Skip to main content
Log in

The politics of environmental enforcement: the case of the Resource and Conservation Recovery Act

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Does environmental enforcement actions, including states’ strategic responses to neighbors’ policy choices, depend on governor party affiliation? Do governors of different parties use environmental policy instruments differently? Our paper addresses these questions. Accounting for endogeneity and omitted variable biases, we find that Democratic governors on average depress overall inspection rates versus their Republican counterparts, but not the frequency of punitive actions (except in the South). Strategic responses to neighbors do not depend on party affiliation. Finally, treating party affiliation as endogenous and allowing for strategic interaction effects both appear important for our estimations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Aldrich (1983), Baron (1994), Wright and Schaffner (2002), and Moon (2004) argue that party polarization is due to party activists and core partisans who heavily influence primary votes and general elections. Adams and Merrill (2003), Owen and Grofman (2006), and Hummel (2010) model elections as a two-stage process with a primary and a general election, where the constituency in the primary is significantly more partisan. In Owen and Grofman (2006), primary voters are concerned both with candidates’ policy positions and their viability in the general elections; this leads to policy divergence. Adams et al. (2010) incorporate voter turnout (with a voter “alienation threshold”) to explain candidate policy divergence even in close elections. Alternatively, politicians may simply have policy convictions or “character” (Kartik and McAfee 2007) and set policies strictly in accordance with their ideology. In the citizen-candidate model by Osborne and Slivinksi (1996) and Besley and Coate (1997) politicians cannot credibly commit to implement policies that deviate from their own preferences; because voters foresee politicians reneging on all other policy choices, politicians must make campaign promises in accordance with their most preferred policies. The “two constituencies thesis” argue that same-state senators from opposing parties offer different policies because they appeal to different constituencies (Peltzman 1984; Schmidt et al. 1996). Partial convergence models include Lindbeck and Weibull (1993) where elections are probabilistically driven by policy and, e.g., competence. Policy-motivated parties face a trade-off between policy and election chances, converging incompletely toward the median voter.

  2. Decentralized policymaking may lead to inefficiently weak policies because of inter-jurisdictional capital competition or neglected transboundary pollution spillovers (Oates 1972; Silva and Caplan 1997; Kunce and Shogren 2007). Alternatively, decentralization may result in efficient policies or inefficiently strong policies due to absentee capital ownership or cross-hauling of capital (Wellisch 1995; Kunce and Shogren 2005, 2008; McAusland 2002; Lee 2005). There are also informational and political advantages to allocating decision making to the local level where specific environmental benefits, costs, and preferences are more easily taken into account (Oates 1972, 1999; Sigman 2003). Oates and Schwab (1988) find that both centralized and decentralized policymaking yield the first-best policy as long as no political incentives are present, while environmental policy may be too weak/strict with a heterogeneous population of voters or a Leviathan ruler. Fredriksson and Gaston (2000) find that while lobbying incentives differ across decentralized and centralized regimes, the aggregate incentives are equal resulting in equivalent policies across the two institutional designs. Using a median voter model, Roelfsema (2007) argues that environmental regulations in a decentralized system may be either too weak or too strict due to strategic delegation by the median voter. Complete decentralization could help avoid a possible bias due to the majority party in Congress favoring its own home districts, according to Fredriksson et al. (2010).

    Empirical evidence suggests that US states may engage in strategic interaction in their environmental policy making (Fredriksson and Millimet 2002a, b; Fredriksson et al. 2004; Levinson 2003; Konisky 2007). Several studies find evidence of free-riding behavior among countries and US states, including Sigman (2002, 2005, 2014), Helland and Whitford (2003), and Gray and Shadbegian (2004). Banzhaf and Chupp (2012) simulate the trade-offs between decentralized versus uniform centralized control of air pollution from the US electricity sector. The centralized policy outperforms the state policy due to interstate spillovers and the marginal cost functions. Fredriksson and Wollscheid (2014) suggest that political centralization raises the stringency of decentralized environmental policies.

  3. In other policy areas, Reed (2006) and Leigh (2008) find no effect of governor party affiliation on state taxes, while Besley and Case (2003) establish that a higher share of Democratic state legislators is associated with higher state spending. Fredriksson et al. (2013) find the Democratic governors raise taxes more that Republicans in their first incumbency period, but not overall if seen over two terms in office. Ferreira and Gyourko (2009) find no political party difference spending across US mayors, suggesting policy convergence.

  4. These are weaker assumptions than independence of \( \left( {\varepsilon ,v} \right) \). Moreover, heteroscedastic \( \varepsilon \) and \( v \) are allowed (Newey et al. 1990).

  5. Heckman (1979) corrects for selection bias using the control function approach.

  6. 2SLS can still work in the case of nonlinear models in endogenous variables, but its estimation requires special care. For example, one may be tempted to implement it by running a “forbidden regression” (Wooldridge 2010) without treating the nonlinear terms properly as separate endogenous variables.

  7. These three weighting schemes differ in terms of their respective definition of “neighbors.” Contiguous neighbors are those bordering a state. The BEA regional classification is based on the homogeneity in various economic and social factors, and the Crone classification is based on similarities in economic activity. Irrespective of weighting schemes, the weights are equal for all neighboring states, and zero for non-neighboring states. As noted in Fredriksson and Millimet (2002a), the BEA regional classification system was introduced by the US Bureau of Economic Analysis in the 1950s and has remained unchanged. Crone’s (1998/1999) regional breakdown for US states is based on cluster analysis.

  8. Our treatment variable would not be well defined if we were to include candidates from other political parties.

  9. Separate 2SLS models are run in this case.

  10. We also repeat our analysis with standard errors clustered at the state level. The results remain unchanged.

  11. Note that when party affiliation is treated as endogenous, six observations have missing information on vote margin and thus a small discrepancy arises between the sample sizes in Specification A and Specifications B and C, respectively.

  12. The similarity in punitive actions may indicate that firms behave similarly (in terms of violations) no matter the party affiliation of the governor in office; this is a topic of further research.

  13. We are grateful to a referee for pointing this out.

  14. While we only have suggestive evidence of this behavior, further research may address this issue.

  15. Southern states are Alabama, Arkansas, Delaware, Florida, Georgia, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maryland, Mississippi, North Carolina, Oklahoma, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas, Virginia, and West Virginia.

  16. We re-estimated the same models by bootstrapping the entire estimation process. The qualitative results remain unchanged (See Table 7 in “Appendix”).

References

  • Adams J, Merrill S III (2003) Voter turnout and candidate strategies in American elections. J Polit 65:161–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Adams J, Brunell TL, Grofman B, Merrill S III (2010) Why candidate divergence should be expected to be just as great (or even greater) in competitive seats as in non-competitive ones. Public Choice 145:417–433

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albouy DY (2011) Do voters affect or elect policies? A new perspective. With evidence from the U.S. Senate. Elect Stud 30:162–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldrich JA (1983) A Downsian spatial model with party activism. Am Poli Sci Rev 77:974–990

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansolabehere S, Snyder JM Jr (2006) Party control of state government and the distribution of public expenditures. Scandi J Econ 108:547–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banzhaf HS, Chupp BA (2012) Fiscal federalism and interjurisdictional externalities: new results and an application to US Air pollution. J Public Econ 96:449–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron DD (1994) Electoral competition with informed and uninformed voters. Am Poli Sci Rev 88:33–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beland L-P, Boucher V (2015) Polluting politics. Econ Lett 137:176–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Case A (2003) Political institutions and policy choices: evidence from the United States. J Econ Lit 41:7–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Coate S (1997) An economic model of representative democracy. Quart J Econ 112:85–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bound J, Jaeger DA, Baker RM (1995) Problems with instrumental variables estimation when the correlation between the instruments and the endogenous explanatory variable is weak. J Am Stat Assoc 90:443–450

    Google Scholar 

  • Crone T (1998/1999) Using state indexes to define economic regions in the U.S. J Econ Soc Meas 25:259–275

  • Downs A (1957) An economic theory of political action in a democracy. J Polit Econ 65:135–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira F, Gyourko J (2009) Do political parties matter? Evidence from U.S. cities. Quart J Econ 124:349–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Gaston, N (2000) Environmental governance in federal systems: the effects of capital competition and lobby groups. Econ Inq 38:501–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Millimet DL (2002a) Strategic interaction and the determination of environmental policy across U.S. states. J Urban Econ 51:101–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Millimet DL (2002b) Is there a ‘California effect’ in US environmental policymaking? Reg Sci Urban Econ 32:737–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Wang L (2011) Sex and environmental policy in the U.S. House of representatives. Econ Lett 113:228–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Wollscheid JR (2014) Environmental decentralization and political centralization. Ecol Econ 107:402–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, List JA, Millimet DL (2004) Chasing the smokestack: strategic policymaking with multiple instruments. Reg Sci Urban Econ 34:387–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Matschke X, Minier J (2010) Environmental policy in majoritarian systems. J Environ Econ Manag 59:177–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Wang L, Mamun KA (2011) Are politicians office or policy motivated? The case of U.S. governors’ environmental policies. J Environ Econ Manag 62:241–253

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson PG, Wang L, Warren PL (2013) Party politics, governors and economic policy. Southern Econ J 80:106–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garmann S (2014) Do government ideology and fragmentation matter for reducing CO2-emissions? Empirical evidence from OECD countries. Ecol Econ 105:1–10

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gray WB, Shadbegian RJ (2004) ‘Optimal’ pollution abatement-whose benefits matter, and how much? J Environ Econ Manag 47:510–534

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helland E, Whitford AB (2003) Pollution incidence and political jurisdiction: evidence from the TRI. J Environ Econ Manag 46:403–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummel P (2010) Flip-flopping from primaries to general elections. J Public Econ 94:1020–1027

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Innes R, Mitra A (2015) Parties, politics, and regulation: evidence from Clean Air Act enforcement. Econ Inq 53:522–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kartik N, McAfee RP (2007) Signaling character in electoral competition. Am Econ Rev 97:852–870

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kelejian HH, Prucha IR (1998) A generalized spatial two-stage least squares procedure for estimating a spatial autoregressive model with autoregressive disturbances. J Real Estate Finance Econ 17:99–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konisky DM (2007) Regulatory competition and environmental enforcement: is there a race to the bottom? Am J Polit Sci 51:853–872

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunce M, Shogren JF (2005) On interjurisdictional competition and environmental federalism. J Environ Econ Manag 50:212–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunce M, Shogren JF (2007) Destructive interjurisdictional competition: firm, capital and labor mobility in a model of direct emission control. Ecol Econ 60:543–549

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kunce M, Shogren JF (2008) Efficient decentralized fiscal and environmental policy: a dual purpose Henry George tax. Ecol Econ 65(3):569–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee K (2005) Absentee ownership of immobile factors and environmental policies in a federation. Environ Resour Econ 32:407–417

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee DS, Lemieux T (2010) Regression discontinuity designs in economics. J Econ Lit 48:281–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee DS, Moretti E, Butler MJ (2004) Do voters affect or elect policies? Evidence from the U.S. house. Quart J Econ 119:807–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leigh A (2008) Estimating the impact of partisanship on policy settings and economic outcomes: a regression discontinuity approach. Euro J Polit Econ 24:256–268

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinson A (2003) Environmental regulatory competition: a status report and some new evidence. Natl Tax J 56:91–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Weibull JW (1993) A model of political equilibrium in a representative democracy. J Public Econ 51:195–209

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List JA, Sturm DM (2006) How elections matter: theory and evidence from environmental policy. Quart J Econ 121:1249–1281

    Google Scholar 

  • McAusland C (2002) Cross-hauling of polluting factors. J Environ Econ Manag 44:448–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCrary J, Royer H (2011) The effect of female education on fertility and infant health: evidence from school entry policies using exact date of birth. Am Econ Rev 101:158–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millimet DL (2014) Environmental federalism: a survey of the empirical literature. Case West Reserve Law Rev 64:1669–1757

    Google Scholar 

  • Moon W (2004) Party activists, campaign resources and candidate position taking: theory, tests and applications. Br J Polit Sci 34:611–633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumayer E (2003) Are left-wing party strength and corporatism good for the environment? Evidence from panel analysis of air pollution in OECD countries. Ecol Econ 45:203–220

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Newey WK, Powell JL, Vella F (1990) Nonparametric estimation of triangular simultaneous equation models. Econometrica 67:565–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE (1999) An essay on fiscal federalism. J Econ Lit 37:1120–1149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oates WE, Schwab RM (1988) Economic competition among jurisdictions: efficiency enhancing or distortion inducing? J Public Econ 35:333–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborne MJ, Slivinksi A (1996) A model of political competition with citizen-candidates. Quart J Econ 111:65–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G, Grofman B (2006) Two-stage electoral competition in two-party contests: persistent divergence of party positions. Soc Choice Welf 26:547–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman S (1984) Constituent interest and congressional voting. J Law Econ 27:181–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed RW (2006) Democrats, republicans, and taxes: evidence that political parties matter. J Public Econ 90:725–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roelfsema H (2007) Strategic delegation of environmental policy making. J Environ Econ Manag 53:270–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt AM, Kenny LW, Morton RB (1996) Evidence on electoral accountability in the U.S. senate: are unfaithful agents really punished? Econ Inq 34:545–567

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sigman H (2002) International spillovers and water quality in rivers: do countries free ride? Am Econ Rev 92:1152–1159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sigman H (2003) Letting states do the dirty work: state responsibility for federal environmental legislation. Natl Tax J 56:107–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sigman H (2005) Tranboundary spillovers and decentralization of environmental policies. J Env Econ Manag 50:82–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sigman H (2014) Decentralization and environmental quality: an international analysis of water pollution levels and variation. Land Econ 90:114–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silva ECD, Caplan AJ (1997) Transboundary pollution control in federal systems. J Environ Econ Manag 34:82–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sjöberg E, Xu J (2018) An empirical study of US environmental federalism: RCRA enforcement from 1998 to 2011. Ecol Econ 147:253–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stafford SL (2002) The effect of punishment on firm compliance with hazardous waste regulations. J Environ Econ Manag 44:290–308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wellisch D (1995) Locational choices of firms and decentralized environmental policy with various instruments. J Public Econ 37:270–310

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd edn. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright GC, Schaffner BF (2002) The influence of party: evidence from state legislatures. Am Polit Sci Rev 96:367–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the helpful referees, Dann Millimet, Hem Paudel, Stuart Rosenthal, and participants at presentations at Resources for the Future (RFF) and the Workshop on the Political Economy of Sustainable Development, Montpellier, for useful comments and suggestions on earlier versions of this paper, and David Konisky and James Snyder for kindly sharing data. The usual disclaimers apply.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Per G. Fredriksson.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 7 Control function results based on bootstrapped standard errors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Fredriksson, P.G., Wang, L. The politics of environmental enforcement: the case of the Resource and Conservation Recovery Act. Empir Econ 58, 2593–2613 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01654-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01654-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation