Skip to main content
Log in

Immigration and internal mobility in Canada

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyse the impact of temporary foreign workers (TFWs) and permanent immigrants on interprovincial mobility in Canada. Empirical results are analysed through the lens of a theoretical model that incorporates a job-matching framework in a migration model à la Harris and Todaro. The effect of the inflow of TFWs in interprovincial mobility is negative, substantial and significant. This is not the case for the inflow of permanent immigrants selected through the Canadian point system. The robustness of these empirical results to issues of endogeneity is assessed through a classical instrumentation approach as well as through a diff-in-diff analysis taking advantage of a pilot project facilitating the admission of TFWs in two Western provinces over the 2007–2010 period. Our paper suggests that, in general, the impact of immigration on labour market conditions depends critically on the way immigration policy is set.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Subsequent studies of the influence of immigration on wages include Borjas (2003), Ottaviano and Peri (2012), and Docquier et al. (2014). D’Amuri et al. (2010) consider the impact of immigration in Germany on wages and employment rates. Recently, Braun and Mahmoud (2014) look specifically at the impact of forced immigration from Eastern Germany to post-war Western Germany on native employment.

  2. Recent immigration reforms that were implemented since the end of 2014 put more emphasis on labour market demand.

  3. See Bertoli et al. (2012) for a detailed description of the immigration systems in developed countries for skill selection policies.

  4. Overall, evidence of the impact on native outflows is very mixed. A large number of papers find significant effects of immigration on natives’ outmigration; see Filer (1992), Frey (1995) and Borjas (2006) in the case of the USA, among others. See Cortes and Pan (2013) on the specific case of native-born nurses in the USA. See also Hatton and Tani (2005) for the UK. In contrast, other papers find very little evidence of native displacement. See Card (2001), Card and Di Nardo (2000) and Kritz and Gurak (2001) among others.

  5. See Molloy et al. (2011) for a recent review. The investigated factors are numerous and related, for instance, to demographic trends (ageing), variation in unemployment rates, and housing factors such as home ownership. These factors also include technological progress that allows people to work at a distance. Kaplan and Schulhofer-Wohl (2013) argue that the fall in internal migration in the USA is due to a decline in the geographic specificity of returns to occupation as well as a reduction in information costs about alternative locations.

  6. There is a direct connection between Eq, (4) and the matching function. See Petrongolo and Pissaridès (2001) for details. Indeed, if one denotes n the number of job matches and defines the matching function n = n(U,V), the n/U ratio can be seen as the probability of finding a job for unemployed workers. n/U is characterized by Eq. (4) if one assumes that (a) each employer sends one job vacancy randomly to one single unemployed worker, (b) all unemployed workers are all the same, (c) the degree of matching is perfect, and (d) U is large enough with respect to V. The equivalence might be checked through a Taylor expansion.

  7. Given the design of the immigration policy regarding TFWs, \( {\alpha}_T^c \)should be close to −1.

  8. In this respect, in an econometric model capturing the impact of immigration on domestic wages and internal migration, Hatton and Tani (2005) insist on the need to explicitly include regional proxies of labour demand shocks instead of nationwide ones. Omitting these variables is indeed likely to generate significant biases in the estimation of coefficients of an equation like ours, since they are obviously correlated with the key covariates T j , t and I j , t .

  9. Card and Peri (2016) discuss the importance of measuring mobility of natives and immigrants to avoid estimation biases of the relationship between the two. Hatton and Tani (2005) emphasize the benefits of such an analysis using direct measures of internal migration as opposed to proxies derived, for instance, from the variations in the population stocks. Hatton and Tani’s measure of flows derived from the records of the British National Health Services is definitely a valuable step towards a better measurement of internal migration. An additional feature of the Canadian regional case is that, given the size of provinces, the share of interprovincial commuters is negligible, which minimizes the case of a systematic downward bias in the measurement of mobility.

  10. In the benchmark analysis, we do not use the dyadic dimension of the migration data. The time-varying pair, country of origin and province of destination are nevertheless used later on for TFWs in the instrumental variable analysis.

  11. Note, however, since estimates of ρ c are fairly similar across regressions, the ranking of short-run effects and long-run effects across categories of natives is similar.

  12. In particular, our estimates compare with the effects reported in their Table 7.

  13. See Table 1 of Gross (2014) for more details.

  14. Source: Immigration Refugees and Citizenship Canada, Facts and figures—immigration overview: temporary residents overview, March 2016 released.

  15. For instance, if one expects to have substitution effects for similar levels of skills between natives and TFWs, and complementarity effects for different levels of skills, this means that our estimates will capture a mixed effect between complementarity and substitution. If this is the case, our estimates can be seen as a lower bound of the substitution effects between similar levels of skills.

  16. The correlation between the immigration rates (resp. flows) for unskilled and skilled TFWs is 0.84 (resp. 0.93), which leads to a very high degree of multicollinearity. This illustrates that provinces tended to attract both types of TFWs at the same time and that, in light with our theoretical background, the global tightness of the provincial labour market played a prominent role in attracting these TFWs.

  17. Actually, the database of bilateral flows to each province transmitted by CIC includes up to 251 origins (the maximum number is for Ontario). While most of these origins are countries, a subset includes regions of some countries (the remaining origins are aggregates of countries like East Africa and are omitted). A good example is provided by the four overseas departments of France (Guyana, Guadeloupe, Martinique, and La Réunion) for which the flows are distinct from the ones coming from Metropolitan France. Aggregating the flows with those coming from Metropolitan France would include some bias since these departments differ significantly from the Metropole, especially in terms of distance to Canada but also in terms of income levels. It is still interesting to include these regions since they send many migrants to Canada and especially to French-speaking Quebec. For these entities, we calculated our own GDP per head data since they are not available in the Penn World Tables (version 8.0). We use the data of the Institut National de la Statistique et des Études Économiques (Insee) for 2009, 2010, and 2011. For the rest of the sample period, we applied the ratio department/metropole to the French data to get GDP per head estimates of these origins.

  18. All the results are available upon request from Michel Beine.

  19. Once again, these results are available upon request from Michel Beine.

References

  • Beine M, Bertoli S, Fernandez-Huerta-Moraga J (2016) A practitioner's guide to gravity models of international migration. The World Economy 39(4):496-512

  • Beine M, Coulombe S, Vermeulen WN (2015) Dutch disease and the mitigation effect of migration: evidence from Canadian provinces. Econ J 125(December):1574–1615F

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Docquier F, Özden Ç (2011) Diasporas. J Dev Econ 95(1):30–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Docquier F, Schiff M (2013) International migration, transfers of norms and home country fertility. Can J Econ 46(4):1406–1430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoli S, Brücker H, Mayda AM, Peri G (2012) “The battle of brains: how to attract talent.” in: Brain Drain and Brain Gain-the Global Competition to Attract High-Skilled Migrants, edited by T. Boeri, H. Brücker, F. Docquier and H. Rapoport. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (1987) Immigrants, minorities, and labour market competition. Industrial and Labour Relations Review 40(3):382–392

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2003) The labour demand curve is downward sloping: reexamining the impact of immigration on the labour market. Q J Econ 118(4):1335–1374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ (2006) Native internal migration and the labour market impact of immigration. J Hum Resour 41(2):221–258

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ, Freeman RB, Katz LF (1996) Searching for the effect of immigration on the labour market. Am Econ Rev 86(2):246–251

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas GJ, Freeman RB, Katz LF (1997) How much do immigration and trade affect labour market outcomes? Brook Pap Econ Act 28(1):1–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braun S, Mahmoud TO (2014) The employment effects of immigration: evidence from the mass arrival of German expellees in post-war Germany. J Econ Hist 74(1):69–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D (1990) The impact of the Mariel boatlift on the Miami labour market. Industrial and Labour Relations Review 43(2):245–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D (2001) Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labour market impacts of higher immigration. J Labour Econ 19(1):22–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Di Nardo J (2000) Do immigrant inflows lead to native outflows? Am Econ Rev 90(2):360–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card D, Peri G (2016) Immigration economics by George J. Borjas: a review essay. J Econ Lit 54(4):1333–1349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cortes, P., and J. Pan. 2013. “Foreign nurse and the supply of native nurses.” Paper presented at the Economic Studies Conference on Migration, Munich, December 2013.

  • Coulombe, S. (2011) Lagging Behind: Productivity and the Good Fortune of Canadian Provinces. Commentary No 331, C.D. Howe Institute, Toronto, 2011

  • D’Amuri F, Ottaviano GIP, Peri G (2010) The labour market impact of immigration in western Germany in the 1990s. Eur Econ Rev 54(4):550–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DAmuri F, Peri G (2014) Immigration, jobs and employment protection: evidence from Europe before and during the great depression. J Eur Econ Assoc 12(2):432–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Özden C, Peri G (2014) The labour market effects of immigration and emigration in OECD countries. Econ J 124:1106–1145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Filer RK (1992) The impact of immigrant arrivals on migratory patterns of native workers. In: Borjas GJ, Freeman RB (eds) Immigration and the Work Force: Economic Consequences for the United States and Source Areas. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 245–269

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J, Romer D (1999) Does trade cause growth? Am Econ Rev 89(3):379–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey WH (1995) Immigration and internal migration ‘flight’: a California case study. Popul Environ 16(4):353–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gross DM (2014) “Temporary foreign workers in Canada: are they really filling labour shortages?” commentary no. 407. CD Howe Institute, Toronto

    Google Scholar 

  • Gross DM, Schmitt N (2012) Temporary foreign workers and regional labour market disparities in Canada. Canadian Public Policy 38(2):233–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman JB (1982) The substitutability of natives and immigrants in production. Rev Econ Stat 64(4):596–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris JR, Todaro MP (1970) Migration, unemployment and development: a two-sector analysis. Am Econ Rev 60(1):126–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatton T, Tani M (2005) Immigration and inter-regional mobility in the UK, 1982–2000. Economic Journal 115(507):F342–F358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, G., and S. Schulhofer-Wohl. 2013. Understanding the long-run decline in interstate migration. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Working Paper 697.

  • Kritz MM, Gurak DT (2001) The impact of immigration on the internal migration of natives and immigrants. Demography 38(1):133–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayda AM (2010) International migration: a panel data analysis of the determinants of bilateral flows. J Popul Econ 23(4):1249–1274

  • Molloy R, Smith CL, Wozniak A (2011) Internal migration in the United States. J Econ Perspect 25(3):173–196

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottaviano GIP, Peri G (2012) Rethinking the effect of immigration on wages. J Eur Econ Assoc 10(1):152–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peri G, Sparber C (2009) Task specialization, immigration, and wages. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1(3):135–169

    Google Scholar 

  • Petrongolo B, Pissaridès C (2001) Looking into the black box: a Survey of the matching function. J Econ Lit 39(2):390–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pissaridès C (1985) Short-run equilibrium dynamics of unemployment, vacancies and real wages. Am Econ Rev 75(4):676–690

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissaridès C (2000) Equilibrium unemployment theory, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Shimer R (2007) Mismatch. Am Econ Rev 97(4):1074–1101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spilimbergo A (2009) Democracy and foreign education. Am Econ Rev 99(1):528–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Canada. 2004. CANSIM II Series V1408265, Table number 3840011. "Intergovernmental transfers, Provincial economic accounts, Series Title, "British Columbia; Medicare." http://dc2.chass.utoronto.ca/cansim2/index.jsp. Accessed April 9, 2005.

  • Todaro M (1969) A model for labour migration and urban unemployment in less developed countries. Am Econ Rev 59(1):138–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Worswick, C. 2013. “Economic implications of recent changes to the temporary foreign worker program.” IRPP Insight 4 (October).

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper has benefitted from comments and suggestions of two anonymous referees and the editor. We also made use of the many comments collected during the presentations made In Barcelona (summer forum), Oxford (migration and development conference), Louvain, Geneva, Poznan, Ottawa and Roma. We are particularly indebted to M. Clemens, M. Corak, F. Docquier, G. Facchini, J. Fernandez, A-M. Mayda, F. Mariani, L-P. Morin, G. Peri and B. Vanderlinden among many others for useful suggestions of improvements. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michel Beine.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Klaus F. Zimmermann

Appendices

Appendix A: Two-step instrumentation strategy: procedure and detailed results

In this appendix, we detail the procedure and results of the instrumentation strategy used in Sect. 4.4.2 to cope with the potential occurrence of unobservable province-specific shocks. If these unobservable shocks are correlated with the inflows of the TFWs, then the FGLS estimates of the structural model to be estimated (see Eq. (9)) can be biased.

The IV procedure basically requires us to use an instrument that is correlated with the observed inflows of TFWs but uncorrelated with the error term and hence with the unobservable shocks. We need to emphasize that these shocks and the instrument are time- and province-specific. Our IV procedure builds on the previous strategies implemented in the literature of growth, trade, and migration. See Frankel and Romer (1999) for an application to the impact of trade on growth. It has also been used in the literature on international migration (see Spilimbergo (2009) and Beine et al. (2013), among others). The present strategy extends the previous contributions in the sense that we use a panel dimension while the previous papers dealt only with cross-sectional data.

The procedure involves two main separate steps. For the sake of clarity, the first step can be broken down further into separate substeps.

1.1 A.1 First step: gravity model and aggregate predicted inflows of TFWs by provinces

In this first step, we use a gravity model applied to the bilateral flows of TFWs between each country of origin of the world and each province in each year. The model is used to generate predicted bilateral flows for each triplet (origin country-destination province-time) that are afterwards aggregated across countries of origin to generate our instrument. This instrument is the time-varying, province-specific aggregate predicted inflows of TFWs. The prediction is supposed to be generated by exogenous factors, i.e., covariates of the gravity model that are uncorrelated with the unobservable shocks (and the error term) of Eq. (9).

We first estimate the following benchmark gravity model:

$$ \mathit{\ln}\left({1+ m}_{i j, t}\right){=\upalpha}_i{+\upalpha}_j{+\upalpha}_t{+\upbeta}_1\kern0.5em \mathit{\ln}\left({d}_{i j}\right){+\upbeta}_2\kern0.5em {l}_{i j}{+\upbeta}_3\kern0.5em {M}_{i j, t\hbox{-} 1+}{\upgamma}^{\prime } f\left({y}_{i t}\right){+\upvarepsilon}_{i j, t} $$
(11)

The gravity model involves a log-log specification explaining the log of the number of TFWs m ij,t each year t between country of origin i and province j. This specification can be more or less justified on the basis of microfoundations with optimizing agents (see Beine et al. (2016) for a survey).

Since there are many pairs with zero bilateral flows or even missing bilateral flows, the use of ln(m ij,t ) would generate estimations that are subject to a significant selection bias. We can indeed expect that countries that do not send any TFWs to a given province do not share the same observed and unobserved features as those of the countries sending TFWs. The same line of reasoning can apply to missing data about the flows. To avoid that, we use the usual “trick” of taking ln(1 + m ij,t ) (the so-called scaled estimation procedure) to include the zeroes in the estimation. Further to that, we also have to deal with the missing data. Looking at the database (kindly provided by Citizenship and Immigration Canada (CIC)), we notice that most of the missing data was found for triplets for which zero flows were observed during other years. If this is correct, we can transform the missing data into zeroes, which would involve even more observations. We follow both procedures and check that the results are qualitatively and quantitatively similar.

Model (11) involves either covariates or fixed effects. With respect to fixed effects, we include country of origin fixed effects α i that capture the time-invariant characteristics of origin countries such as geographical location. We also include the destination province fixed effects α j that capture the time-invariant characteristics of receiving provinces such as geographical location or language. Finally, we include time fixed effects that capture the general factors affecting the migration of TFWs. These include important factors such as the Canada-wide immigration policy regarding these TFWs.

We use two time-invariant factors affecting the relative attraction between each country of origin and each province. First, we use geographic distance d ij between each origin country and each province, using the respective capitals as references. Second, we use linguistic proximity measures denoted by l ij . Note that Canada is mainly an English-speaking country with the exceptions of Quebec, which is French-speaking, and New Brunswick in which both languages are spoken. l ij is broken down further into two variables, one for French, one for English. The two variables are dummy ones taking 1 if the origin and the destination share the same language, 0 otherwise. The l ij and d ij variables are exogenous with respect to unobserved shocks.

We also capture in model (11) some network effect regarding the TFWs. The migration of workers has been shown to depend a lot on migrants’ networks at the macroeconomic level (see Beine et al. (2014)). These networks are related to the stock of previous migrants in the destination province who came from the same origin. For TFWs, however, this concept is not directly applicable since these are temporary migrants who have to return to their country at the end of the year. Still, some network effect definitely exists in the process of hiring TFWs. In hiring TFWs from a specific origin, Canadian employers obtain some information about productivity, efficiency, and so on of that origin’s workers from previously hired TFWs from the origin. But these important revelations can be asymmetric. Furthermore, if employers are satisfied with the previous TFWs, employers can hire the same workers provided they return to their origin and reapply to the program. Anecdotal evidence of farmers in Quebec repeatedly hiring agricultural workers from Honduras as TFWs is a good illustration of that phenomenon. We capture this particular network effect by summing up the flows of previous TFWs over the last 5 years. This variable is denoted by M ij,t−1. If unobserved shocks to the province are not too persistent over time, this variable is also exogenous with respect to unobserved shocks.

Finally, we include origin-specific income shocks y it . We use GDP per head data from the Penn World Tables (version 8.0)Footnote 17 in several functional forms. In a first one, we simply use the log of GDP per head, i.e., γ f(y it ) = β4ln(y it ). This could capture the role of the wage differential between the origin and Canada, and we should expect a negative coefficient if this mechanism is prevailing. Nevertheless, the literature on migration shows that income at origin can have a non-linear effect. See Mayda (2010) and Beine et al. (2016) on that. Low-income levels can be associated with little emigration because liquidity constraints are operating. As income increases, this releases these constraints and leads to more migration. After some threshold, when constraints are no longer operating, further increases lead to a reduction in the wage differential and therefore deter emigration. In that case, one should expect a concave relationship. In this functional form, we have γf(yit) = β4yit + β5yit 2. Income shocks at origin y it are obviously uncorrelated with province-specific shocks and can be therefore considered as exogenous factors.

Table 8 presents the results of the estimation of Eq. (11) with different variants.

Table 8 First-stage regressions: explaining flows of TFWs

The results of the gravity regressions are more or less in line with the expectations. Flows of TFWs to a given province from a given origin increase with linguistic similarity, decrease with distance, increase with the size of the previous flows of the TFWs. The role of origin-specific GDP shocks receives less support from the data. While the signs of the coefficients are consistent with the expectations, they are mostly insignificant. This might due to the fact that what matters for migration decisions is the wage at origin. GDP per head might be a poor proxy for the wages in a lot of cases. This issue has already been identified in the existing literature on gravity models applied to international migration (see Beine et al. (2016), among others).

The different specifications (1) to (6) give fairly similar results. The R2 vary between 0.83 and 0.90, which suggests that the prediction should be quite good, at least at the bilateral level. The fact that missing data are transformed into zero values leads to a slightly less-good fit; this is understandable since, in some cases, this might be too strong an assumption. One should be aware that each model will give rise to a different instrument, so a choice has to be made for the subsequent instrumentation procedure. In Sect. 4.4.2, we use the instrument generated by model (6). Nevertheless, the results of the final IV estimation do not depend in general on that choice since the results are qualitatively and quantitatively similar across the six possible instruments.Footnote 18

1.2 A.2 Prediction of bilateral flows of TFWs

Once model (11) has been estimated, one can recover the estimates of the fixed effects and the coefficients to predict each bilateral flow of TFWs between each origin and each province of destination at each point of time. Let us denote α as the vector of the estimated fixed effects and denote θ as the vector containing the estimated slope coefficients

$$ \left(\widehat{\upbeta_1},\widehat{\upbeta_2},\widehat{\upbeta_3},\widehat{\upbeta_4},\widehat{\upbeta_5}\right) $$

from model (11). Finally, let us collapse in vector X jt the covariates used in each regression. Then, we have

$$ \left(1+{\overset{\frown }{m}}_{1 j, t}\right)=\mathit{\exp}\left({\alpha}^{\prime }+{\theta}^{\prime }{X}_{ijt}^{\prime}\right). $$
(12)

1.3 A.3 Prediction of inflows of TFWs by province and by year

We then can use the predicted \( {\overset{\frown }{\mathrm{m}}}_{1\mathrm{j},\mathrm{t}} \) at the dyadic level to produce a predicted aggregate value for each province at each point of time. This is obtained simply by summing up across origins for each province in each year:

$$ {\overset{\frown }{m}}_{j, t}={\sum}_{i=1}^N{m}_{i j, t}. $$
(13)

The predicted \( {\overset{\frown }{m}}_{j, t} \) can be used subsequently as an instrument for the observed values of TFWs by province and time period.

The validity of these instruments has to fulfil the usual two conditions. First, the instruments must be strong predictors of the observed TFWs. The estimates of Table 8, in particular the values of the R2, suggest that this is the case at the bilateral level. Furthermore, at the aggregate level, i.e., after summing up across origins, this can be evaluated by the F-stat of the first stage of the final IV procedure. The values of the F-stats reported in Table 5 in the core of the text are far beyond the usual threshold of 10.

The second condition is that the instrument must be uncorrelated with the error term of the final regression. In this case, the error term contains the influence of unobserved provincial shocks on the net interprovincial immigration flows of native workers. The covariates used for the prediction of \( {\overset{\frown }{\mathrm{m}}}_{\mathrm{j},\mathrm{t}} \) and \( {\overset{\frown }{\mathrm{m}}}_{\mathrm{j},\mathrm{t}} \) are obviously uncorrelated with the contemporaneous shocks. The exclusion restriction can be questioned only for our measure of the network effect M ij,t−1 if these shocks are highly persistent over time. Nevertheless, instruments generated without the inclusion of M ij,t−1 give qualitatively similar results.Footnote 19

Appendix 2. Supplementary results

Table 9 Impact of international immigration on net internal migration by age profile: benchmark results
Table 10 Impact of international immigration on net internal migration by age profile, males: benchmark results
Table 11 Impact of international immigration on net internal migration by age profile, females: benchmark results
Table 12 The impact of international immigration on net internal migration (including permanent economic and non-economic immigrants)
Table 13 Diff-in-diff analysis: impact of the E-LMO policy (2007–2010)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Beine, M., Coulombe, S. Immigration and internal mobility in Canada. J Popul Econ 31, 69–106 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-017-0645-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-017-0645-0

Keywords

JEL codes

Navigation