Skip to main content
Log in

Ethnic assortative matching in marriage and family outcomes: evidence from the mass migration to the US during 1900–1930

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Positive assortative matching in terms of traits such as ethnicity and race has been prevalent in marital formation. One possible explanation for this is that spouses in endogamous marriages possess complementary skills and tastes that increase marital surplus. This paper aims to estimate the effects of ethnic assortative matching on a variety of household outcomes by using the exogenous variation in immigrant flows in the USA during the period 1900–1930 to disentangle the selection effect of partners. The major finding is that the complementarities in home production from same ethnic marriage enhances investment in household public goods such as childrearing and home ownership and reduces the market labor supply of wives. The OLS estimates of the sizes of these effects appear to be substantially biased downward, indicating positive selection into intermarriage in terms of unobservable traits that increase marital surplus.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I thank one anonymous referee for suggesting this theoretical possibility.

  2. In the same spirit as this paper, Frimmel et al. (2013) estimated the effect of assortative mating on marital stability in Austria by performing Cox proportional hazard models. One dimension of assortative mating they investigated is ethnicity. They found no evidence that a decrease in assortative mating by ethnicity to be associated with an increase in risk of divorce in Austria. But again, in their estimations, the non-random mate selection has not been accounted for, which potentially could confound their results.

  3. The local sex ratio of immigrants was used as an instrument for the probability of intermarriage between natives and immigrants.

  4. Studies relate cultural proximity of couples to marital outcomes can be found in Kalmijn et al. (2005) and Dribe and Lundh (2012).

  5. Lam (1988) incorporated the joint consumption of household public goods in the assortative matching model in marriage. The traits he focused on were wealth and market wages.

  6. The difference between inter-married and endogamous married couples is that, the marginal benefit from allocating resources to each unit of public good provision is higher for same-ethnic couples due to complementarity of same ethnicity in home production. So for any given amount of resources, same-ethnic couples would allocate more resources on investing in household public goods rather than on their own private consumption relative to intermarried couples. Conceptually, the resources could be in the form of time spent on housework, financial resources devoted to home assets and children. Arguably for mates that are otherwise identical, same-ethnicity matching is also more efficient because the total marital surplus generated by the households would be higher than if mates were to match across ethnicity.

  7. The immigration flows in the numerators of the instruments are calculated by female and male immigrants of all ages. The reason for not confining the calculation to a certain age group is because the data on the immigrants by age were not very consistently grouped in the sample years.

  8. The foreign born plus the native born of foreign or mixed parentage are referred to as the foreign stock by the US Census Bureau.

  9. See Wooldridge (2002; 623) for further discussion on the advantages of this Probit IV estimator and on the procedure.

  10. The local average treatment effect of the IV method was first discussed by Imbens and Angrist (1994).

  11. Also the quota limit law put a more severe restriction of immigrants from countries of South and East Europe and East Asia, but less on North and West Europe (see the Annual Report of the Commissioner General of Immigration in the fiscal year ended June 30, 1924).

  12. Angrist (2002) also used this exogenous variation in immigrant flows to instrument for the sex ratios of ethnic groups.

  13. Chiappori et al. (2002) also pointed out the potential problem of reverse causality in the relationship between regional sex ratios and economic conditions. States that specialize in industries dominated by males will attract more men through migration, and thus, driving up the sex-ratio in these states. The same reasoning can be applied to the inter-state locational choice of immigrants.

  14. Therefore, it is likely that for the majority of the immigrants in the period under study, their marital choice was not confined to the availability of same-ethnic mates within their residing states as reported in the Census data but was affected by the flows of immigrants nationwide, whose arrival locations were heavily concentrated in states where their ethnic groups tended to congregate. However, caution should be taken when using nationwide immigration flows as instruments for local marriage market conditions as the nationwide variation might not affect local marriage market conditions in different geographic location equally.

  15. The results are virtually the same without this treatment.

  16. During 1895–1903, the data was collected by the Bureau of Immigration in the Department of Treasury. It was then transferred to the Bureau of Immigration and Naturalization in the Department of Commerce and Labor between 1906 and 1913 and subsequently became the Bureau of Immigration in the Department of Labor.

  17. The results are very similar using the wife as the household head.

  18. The changes in national boundaries during the First World War permit consistent separation of ethnic groups in the former Austria-Hungary. My results are insensitive to exclusion of the “Former Austro-Hungarian” group.

  19. To examine the validity of the instruments, I obtained the F-statistics in the first stage regression using OLS. But actual estimates are performed by a three-stage procedure as stated in section 3 with the first stage being a Probit model. The estimates of the Probit first stage evaluated at the sample means are very close to the OLS estimates.

  20. The F-statistics in Table 8 for the first stage regression using this ethnic-specific sex ratio IV and in a specification assuming constant effect of sex ratio presented in Table B1 of Appendix B shows that sex ratios of arriving immigrants as instruments are weaker instruments than IV(1) and IV(2), as it only captures the effect of the gender composition of immigrants on endogamous marriage but not the size effect of immigrants on the foreign stock in the marriage market. Yet it is reassuring that the main results are robust to these alternative instrument sets. These instruments are not employed at the same time due to collinearity for some ethnic groups.

  21. This information is unavailable for the period 1900–1909.

  22. Angrist (2002) argued that the sex ratios of immigrants could affect marital outcomes. But given that the divorce rate was very low: 0.9–1.6 during 1910–1930, (Source: Centers for Disease Control, National Center for Health Statistics) and importantly divorce was extremely difficult to obtain and could only be granted by proof of fault (such as insanity, drunkenness, physical abuse, imprisonment for a crime, cruelty of treatment, and desertion), it is more plausible that the effect of sex ratios on marital outcomes operated through its effect on endogamous marriage rather than through its changes in remarriage prospects of spouses in the marriage market. A spouse that was unhappy with a marriage could not obtain a divorce unilaterally and remarry. This made divorce as a threat point unlikely. In particular, couples that entered into marriage in that period would not conceive the possibility of divorce when divorces were fault-based only. Therefore, once couples had entered into marriages, it is hard to imagine that the sex-ratios in the marriage market could alter family outcomes determined within marriage because the marriage market conditions became irrelevant to couples that were already married when the possibility of remarriage and divorce was almost out of reach.

  23. I also estimate results using an alternative specification that the effects of the instruments to be constant among ethnic groups (i.e., no interaction terms with the ethnic dummies). The results are presented in Appendix B. The estimates are nonetheless not sensitive to this alternative econometric specification.

  24. Massey et al. (2002) suggested that the motivation of migrating to the US among the earliest Mexicans was generally not to relocate permanently but to work temporarily in the US to support families in Mexico (see also Rosenblum et al. 2012). If for example, proportionately more female Mexicans remain in or migrate to the US on a permanent basis when the economic condition in Mexico is bad and increase in the net supply of female Mexicans could reduce the tendency for endogamous marriage among the Mexicans in the US.

  25. I also estimated the effect of endogamous marriage on the labor force participation of husbands. None of the results are statistically significant. This is not surprising given that the labor force participation rate of husbands is 99 % during the sample period.

  26. The instrument set is the number of single female minus the number of single males over the single male population aged 20–45 in ethnic group j in year t.

  27. “Both second generation” is the omitted group.

  28. I have not confined the sample to second generation heads and wives only for the reason that the instruments constructed by the variation in first generation immigration flows might not be valid when the sample is limited to matching among second-generation immigration alone.

  29. In their study, racially mixed couples tend to have one less child than other couples. Note that in their estimates, they did not account for the selection into intermarriage and so it is likely that the true effect of racially endogamous marriage is larger than their estimates.

References

  • Adserà A, Ferrer AM (2014) Immigrants and demography: marriage, divorce, and fertility. IZA Discussion Paper DP7982

  • Angrist JD (2002) How do sex ratios affect marriage and labor markets? Evidence from America’s second generation. Q J Econ 117(3):997–1038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angrist JD, Pischke J (2009) Mostly harmless econometrics: an empiricist’s companion. Princeton University Press, Priceton

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker M, Benjamin D (1997) The role of family in immigrants’ labor-market activity: an evaluation of alternative explanations. Am Econ Rev 87(4):705–727

  • Becker GS (1973) A theory of marriage: part I. J Polit Econ 81(4):813–846

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Landes EM, Michael RT (1977) An economic analysis of marital instability. J Polit Econ 85(6):1141–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloch L (1929) Facts about Mexican immigration before and since the quota restriction laws. J Am Stat Assoc 24(165):50–60

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bodnar J (1985) The transplanted: a history of immigrants in urban America. Indiana University Press, Bloomington

    Google Scholar 

  • Bratter JL, King RB (2008) “But will it last?”: marital instability among interracial and same‐race couples. Fam Relat 57(2):160–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casey T, Dustmann C (2010) Immigrants’ identity, economic outcomes and the transmission of identity across generations. Econ J 120(542):F31–F51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori PA, Fortin B, Lacroix G (2002) Marriage market, divorce legislation, and household labor supply. J Polit Econ 110(1):37–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Childs EC (2005) Navigating interracial borders: black-white couples and their social worlds. Rutgers University Press, Piscataway

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick CU (2009) The economic determinants of ethnic assimilation. J Popul Econ 22(4):859–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick BR, Houseworth C (2011) Ethnic intermarriage among immigrants: human capital and assortative mating. Rev Econ Househ 9(2):149–180

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constant AF, Zimmermann KF (2008) Measuring ethnic identity and its impact on economic behavior. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(2/3):424–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalmage H (2000) Tripping on the color line: black/white multiracial families in a racially divided world. Rutgers University Press, Piscataway

    Google Scholar 

  • Dribe M, Lundh C (2012) Intermarriage, value context and union dissolution: Sweden 1990–2005. Eur J Popul 28(2):139–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duncan B, Trejo S (2005) Ethnic identification, intermarriage, and unmeasured progress by Mexican Americans. IZA Discussion Paper DP1627

  • England P, Folbre N (1999) The cost of caring. Ann Am Acad Pol Soc Sci 561(1):39–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foerster RF (1924) Italian emigration of our times. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Frimmel W, Halla M, Winter-Ebmer R (2013) Assortative mating and divorce: evidence from Austrian register data. J R Stat Soc A Stat Soc 176(4):907–929

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furtado D (2009) Cross-nativity marriages and human capital levels of children. Res Labor Econ 29:273–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furtado D (2012) Human capital and interethnic marriage decisions. Econ Inq 50(1):82–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furtado D, Theodoropoulos N (2011) Interethnic marriage decisions: a choice between ethnic and educational similarities. J Popul Econ 24(4):1257–1279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furtado D, Trejo SJ (2013) 15 Interethnic marriages and their economic effects. In: Constant AF, Zimmermann KF (eds) International handbook on the economics of migration. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, pp 276–292

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, CJ, (2013) Country of Birth of the Foreign-Born Population. In Gibson CJ (ed) American Demographic History Chartbook: 1790 to 2010. http://www.demographicchartbook.com

  • Gilbertson GA, Fitzpatrick JP, Lijun Y (1996) Hispanic intermarriage in New York City: new evidence from 1991. Int Migr Rev 30(2):445–459

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray J (1998) Divorce law changes, household bargaining, and married women’s labor supply. Am Econ Rev 88(3):628–642

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang W, Zhou Y (2015) Impact of one-child policy on inter-ethnic marriage in China. Working Paper

  • Hutchinson EP (1956) Immigrants and their Children, 1850–1950. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens GW, Angrist JD (1994) Identification and estimation of local average treatment effects. Econometrica 62(2):467–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson WR, Skinner J (1986) Labor supply and marital separation. Am Econ Rev 76(3):455–469

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones FL (1996) Convergence and divergence in ethnic divorce patterns: a research note. J Marriage Fam 58(1):213–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn M (1998) Intermarriage and homogamy: causes, patterns, trends. Annu Rev Sociol 24:395–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalmijn M, de Graff PM, Jacques PG (2005) Intermarriage and the risk of divorce in the Netherlands: the effects of differences in religion and in nationality, 1974–94. Popul Stud 59(1):71–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kulu H, Milewski N (2008) Family change and migration in the life course: an introduction. Demogr Res 17:567–590

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lafortune J (2013) Making yourself attractive: pre-marital investments and the returns to education in the marriage market. Am Econ J Appl Econ 5(2):158–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lam D (1988) Marriage markets and assortative mating with household public goods: theoretical results and empirical implications. J Hum Resour 23(4):462–487

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S (2010) Personality and marital surplus. IZA Discussion Paper DP7982

  • Lundberg S, Pollak AP (1993) Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market. J Polit Econ 101(6):988–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Massey DS, Durand J, Malone NJ (2002) Beyond smoke and mirror: Mexican immigration in an era of economic integration. Russell Sage, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Meng X, Gregory RG (2005) Intermarriage and the economic assimilation of immigrants. J Labor Econ 23(1):135–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey WK (1990) Efficient instrumental variables estimation of nonlinear models. Econometrica 58(4):809–837

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagnini DL, Morgan SP (1990) Intermarriage and social distance among U.S. immigrants at the turn of the century. Am J Sociol 26(2):405–432

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parkman AM (1992) Unilateral divorce and the labor force participation rate of married women, revisited. Am Econ Rev 82(3):671–678

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian Z (1997) Breaking the racial barriers: variations in interracial marriage between 1980 and 1990. Demography 34(2):263–276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian Z, Lichter DT (2007) Social boundaries and marital assimilation: interpreting trends in racial and ethnic intermarriage. Am Sociol Rev 72(1):68–94

  • Qian Z, Blair SL, Ruf SD (2001) Asian American interracial and interethnic marriages: differences by education and nativity. Int Migr Rev 35(2):557–586

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenblum MR, Kandel WA, Seelke CR, Wasem RE (2012) Mexican Migration to the United States: Policy and Trends. CRS Report for Congress R42560.

  • Stevenson B (2007) The impact of divorce laws on marriage-specific capital. J Labor Econ 25(1):75–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B (2008) Divorce law and women’s labor supply. J Empir Leg Stud 5(4):853–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildsmith E, Myron PG, Gratton B (2003) Assimilation and intermarriage for U.S. immigrant Groups, 1880–1990. Hist Fam 8(4):563–584

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2001) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge, p 623

    Google Scholar 

  • Zimmermann L, Zimmermann KF, Constant A (2007) Ethnic self-identification of first-generation immigrants. Int Migr Rev 41(3):769–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper was previously circulated as “The Effects of Endogamous Marriage on Family Outcomes: Evidence from Exogenous Variation in Immigrant Flows during 1900–1930 in the United States.” I thank Tsz-Kin Chan, Shelly Lundberg and the anonymous referees for their valuable suggestions. All errors are my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ho-Po Crystal Wong.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Klaus F. Zimmermann

Appendices

Appendix A

Table 11 Mean values of selected outcome variables by ethnicity of household heads

Appendix B

Table 12 Regression results assuming constant marriage market effects across ethnic groups

Appendix C

Grouping of ethnicity

Individuals are grouped by their place of birth or the place of birth of their parents in the Census data. If the individual was native born and both his parents are foreigners, he would be categorized into the ethnic group of his mother as second generation.

The following codes of the places of birth in the IPUMS Census data that are used to merge with data on the immigration flows from the Annual Report of the Commissioner General of Immigration by “race or people”.

Categorization of ethnicity in IPUMS Census data

Country code in Census

Country

Ethnicity

Country code in census

Country

Ethnicity

200

Mexico

Mexican

434

Italy

Italian

400

Denmark

Scandinavian

436

Portugal

Portuguese

401

Finland

Finnish

438

Spain

Spanish

402

Iceland

Scandinavian

450

Austria

Former Austro-Hungarian

404

Norway

Scandinavian

452

Czechoslovakia

Former Austro-Hungarian

405

Sweden

Scandinavian

453

Germany

German

410

England

English (Anglophone)

454

Hungary

Former Austro-Hungarian

411

Scotland

English (Anglophone)

455

Poland

Polish

412

Wales

English (Anglophone)

456

Romania

Romanian

413

United Kingdom

English (Anglophone)

462

Lithuania

Russian

412

Ireland

English (Anglophone)

465

Russia

Russian

421

France

French

501

Japan

Japanese

425

Netherlands

Dutch

542

Turkey

Turkish

433

Greece

Greek

   

Poland was not identified as a country in the 1910 Census but was again identified in 1920 and onwards after World War I. The Polish stock in the US in 1910 is estimated by population with Polish mother tongue. The same approach is used by Census in estimating the 1910 foreign-born population from Poland (See Gibson 2013). Note that the results are insensitive to exclusion of the Polish ethnic group.

Classification for Ethnicity of Immigrants from the Annual Report of the Commissioner General of Immigration

Race or people

Ethnicity

Bohemian and Moravian (Czech)

Former Austro-Hungarian

Bulgarian, Serbian, and Montenegrin

Former Austro-Hungarian

Dalmatian, Bosnian, Herzegovinian

Former Austro-Hungarian

Dutch and Flemish

Dutch

English

English (Anglophone)

Finnish

Finnish

French

French

German

German

Greek

Greek

Irish

English (Anglophone)

Italian North

Italian

Italian South

Italian

Japanese

Japanese

Lithuanian

Russian

Magyar

Former Austro-Hungarian

Mexican

Mexican

Polish

Polish

Portuguese

Portuguese

Rumanian

Romanian

Russian

Russian

Ruthenia

Russian

Scandinavian

Scandinavian

Scotch

English (Anglophone)

Spanish

Spanish

Turkish

Turkish

Welsh

English (Anglophone)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wong, HP.C. Ethnic assortative matching in marriage and family outcomes: evidence from the mass migration to the US during 1900–1930. J Popul Econ 29, 817–848 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-016-0588-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-016-0588-x

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation