Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Offshoring and labor income risk: an empirical investigation

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes how increased offshoring affects labor income risk. Dealing with the variability of incomes, it is therefore distinct from a large number of studies explaining the level effects of globalization on income in the labor market. It provides an assessment that directly connects labor income risk and offshoring trends in a panel setting at the industry level using German data. Importantly, we distinguish between transitory and permanent risk to individual income. Permanent income risk is defined as the variance of unpredictable shocks to income that do not fade out over time. Different from transitory short-term fluctuations, it has a particular welfare relevance. Our findings suggest that, at the industry level, permanent labor income risk decreases with offshoring. This effect is particularly strong for offshoring to low-income destinations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Yet, the opposite holds true for the receiving country. Volatility abroad (e.g., in Mexico for the case of US offshoring) is amplified.

  2. Note that our approach, which is standard in the literature, does not allow us to link offshoring to income risk from switching industries. For studies on level effects on displaced worker’s income, among others, see Hummels et al. (2014) and Ebenstein et al. (2014).

  3. Given that individuals affected by offshoring could be credit constrained and hence less able to smooth such shocks, we investigated whether there is any relation of offshoring and transitory income risk in our setting. We find no such effect.

  4. It is supported by existing empirical evidence that consumption responds to permanent income shocks. For example, using PSID and CEX data, Blundell et al. (2008) find that a 10 % permanent income shock induces a 6.4 % permanent change in consumption.

  5. The degree of permanent shocks to be smoothed out depends on the size of precautionary savings, that is, depends on the parametrization of the model, say, the risk aversion degree, the utility function, etc.

  6. Individuals have a log utility function with degree of risk aversion 2, and the time discount factor is 0.96.

  7. Leaving out these industry fixed effects in the first stage does not alter much our results on the link between offshoring and income risk.

  8. The random walk assumption is not the only possible structure underlying the income process. For instance, other papers have suggested including a third, MA(1), component. Yet, as Krebs and Yao (2009) show, the permanent component of income risk is hardly affected by different assumptions on the income process. We therefore stick to the random walk assumption.

  9. Storesletten et al. (2004) argue that the conditional variance of these permanent income shocks is counter-cyclical, increasing during contractions and decreasing during expansions.

  10. We drop the industry subscript \(j\) for expositional reasons in this subsection.

  11. This study uses the factually anonymous BA-Employment Panel (Years 1998–2007). Data access was provided via a Scientific Use File supplied by the Research Data Centre (FDZ) of the German Federal Employment Agency (BA) at the Institute for Employment Research (IAB). For detailed information on the database, see Schmucker and Seth (2009).

  12. Krishna and Senses (2014) estimate income risk to be higher for individuals experiencing a transition from one industry to another when compared to individuals staying in one industry. We thus regard our estimations of income risk as a lower bound. If one were to link individual income risk arising from switching industries to offshoring, one would have to be able to clearly and causally identify offshoring as the reason for the switch—a task that we cannot accomplish with our data at hand.

  13. The few remaining assumed imputed incomes, which are reported in the absence of a report by the employer, so-called Forschreibefälle, are deleted. In a robustness exercise further below, we show our results to be very similar when using the June waves.

  14. The estimates in Table 1 are somewhat lower than those found in other studies, e.g., in Fuchs-Schuendeln et al. (2010). Note, however, that this latter study estimates permanent income risk of all West German individuals, while our study concentrates on fulltime employed males, which are characterized by a more stable income process. Furthermore, some studies rely on total household income, which inherently has higher risk since it includes the outcomes of labor-leisure choice and substitution effects between household members. With regard to the international evidence, it is plausible to us that the German labor market features lower income risk due to stronger institutions such as employment protection and wage bargaining coordination.

  15. The data on imports and industry output are deflated using an aggregate manufacturing import price deflator and industry-specific producer price indices, respectively. The import price index is taken from the German Statistical Office Destatis and the industry-specific indices for producer prices come from the EU KLEMS database (March 2008) release.

  16. Here, we again draw on the OECD STAN database and multiply the imports in (9) by the industries’ share of imports coming from non-OECD countries. When calculating import shares for non-OECD countries, we had to rely on aggregates for industries 15–16, 17–19 and 21–22 and thus use the same non-OECD share for each industry within the respective group. Note, however, that this only applies to the non-OECD trade share and neither to total imports \(IMP_{j^*t}\) nor \(\Omega _{j^*jt}\). Furthermore, this region-specific calculation of offshoring entails the assumption of identical \(\Omega _{j^*jt}\) for the two groups of countries, since the input–output tables do not hold any region-specific information.

  17. All these data are retrieved from the OECD STAN database. Industry 36 includes industry 37 (recycling) in the OECD data. Dropping this industry leaves the results almost identical.

  18. We present results for 1-year lagged values of offshoring as explanatory variables, because we do not find any significant contemporaneous correlation.

  19. This does not say anything about the possible effects of displacements at the margin of offshoring. Yet, according to some recent studies, offshoring does not seem to be a major cause of aggregate job loss at the industry level (OECD 2007; Harrison and McMillan 2011), which might be due to offshoring-related productivity effects Wright (2014). The possibility that some specific groups of workers are being displaced while employment grows for others remains evident, however (Harrison and McMillan 2011). In this sense, our results have an aggregate interpretation.

  20. Note that the (unweighted) average increase between 1999 and 2005 was 1.6 % points for worldwide offshoring and 1 % point for non-OECD offshoring, respectively, the latter coming from a lot lower values.

  21. The data are available at (http://www.uni-goettingen.de/en/99958.html). Further information on their exact construction can be found in Geishecker (2006).

References

  • Aiyagari S (1994) Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Q J Econ 109(3):659–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altonji JG, Segal LM (1996) Small-sample bias in GMM estimation of covariance structures. J Bus Econ Stat 14(3):353–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Lopez-Gonzalez J (2013) Supply-chain trade: a portrait of global patterns and several testable hypotheses. NBER Working Papers 18957, NBER

  • Baumgarten D, Geishecker I, Görg H (2013) Offshoring, tasks, and the skill-wage pattern. Eur Econ Rev 61:132–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker S, Muendler M (2008) The effect of FDI on job security. BE J Econ Anal Pol 8(1):1770

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergin P, Feenstra R, Hanson G (2009) Offshoring and volatility: evidence from Mexico’s maquiladora industry. Am Econ Rev 99(4):1664–1671

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Preston I (2008) Consumption inequality and partial insurance. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1887–1921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buch C, Lipponer A (2010) Volatile multinationals? Evidence from the labor demand of German firms. Lab Econ 17(2):345–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll C, Samwick A (1997) The nature of precautionary wealth. J Mon Econ 40(1):41–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides G, Duffie D (1996) Asset pricing with heterogeneous consumers. J Pol Econ 104(2):219–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Fitzenberger B, Schönberg U, Spitz-Oener A (2014) From sick man of Europe to economic superstar: Germany’s resurgent economy. J Econ perspect 28(1):167–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Ludsteck J, Schoenberg U (2009) Revisiting the German wage structure. Q J Econ 124(2):843–881

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ebenstein A, Harrison A, McMillan M, Phillips S (2014) Estimating the impact of trade and offshoring on American workers using the current population surveys. Rev Econ Stat 96(4):581–595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R (2010) Offshoring in the global economy: microeconomic structure and macroeconomic implications, vol 1, 1st edn. The MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra R, Hanson G (1999) The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. Q J Econ 114(3):907–940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuchs-Schuendeln N, Krueger D, Sommer M (2010) Inequality trends for Germany in the last two decades: a tale of two countries. Rev Econ Dyn 13(1):103–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gartner H (2005) The imputation of wages above the contribution limit with the German IAB employment sample. FDZ Methodenrep 2:2005

    Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker I (2006) Does outsourcing to central and eastern Europe really threaten manual workers’ jobs in Germany? World Econ 29(5):559–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker I, Görg H (2008) Winners and losers: a micro-level analysis of international outsourcing and wages. Can J Econ 41(1):243–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker I, Görg H (2011) Services offshoring and wages: evidence from micro data. Oxf Econ Pap 65(1):124–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geishecker I, Riedl M, Frijters P (2012) Offshoring and job loss fears: an econometric analysis of individual perceptions. Lab Econ 19(5):738–747

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman G, Rossi-Hansberg E (2008) Trading tasks: a simple theory of offshoring. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1978–1997

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison A, McMillan M (2011) Offshoring jobs? Multinationals and US manufacturing employment. Rev Econ Stat 93(3):857–875

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hogrefe J, Wrona J (2015) Trade, tasks, and training: The effect of offshoring on individual skill upgrading. Can J Econ (forthcoming)

  • Houseman S, Kurz C, Lengermann P, Mandel B (2011) Offshoring bias in U.S. manufacturing. J Econ Perspect 25(2):111–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D, Jørgensen R, Munch JR, Xiang C (2014) The wage effects of offshoring: evidence from Danish matched worker-firm data. Am Econ Rev 104(6):1597–1629

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karabay B, McLaren J (2010) Trade, offshoring, and the invisible handshake. J Int Econ 82(1):26–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kohler W, Wrona J (2011) Offshoring tasks, yet creating jobs? University of Tübingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance (12)

  • Krebs T (2003) Human capital risk and economic growth. Q J Econ 118(2):709–744

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krebs T, Krishna P, Maloney W (2010) Trade policy, income risk, and welfare. Rev Econ Stat 92(3):467–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krebs T, Kuhn M (2010) Welfare and consumption with permanent income shocks. Mimeo, University of Bonn, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Krebs T, Yao Y (2009) Measuring income risk in the German labor market. Mimeo, Mannheim University, Mannheim

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishna P, Senses M (2014) International trade and labor income risk in the United States. Rev Econ Stud 81(1):186–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine D, Zame W (2002) Does market incompleteness matter? Econometrica 70(5):1805–1839

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meghir C, Pistaferri L (2004) Income variance dynamics and heterogeneity. Econometrica 72(1):1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2007) Offshoring and employment: trends and impacts. OECD Report

  • Rodrik D (1997) Has globalization gone too far?. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheve K, Slaughter MJ (2004) Economic insecurity and the globalization of production. Am J Polit Sci 48(4):662–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmucker A, Seth S (2009) BA-employment panel 1998–2007, Codebook (only in German). FDZ Datenreport 1

  • Senses M (2010) The effects of offshoring on the elasticity of labor demand. J Int Econ 81(1):89–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storesletten K, Telmer C, Yaron A (2004) Cyclical dynamics in idiosyncratic labor market risk. J Pol Econ 112(3):695–717

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wright GC (2014) Revisiting the employment impact of offshoring. Eur Econ Rev 66:63–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Yao Yao.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hogrefe, J., Yao, Y. Offshoring and labor income risk: an empirical investigation. Empir Econ 50, 1045–1063 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0966-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0966-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation