Skip to main content
Log in

Unemployment hysteresis and structural change in Europe

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

“...at present the situation is different. The risks of ‘doing too little’—i.e. that cyclical unemployment becomes structural—outweigh those of ‘doing too much’—that is, excessive upward wage and price pressures.”

Mario Mario Draghi (2014), President of the ECB, Jackson Hole Speech.

Abstract

We examine the unemployment hysteresis hypothesis for 31 European countries, the USA and Japan, using alternative linear and nonlinear unit root tests, taking into account possible structural breaks. Two types of smooth transition models—Exponential Smooth Transition Autoregressive and Asymmetric Exponential Smooth Transition Autoregressive—are employed to account for the nonlinear mean-reverting behaviour in unemployment due to heterogeneity in hiring and firing costs across firms. Four main results emerge: first, the hysteresis hypothesis is rejected for 60 % of the countries in our sample. Second, nonlinear models capture the asymmetries in unemployment dynamics over the business cycle for some countries. Third, many of the series display multiple structural breaks which might point out shifts in mean level of unemployment. Fourth, forecasting powers of our nonlinear models display poor performance against the linear AR specification. The results have policy implications for the debate on the benefits of demand or supply-side policies for tackling the current unemployment problem in Europe.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Blanchard and Summers (1986) point out asymmetries in wage setting process between insiders and outsiders as the main driver of a propagation mechanism in unemployment. They argue that negative shocks contracting number of workers could increase the bargaining power of insiders due to their increasing marginal product. This would lead to a new equilibrium wage rate. This line of reasoning is later critisized in Lindbeck and Snower (2001) which argues that the remaining insiders are not necessarily more secure because in case of negative shocks (i) firms might decide to contract capital and labour services simultaneously provided that they have excess capacity and (ii) the relation between the wage negotiation and employment is not unambiguous due to changes in reservation wage.

  2. In general, short-term demand shocks are considered to have cyclical impacts on unemployment while supply shocks might lead to long-term changes in labour market conditions.

  3. Obviously, as Bean (1997) argues, a “fine tuning” is almost impossible due to high level of uncertainty regarding the economy. However, offsetting policy actions would lead to a “coarse tune” of the economy by means of smoothing the economic activity.

  4. In a similar manner, Yellen (2012) motivates a loose monetary policy stance with FED’s concerns over hysteresis: “To date, I have not seen evidence that hysteresis is occurring to any substantial degree... Nonetheless, the risk that continued high unemployment could eventually lead to more-persistent structural problems underscores the case for maintaining a highly accommodative stance of monetary policy.”

  5. Another reason for unemployment persistence could be the stigmatization of unemployed workers (Blanchard and Diamond 1994).

  6. Blanchard and Summers (1986) also favour a looser form of the definition where coefficients do not add up to one but very close to one (a near unit root process). These two cases are also referred later in the literature as pure hysteresis or partial hysteresis (see Layard et al. 1991; León-Ledesma and McAdam 2004). In this study, the hysteresis term is used to refer to the case where the autoregressive parameter is unity (i.e. a unit root process or pure hysteresis).

  7. Phelps and Zoega (1998) point out other structural factors behind unemployment such as technological change, labour productivity or educational composition of the labour force.

  8. Davis and Haltiwanger (1991) show that job destruction and job creation by US firms display heterogeneity for both cross-sectional and time dimensions for US firms. They argue that job destruction is relatively more volatile over the business cycle and job reallocation displays a countercyclical movement.

  9. Moreover, these causes could be a result of government policies such as compulsory advance notice of layoffs or changes in the financing structure of unemployment compensation dynamics (Hamermesh and Pfann 1996).

  10. In a recent study, Galí (2016) analyses the implications of this framework on optimal monetary policy design.

  11. Koop and Potter (1999) corroborate with these result using TAR model with Bayesian methods. Coakley et al. (2001) also detect nonlinear behaviour in US, UK and Germany unemployment series using Momentum-TAR framework introduced by Enders and Granger (1998).

  12. Recently, Cheng et al. (2014) employs flexible Fourier unit root test; Caporale and Gil-Alana (2007) and Cuestas et al. (2011) use fractional integration along with nonlinear techniques; Pérez-Alonso and Di Sanzo (2011) propose a nonlinear unobserved component model to test for hysteresis. Cuestas and Ordóñez (2011) explore the nonlinearities in unemployment rates of Central and Eastern European countries with ESTAR and LSTAR models. Gustavsson and Österholm (2006) also employ ESTAR model for testing the unemployment hysteresis for five developed countries. Bolat et al. (2014) apply nonlinear panel unit root tests for the Eurozone area.

  13. Later on, Lumsdaine and Papell (1997) extend this methodology with two structural breakpoints alternative, emphasizing that the unit-root test results are sensitive to the number of breaks in the alternative hypothesis.

  14. This correction behaviour could also be motivated as a reflection of the business cycles. A long-run mean reversion would imply that recessions will be followed by a recovery which could be the result of an improvement in expectations, corresponding to a positive demand shock in Bentolila and Bertola (1990). An ESTAR-type adjustment imposes that these countercyclical movements that would move the unemployment level back to equilibrium are not that strong when the series is close to its mean but gets stronger when it gets far away from it. Also, note that employment is a nonstationary process in Bentolila and Bertola (1990) since they conduct their analysis for a given level of demand in order to examine the comparative dynamics. Instead, our study focuses on long-term time series characteristics of unemployment, i.e. considering alternative phases of the cycle, testing the presence of a long-run mean reversion.

  15. The \({B}_\mathrm{L }\) level could also move depending on the magnitude of the impact of the change in severance payments on the threshold levels \({B}_\mathrm{LL}\) or \({B}_{\mathrm{LL'}}\) in the lower regions.

  16. We follow the three-step testing procedure that is described in detail at page 1082 of Christopoulos and León-Ledesma (2010), using Eq. (7) as our base model. The footnotes of the Table 3 also provide details of the estimation.

  17. For the current period, the source of the differences requires an in-depth analysis for the individual countries, which is beyond the scope of this exercise and stands as a good research question for the future.

  18. Hence, we only present the estimation results for AESTAR model in this section. The ESTAR estimation results are not presented due to space considerations but are available upon request.

  19. The nonlinear problem is solved by the sequential quadratic programming method of Gauss 14. The estimation returns the smallest value to fulfil with the restrictions for some parameters. Standard errors are very close to zero for these cases.

  20. For a review of this literature and examples see Teräsvirta et al. (2005) and Ferrara et al. (2015).

  21. For time-inconsistency and resulting free-rider problems in a monetary union that would negatively affect the structural reform incentives, see Chari and Kehoe (2008).

  22. For the impacts of economic governance of Europe on European labour markets, see Ioannou and Stracca (2014).

References

  • Akdoğan K (2014) Asymmetric behaviour of inflation around the target in inflation-targeting countries. Scott J Polit Econ 62(5):486–504

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altavilla C, De Grauwe P (2010) Forecasting and combining competing models of exchange rate determination. Appl Econ 42(27):3455–3480

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arestis P, Mariscal IBF (1998) Capital shortages and asymmetries in UK unemployment. Struct Change Econ Dyn 9(2):189–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ayala A, Cuñado J, Gil-Alana LA (2012) Unemployment hysteresis: empirical evidence for Latin America. J Appl Econ 15(2):213–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bean C (1997) The role of demand-management policies in reducing unemployment. Government options for the labour market, Unemployment policy, pp 83–111

  • Bean C, Mayer C (1989) Capital shortages and persistent unemployment. Econ Policy 4(8):11–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma R, Giuliodori M (2010) The macroeconomic costs and benefits of the EMU and other monetary unions: an overview of recent research. J Econ lit 48(3):603–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentolila S, Bertola G (1990) Firing costs and labour demand: how bad is eurosclerosis? Rev Econ Stud 57(3):381–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bianchi M, Zoega G (1998) Unemployment persistence: does the size of the shock matter? J Appl Econom 13(3):283–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O (2006) European unemployment: the evolution of facts and ideas. Econ Policy 21(45):6–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Summers LH (1986) Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. In: NBER macroeconomics annual 1986, vol 1. MIT Press, pp 15–90

  • Blanchard OJ, Diamond P (1994) Ranking, unemployment duration, and wages. Rev Econ Stud 61(3):417–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolat S, Tiwari AK, Erdayi AU (2014) Unemployment hysteresis in the Eurozone area: evidences from nonlinear heterogeneous panel unit root tests. Appl Econ Lett 21(8):536–540

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Hammour ML (1991) The cleansing effect of recessions. National Bureau of Economic, Research w3922

  • Calmfors L (2001) Unemployment, labour market reform, and monetary union. J Labor Econ 19(2):265–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caner M, Hansen BE (2001) Threshold autoregression with a unit root. Econometrica 69(6):1555–1596

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caporale GM, Gil-Alana LA (2007) Nonlinearities and fractional integration in the US unemployment rate. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 69(4):521–544

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari VV, Kehoe PJ (2008) Time inconsistency and free-riding in a monetary union. J Money Credit Bank 40(7):1329–1356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng SC, Wu TP, Lee KC, Chang T (2014) Flexible Fourier unit root test of unemployment for PIIGS countries. Econ Model 36:142–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christopoulos DK, León-Ledesma MA (2010) Smooth breaks and non-linear mean reversion: Post-Bretton Woods real exchange rates. J Int Money Finance 29(6):1076–1093

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements MP, Smith J (2001) Evaluating forecasts from SETAR models of exchange rates. J Int Money Finance 20(1):133–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coakley J, Fuertes AM, Zoega G (2001) Evaluating the persistence and structuralist theories of unemployment from a nonlinear perspective. Stud Nonlinear Dyn Econom 5(3):179–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cuestas JC, Ordóñez J (2011) Unemployment and common smooth transition trends in Central and Eastern European Countries. Econ Issues 16(2):39

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuestas JC, Gil-Alana LA, Staehr K (2011) A further investigation of unemployment persistence in European transition economies. J Comp Econ 39(4):514–532

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis SJ, Haltiwanger J (1991) Gross job creation, gross job destruction and employment reallocation. National Bureau of Economic, Research w3728

  • Draghi M (2014) Unemployment in the euro area. Speech in annual central bank symposium in Jackson Hole, 22 August 2014. www.ecb.eu

  • Enders W, Granger CWJ (1998) Unit-root tests and asymmetric adjustment with an example using the term structure of interest rates. J Bus Econ Stat 16(3):304–311

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2013) Labour market developments in Europe. European Economy, 6/2013

  • Ferrara L, Marcellino M, Mogliani M (2015) Macroeconomic forecasting during the Great Recession: the return of non-linearity? Int J Forecast 31(3):664–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fosten J, Ghoshray A (2011) Dynamic persistence in the unemployment rate of OECD countries. Econ Model 28(3):948–954

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J (2016) Insider-outsider labor markets, hysteresis and monetary policy, unpublished manuscript

  • Granger CWJ, Teräsvirta T (1993) Modelling nonlinear economic relationships. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustavsson M, Österholm P (2006) Hysteresis and non-linearities in unemployment rates. Appl Econ Lett 13(9):545–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh DS, Pfann GA (1996) Adjustment costs in factor demand. J Econ Lit 34(3):1264–1292

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen BE (1997) Inference in TAR models. Stud Nonlinear Dyn Econom 2(1):1–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Ioannou D, Stracca L (2014) Have the euro area and EU governance worked? Just the facts. Eur J Polit Econ 34:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaeger A, Parkinson M (1994) Some evidence on hysteresis in unemployment rates. Eur Econ Rev 38(2):329–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapetanios G, Shin Y, Snell A (2003) Testing for a unit root in the nonlinear STAR framework. J Econom 112(2):359–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karanassou M, Sala H, Snower DJ (2010) Phillips curves and unemployment dynamics: a critique and a holistic perspective. J Econ Surv 24(1):1–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilian L, Taylor MP (2003) Why is it so difficult to beat the random walk forecast of exchange rates? J Int Econ 60(1):85–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim D, Perron P (2009) Unit root tests allowing for a break in the trend function at an unknown time under both the null and alternative hypotheses. J Econom 148(1):1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koop G, Potter SM (1999) Dynamic asymmetries in US unemployment. J Bus Econ Stat 17(3):298–312

    Google Scholar 

  • Lanzafame M (2010) The nature of regional unemployment in Italy. Empir Econ 39(3):877–895

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard R, Nickell SJ, Jackman R (1991) Unemployment: macroeconomic performance and the labour market. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee J, Strazicich MC (2003) Minimum Lagrange multiplier unit root test with two structural breaks. Rev Econ Stat 85(4):1082–1089

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee J, Strazicich MC (2004) Minimum LM unit root test with one structural break. Manuscript, Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee CC, Chang CP (2008) Unemployment hysteresis in OECD countries: Centurial time series evidence with structural breaks. Econ Model 25(2):312–325

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee JD, Lee CC, Chang CP (2009) Hysteresis in unemployment revisited: evidence from panel LM unit root tests with heterogeneous structural breaks. Bull Econ Res 61(4):325–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • León-Ledesma MA, McAdam P (2004) Unemployment, hysteresis and transition. Scott J Polit Econ 51(3):377–401

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (2001) Insiders versus outsiders. J Econ Perspect 78(1):165–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lumsdaine RL, Papell DH (1997) Multiple trend breaks and the unit-root hypothesis. Rev Econ Stat 79(2):212–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews K, Minford P, Naraidoo R (2008) Vicious and virtuous circles—the political economy of unemployment in interwar UK and USA. Eur J Polit Econ 24(3):605–614

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMillan DG, Wohar ME (2010) Stock return predictability and dividend-price ratio: a nonlinear approach. Int J Finance Econ 15(4):351–365

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen DT (1989) The persistence and indeterminacy of unemployment in search equilibrium. Scand J Econ 91(2):347–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neftci SN (1984) Are economic time series asymmetric over the business cycle? J Polit Econ 92(2):307–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pérez-Alonso A, Di Sanzo S (2011) Unemployment and hysteresis: a nonlinear unobserved components approach. Stud Nonlinear Dyn Econom 15(1):1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Perron P (1989) The great crash, the oil price shock, and the unit root hypothesis. Econom J Econom Soc 57(6):1361–1401

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran H, Timmermann A (1999) Model instability and choice of observation window. UC San Diego Department of Economics, Discussion Papers. pp 1–60

  • Phelps ES (1967) Phillips curves, expectations of inflation and optimal unemployment over time. Economica 34:254–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1968) Money-wage dynamics and labour market equilibrium. J Polit Econ 76:678–711

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1994) Structural slumps: the modern equilibrium theory of unemployment, interests and assets. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES, Zoega G (1998) Natural-rate theory and OECD unemployment. Econ J 108(448):782–801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raurich X, Sala H, Sorolla V (2006) Unemployment, growth, and fiscal policy: new insights on the hysteresis hypothesis. Macroecon Dyn 10(03):285–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Røed K (1997) Hysteresis in unemployment. J Econ Surv 11(4):389–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sibert A, Sutherland A (2000) Monetary union and labour market reform. J Int Econ 51(2):421–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skalin J, Teräsvirta T (2002) Modeling asymmetries and moving equilibria in unemployment rates. Macroecon Dyn 6(02):202–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sollis R (2009) A simple unit root test against asymmetric STAR nonlinearity with an application to real exchange rates in Nordic countries. Econ Model 26(1):118–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strazicich MC, Lee J, Day E (2004) Are incomes converging among OECD countries? Time series evidence with two structural breaks. J Macroecon 26(1):131–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teräsvirta T (1994) Specification, estimation, and evaluation of smooth transition autoregressive models. J Am Stat Assoc 89(425):208–218

    Google Scholar 

  • Teräsvirta T (2006) Forecasting economic variables with nonlinear models. In: Handbook of economic forecasting. pp 413–457

  • Teräsvirta T, Anderson HM (1992) Characterizing nonlinearities in business cycles using smooth transition autoregressive models. J Appl Econom 7(S1):S119–S136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Teräsvirta T, Van Dijk D, Medeiros MC (2005) Linear models, smooth transition autoregressions, and neural networks for forecasting macroeconomic time series: A re-examination. Int J Forecast 21(4):755–774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tong H (1990) Nonlinear time series: a dynamical system approach. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Yellen J (2012) The economic outlook and monetary policy. Speech. At the Money Marketeers of New York University, New York, April 11, 2012. www.federalreserve.gov

  • Zivot E, Andrews DWK (2002) Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock, and the unit-root hypothesis. J Bus Econ Stat 20(1):25–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kurmaş Akdoğan.

Additional information

The views and opinions presented in this study belong to the author and do not necessarily represent those of the Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey or its staff.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Akdoğan, K. Unemployment hysteresis and structural change in Europe. Empir Econ 53, 1415–1440 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1171-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1171-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation