed not to be affected by treatment and typically measured before treatment. Conditioning the analysis on variables which are affected by treatment will bias the analysis, as it removes indirect effects which work through such covariates.

  16. As mentioned in Section 2, censoring is associated with death, migration abroad and, for the comparison group, enrolment in AE.

  17. An estimator for the variance of the estimator is given in de Luna and Johansson (2010, Sec. 4.2); using this tool, confidence intervals can be computed with a normal approximation.

  18. As suggested by an anonymous referee, the results could be driven by AE individuals who left the labour market after only 1 or 2 years. However, conditioning the sample to have survived in two successive years (1990 and 1991), the results are very similar (not displayed).

  19. The full set of figures and confidence interval tables is available upon request from the authors.

  20. The point estimates sometimes tend to be below zero. Although estimates are very small and not significantly different from zero, a negative effect on the survival rate is of course theoretically feasible, as described in the introduction.

  21. To further check for proportional effects of AE, an anonymous referee suggested to include the number of registered credits as a single covariate in a proportional hazard regression (matched sample). The coefficient estimate for males was not significantly different from zero (p value of 0.57) whereas the estimate for females was positive and significant (younger participants are linked with higher number of credits), but not when applied to the thick support sample of females discussed above (p value 0.91 and N treated = 1,653). We also found it interesting to use an OLS regression on the number of registered credits as the first stage (instead of a probit). The balancing of the samples based on the fitted values work well, and the results indicate no significant differences in survival rates between treated and matched comparisons.

References

  • Albrecht JW, van den Bergh G, Vroman SB (2004) The knowledge lift: The Swedish adult education program that aimed to eliminate low worker skill levels. IFAU Working Paper 2004:17, Institute of Labour Market Policy Evaluation, Uppsala

  • Albrecht JW, Van den Bergh G, Vroman SB (2009) The aggregate labour market effects of the Swedish knowledge lift program. Rev Econ Dyn 12(1):129–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji J (1993) The demand for and return to education when education outcomes are uncertain. J Labor Econ 11(1):48–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arulampalam W, Booth LA, Bryan MA (2004) Training in Europe. J Eur Econ Assoc 2(2–3):346–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aubert P, Caroli E, Roger M (2006) New technologies, organisation and age: firm-level evidence. Econ J 116(509):73–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel AP, Sicherman N (1993) Technological change and retirement decisions of older workers. J Labor Econ 11(1):162–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1962) Investment in human capital: a theoretical analysis. J Polit Econ 70(5), part 2: investment in human beings (Oct., 1962), pp 9–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1993) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis with special reference to education, 3rd edn. Chicago University Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Black DA, Smith JA (2004) How robust is the evidence on the effects of college quality? Evidence from matching. J Econom 121:99–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blau D (1994) Labour force dynamics of older men. Econometrica 62(1):117–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blöndahl S, Scarpetta S (1999) The retirement decision in OECD-countries. OECD Working Papers No 202

  • Borghans L, Weel B (2002) Do older workers have more trouble using a computer than young workers? Res Labor Econ 21:139–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunello G (2003) On the complementarity between education and training in Europe. In: Checchi C, Lucifora C (eds) Education, training and labour market outcomes in Europe. MacMillan

  • Caliendo M, Kopeinig S (2008) Some practical guidance for the implementation of propensity score matching. J Econ Surv 22(1):31–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Luna X, Johansson P (2010) Non-parametric inference for the effect of a treatment on survival times with application in the health and social sciences. J Stat Plan Inference 140:2122–2137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denton F, Spencer B (2009) What is retirement? A review and assessment of alternative concepts and measures. Can J Aging 28(1):63–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ekström E (2003) Essays on inequality and education. Avhandlingsuppsats. Economic Studies 76, Uppsala Universitet

  • Eklöf M, Hallberg D (2004) Private alternatives and early retirement programs. Working paper 2004:5, Department of Economics, Uppsala University

  • Eklöf M, Hallberg D (2010) Do buy-outs of older workers matter? Estimating retirement behavior with special early retirement offers. Int J Manpow 31(3):337–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eliasson K, Westerlund O (2009) Geographical mobility in Sweden—does the influence of labour market related factors diminish over time? Mimeo, Department of Economics, Umeå University

  • EU (2007) Raising productivity growth. Key messages from the European Competetiveness Report 2007. Communication from the Commission, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • EU (2008) A European economic recovery plan. Communication from the Commission, Brussels

    Google Scholar 

  • Fouarge D, Schils T (2009) The effect of early retirement incentives on the training participation of older workers. Labour 23(1):85–109

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson P, Johansson P (2008) Dynamic treatment assignment—the consequences for evaluations using observational data. J Bus Econ Stat 26(4):435–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazerman S, Levy DM, Myers D (2003) Nonexperimental versus experimental estimates of earnings impacts. Ann Am Acad 63–93

  • Hallberg D (2003) A description of routes out of the labor force for workers in Sweden. Working Paper 2003:23, Department of Economics, Uppsala University

  • Heckman J, LaLonde R, Smith J (1999) The economics and econometrics of active labor market programs. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economic, vol 3A, ch 31

  • Holland PW (1986) Statistics and causal inference. J Am Stat Assoc 81:945–960

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iwahashi R (2007) A theoretical assessment of regional development effects on the demand for general education. Econ Educ Rev 26(3):387–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson LS, LaLonde RJ, Sullivan DG (2005a) The returns to community college schooling for displaced workers. J Econom 125(1–2):271–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson LS, LaLonde RJ, Sullivan DG (2005b) The impact of community college retraining on older displaced workers: should we teach old dogs new tricks? Ind Labor Relat Rev 58(3):397–415

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalwij A, Vermeulen F (2008) Health and labour force participation of older people in Europe: what do objective health indicators add to the analysis? Health Econ 17(5):619–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karlström A, Palme M, Svensson I (2004) A dynamic programming approach to model retirement behavior of bluecollar workers in Sweden. J Appl Econ 19:795–807

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Killingsworth M (1982) “Learning by doing” and “Investment in training”: a synthesis of two “rival” models of the life cycle. Rev Econ Stud 263–271

  • Lleras-Muney A (2005) The relationship between education and adult mortality in the United States. Rev Econ Stud 72:189–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monks J (1998) The effect of uncertain returns on human capital investment patterns. Atl Econ J 26(4):413–419

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (1998) Maintaining prosperity in an aging society. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2001) Ageing and income: financial resources and retirement in 9 OECD countries. Paris

  • OECD (2003) Beyond rhetoric: adult learning policies and practices. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2006) Promoting adult learning. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Oosterbeek H (1998) Unravelling supply and demand factors in work-related training. Oxf Econ Pap 50:266–283

    Google Scholar 

  • Peracchi F, Welch F (1994) Trends in labor force transitions of older men and women. J Labor Econ 12(2)

  • Rosenbaum P, Rubin D (1983) The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects. Biometrika 70(1):41–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin D (1974) Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized and non-randomized studies. J Educ Psychol 66(5):688–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sjögren A, Sällström S (2002) Trapped, delayed and handicapped. CEPR Dicussion Paper 3335

  • Smith J, Todd P (2005) Does matching overcome LaLonde’s critique of non-experimental estimators? J Econom 125:305–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence M (1973) Job market signaling. Q J Econ 87(3):355–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stenberg A (2009) Upgrading low skilled adults; is public provision of formal education a sensible policy? Working Paper 2009/1, Institute for Social Research, Stockholm University

  • Stenberg A, Westerlund O (2008) Does comprehensive education work for the unemployed? Labour Econ 15(1):54–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Wise DA (1990) Pensions, the option value of work, and retirement. Econometrica 58(5):1151–1180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waernbaum I (2008) Covariate selection and propensity score specification in causal inference. PhD Thesis, Statististical Studies 38. Department of Statistics, Umeå University

  • Wallace TD, Ihnen LA (1975) Full-time schooling in life-cycle models of human capital accumulation. J Polit Econ 83:137–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss Y (1971) Learning by doing and occupational specialization. J Econ Theory 3(2):189–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weiss A (1995) Human capital vs. signalling explanations of wages. J Econ Perspect 9(4):133–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors wish to thank seminar participants at the European Society for Population Economics 2008 conference and especially two anonymous referees and the editor in charge who helped us improve the quality of the manuscript. We also gratefully acknowledge financial support from The Swedish Research Council through the Ageing and Living Condition (ALC) program and the Swedish Initiative for Research on Microdata in the Social and Medical Sciences (SIMSAM) at Umeå University, and The Bank of Sweden Tercentenary Foundation.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anders Stenberg.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 670 kb)

(DOC 565 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Stenberg, A., de Luna, X. & Westerlund, O. Can adult education delay retirement from the labour market?. J Popul Econ 25, 677–696 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-010-0350-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-010-0350-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation