Skip to main content
Log in

Rational populists: the social consequences of shared narratives

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study a simple opinion dynamic model where a number of influencers have the possibility of conditioning it by supporting one of two alternative narratives. Influencers choose the narrative to support in order to optimize their return. They can therefore choose to support a narrative that is socially dysfunctional with which they need not agree with, insofar as the environmental conditions make it convenient. We show in particular under what conditions the dynamic leads to social polarization, that is, eventual takeover of one narrative over the other. The critical factors in this regard are the persuasion strength of the narratives and the number of influencers who are active. Stronger persuasion and a larger number of influencers both favor the takeover of one narrative over the other. In particular, simulation results suggest that even small changes in persuasion strength may cause major changes in the social dynamic and sudden regime shifts. We discuss the policy implications of these results, with an eye to current trends in online media in reinforcement of persuasion strength, e.g. by deploying artificial bots that reverberate one narrative at the expense of the others.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abts K, van Kessel S (2015) Populism. International Encyclopedia of the social and behavioral sciences. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 609–612

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Ozdaglar A, Parandeh Gheibi A (2010) Spread of (mis)information in social networks. Games and Economic Behavior 70:194–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acerbi A, Sacco PL (2018) Folk-economic beliefs as “evidential fiction”: Using narratives to debunk conceptual fallacies and “fake news” and put the economic public discourse back on track. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 41:e159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amante A (2019) Half of Italians want ‘strongman’ in power, survey shows. Reuters, December 6, https://www.reuters.com/article/us-italy-politics-survey/half-of-italians-want-strongman-in-power-survey-shows-idUSKBN1YA1X5. Accessed December 8, 2019

  • Antoci A, Bellanca N, Galdi G (2018) At the relational crossroads: Narrative selection, contamination, biodiversity in trans-local contexts. J Econ Behav Organ 150:98–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashraf N, Camerer CF, Loewenstein G (2005) Adam Smith, behavioral economist. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19:131–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bacchetta P, Tille C, van Wincoop E (2012) Self-fulfilling risk panics. Am Econ Rev 102:3674–3700

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassi A, Ferrara E (2016) Social bots distort the 2016 US presidential election online discussion. First Monday 21:11, November 7 http://firstmonday.org/article/view/7090/5653

  • Battiston P, Stanca L (2015) Boundedly rational opinion dynamics in social networks: Does indegree matter? J Econ Behav Organ 119:400–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • BBC (2019) Europe and right-wing nationalism: a country-by-country guide. BBC News, November 13, 2019, https://bbc.com/news/world-europe-36130006. Accessed December 8, 2019

  • Berning CC, Ziller C (2017) Social trust and radical right-wing populist party preferences. Acta Politica 52:198–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Verdier T (2001) The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences. J Econ Theory 97:298–319

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisin A, Topa G (2003) Empirical models of cultural transmission. J Eur Econ Assoc 1:363–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd B (2009) On the origin of stories. Belknap Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boyer P, Petersen MB (2018) Fold-Economic beliefs: an evolutionary cognitive model. Behav Brain Sci 41:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buechel B, Hellman T, Piechler MM (2014) The dynamics of continuous cultural traits in social networks. J Econ Theory 154:274–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buechel B, Hellman T, Klössner S (2015) Opinion dynamics and wisdom under conformity. J Econ Dyn Control 52:240–257

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bursting P (2003) The impact of public opinion on public policy: a review and an agenda. Political Research Quarterly 56:29–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campodónico H, Carbonnier G, Tezanos Vázquez S (2017) Alternative development narratives, policies and outcomes in the Andean region. Revue Internationale de Politique de Dévelopement 9:3–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier P (2016) The cultural foundations of economic failure: a conceptual toolkit. J Econ Behav Organ 126:5–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G, Jeanne O (1997) Conspicuous consumption, snobbing and conformism. J Public Econ 66:55–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ding F, Liu Y, Shen B, Si XM (2010) An evolutionary game theory model of binary opinion formation. Physica A 389:1745–1752

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2018) A new European Agenda for Culture. Brussels, COM(2018) 267 final, https://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/PDF/?uri=CELEX:52018DC0267&from=en. Accessed December 8, 2019

  • Falk A, Tirole J (2016) Narratives imperatives and moral reasoning. Mimeo, TSE

  • Farmer REA (1999) The macroeconomics of self-fulfilling prophecies. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara E (2017) Disinformation and social bot operation in the run up to the 2017 French presidential election. arXiv:1707.00086[cs.SI]

  • Frydman R, Goldberg MD (2013) Change and expectations in macroeconomic models: Recognizing the limits to knowability. J Econ Methodol 20:118–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil de Zuniga H, Veenstra A, Vraga E, Shah D (2010) Digital democracy: reimagining pathways to political participation. Journal of Information Technology & Politics 7:36–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon S (2015) The relationship between national well-being and xenophobia in a divided society: The case of South Africa. African Review of Economics and Finance 7:80–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Gottschall J (2012) The storytelling animal: How stories make us human. Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Green EGT, Deschamps JC, Pàez D (2005) Variations of individualism and collectivism within and between 20 countries. A typological analysis. J Cross-Cult Psychol 36:321–339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hale Williams M (2010) Can leopards change their spots? Between xenophobia and trans-ethnic populism among West European far right parties. Nationalism and Ethnic Politics 16:111–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison P (2011) Adam Smith and the history of the Invisible Hand. J Hist Ideas 72:29–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Hauk E, Saez-Marti M (2002) On the cultural transmission of corruption. J Econ Theory 107:311–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs DA Jr (1979) The mass public and macroeconomic performance: the dynamic of public opinion toward unemployment and inflation. Am J Polit Sci 23:705–731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howard PN, Kollanyi B (2016) Bot, #StrongerIn, and Brexit: Computational propaganda during the UK-EU referendum. arXiv:1606:06356[cs.SI]

  • Katona Z (2015) Competing for influencers in a social network. SSRN Electronic Journal 2335679

  • Laclau E (2005) On populist reason. Verso, London

  • Lindeberg R, Rolander N (2019) Shock poll has Sweden Nationalists more emboldened than ever. Bloomberg, November 17, https://bloomberg.com/news/articles/2019-11-17/shock-poll-insweden-has-nationalists- more-emboldened-than-ever. Accessed December 8, 2019

  • Mesoudi A (2011) Cultural evolution: How Darwinian theory can explain human culture and synthesis the social sciences. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt B, Tormey S (2014) Rethinking populism: Politics, mediatisation and political style. Political Studies 62:381–397

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oatley K (1999) Why fiction may be twice as true as fact: Fiction as cognitive and emotional simulation. Rev Gen Psychol 3:101–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oatley K (2016) Fiction: Simulation of social worlds. Trends Cogn Sci 20:618–628

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panebianco F (2014) Socialization networks and the transmission of interethnic attitudes. J Econ Theory 150:583–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prummer A (2018) Religious and cultural leaders. Preprint, Queen Mary University of London

  • Prummer A, Siedlarek JP (2017) Community leaders and preservation of cultural traits. J Econ Theory 168:143–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rojas H, Puig-i-Abril E (2009) Mobilizers mobilized: Information, expression, mobilization and participation in the digital age. J Comput.-Mediat Commun 14:902–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rolls ET (2013) What are emotional states, and why do we have them? Emot Rev 5:241–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild E (1994) Adam Smith and the invisible hand. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 84:319–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubin PH (2003) Folk economics. Southern Economic Journal 70:157–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schaller M (2006) Parasites, behavioral defenses, and the social psychological mechanisms through which cultures are evoked. Psychol Inq 17:96–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shiller RJ (2017) Narrative economics. American Economic Review 107:967–1004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Snower DJ (2016) Thriving through balance. J Econ Behav Organ 126:1–4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sperber D (1985) Anthropology and psychology: Towards an epidemiology of representations. Man 20:73–89

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sperber D, Clément F, Heinz C, Mascaro O, Mercier H, Origgi G, Wilson D (2010) Epistemic vigilance. Mind and Language 25:359–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stella M, Ferrara E, De Domenico M (2018) Bots sustain and inflate striking opposition in online social systems. arXiv:1802:07292[psyhics.soc-ph]

  • Stockmann D, Gallagher ME (2011) Remote control: How the media sustain authoritarian rule in China. Comparative Political Studies 44:436–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuckett D, Nikolic M (2017) The role of conviction and narrative in decision-making under radical uncertainty. Theory and Psychology 27:501–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Verdier T, Zenou Y (2018) Cultural leader and the dynamics of assimilation. J Econ Theory 175:374–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yilmaz F (2012) Right-wing hegemony and immigration: How the populisr far-right achieved hegemony through the immigration debate in Europe. Curr Sociol 60:368–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to express their sincere appreciation to the anonymous reviewers for their signicant suggestions from which the paper has been substantially improved.

Funding

This research was supported by the Italian Ministry of Education (MIUR): “Dipartimenti di Eccellenza Program (2018-2022)”, Department of Economics and Business, University of Sassari.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Pier Luigi Sacco.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interests

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Mathematical Appendix A: the dynamic system

The representative influencer has to solve the following optimization problem:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\underset{G\in \lbrack 0,1]}{MAX}\int\limits_{0}^{+\infty }\left\{ G^{\alpha }\left[ \overline{G}(N-1)\right]^{\beta }n^{\gamma }+(1-G)^{\alpha }\left[ (\overline{1-G})(N-1)\right]^{\beta }(1-n)^{\gamma }\right.\\ &&\qquad\qquad\quad\left.+\delta n+\varepsilon (1-n)\vphantom{\left[ \overline{G}(N-1)\right]^{\beta }}\right\} e^{-rt}dt \end{array} $$
(11)

subject to the dynamic constraint (2). We can write the current value Hamiltonian function as:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} H(n,G,\lambda ) \!&=&\!G^{\alpha }\left[ \overline{G}(N-1)\right]^{\beta }n^{\gamma }+(1-G)^{\alpha }\left[ (\overline{1-G})(N-1)\right]^{\beta }(1-n)^{\gamma }\\ &&+\delta n+\varepsilon (1-n)+\lambda \left[ n(1-n)(a+bn)+c \left[ G+\overline{G}(N\!-1)\right] (1\!-n)\right.\\ &&\left.-c \left[ 1-G+(\overline{1-G})(N-1)\right] n\right] \end{array} $$

where λ is the multiplier associated to the n variable. The conditions that are derived from the Maximum principle are:

  1. 1.

    The value of G is chosen in order to maximize H(n, G, λ), given the values of n and λ. By computing the partial derivative of H(n, G, λ) with respect to G (remind that, by assumption, α + β = 1) one has:

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{\partial H(n,G,\lambda )}{\partial G} &=&\alpha (N-1)^{\beta }\left[ n^{\gamma }-(1-n)^{\gamma }\right] +c \lambda (1-n)+c \lambda n \\ &=&\alpha (N-1)^{\beta }\left[ n^{\gamma }-(1-n)^{\gamma }\right] +c \lambda \end{array} $$

    It results that \(\frac {\partial H(n,G,\lambda )}{\partial G}=0\) along the curve:

    $$ \lambda =\widetilde{\lambda }(n):=\frac{\alpha (N-1)}{c}^{\beta }\left[ (1-n)^{\gamma }-n^{\gamma }\right] $$
    (12)

    where \(\widetilde {\lambda }^{\prime }(n)<0\), \(\widetilde {\lambda }(0)=\frac { \alpha (N-1)}{c}^{\beta }>0\), \(\widetilde {\lambda }(1)=-\frac {\alpha (N-1)}{c }^{\beta }<0\), and \(\widetilde {\lambda }(1/2)=0\). The (12) curve separates, in the plane (n, λ) (see Fig. 1), the region where the representative influencer chooses G = 1 (above the curve) from the region where she chooses G = 0 (below the curve).

  2. 2.

    The dynamics of n and λ are given by (remind that, ex post, one has \(\overline {G}=G\) and \(\overline {1-G}=1-G\)):

    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \overset{\cdot }{n}&=&\frac{\partial H(n,G,\lambda )}{\partial \lambda } =n(1-n)(a+bn)+cN(G-n) \end{array} $$
    (13)
    $$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }&=&r\lambda -\frac{\partial H(n,G,\lambda )}{ \partial n}\\ &=&r\lambda -\left[ \gamma (N-1)^{\beta }Gn^{\gamma -1}+\gamma (N-1)^{\beta }(1-G)(1-n)^{\gamma -1}+\delta -\varepsilon \right]\\&&-\lambda \left[ (1-2n)(\alpha +\beta n)+\beta n(1-n)-cN\right]\\ &=&\lambda \left\{ r+3bn^{2}+2\left( a-b\right) n-a+cN\right\}\\ &&-\gamma (N-1)^{\beta }\left[ Gn^{\gamma -1}+(1-G)(1-n)^{\gamma -1}\right] -\delta +\varepsilon \end{array} $$
    (14)

Moreover, the usual transversality condition has to be satisfied:

$$ \underset{t\rightarrow +\infty }{\lim}\lambda (t)n(t)e^{-rt}=0 $$

Here, it is always satisfied along the trajectories that lead to an equilibrium.

Mathematical Appendix B: basic mathematical results

Above the curve (12) the representative influencer chooses G = 1, and the system (13)-(14) becomes:

$$ \overset{\cdot }{n}=n(1-n)(a+bn)+c N(1-n) $$
(15)
$$ \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }=\lambda \left[ r+3bn^{2}+2\left( a-b\right) n-a+cN \right] -\gamma (N-1)^{\beta }n^{\gamma -1}-\delta +\varepsilon $$
(16)

while below the curve (12) the representative influencer chooses G = 0, and the system (13)-(14) becomes:

$$ \overset{\cdot }{n}=n(1-n)(a+bn)-cNn $$
(17)
$$ \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }=\lambda \left[ r+3bn^{2}+2\left( a-b\right) n-a+c N\right] -\gamma (N-1)^{\beta }(1-n)^{\gamma -1}-\delta +\varepsilon $$
(18)

The systems (15)-(16) and (17)-(18) are triangular, that is, \(\overset {\cdot }{n}\) only depends on the value of n, whereas \(\overset {\cdot }{\lambda }\) depends on both n and λ. Such structure is not anomalous for this type of control problems (bang-bang control) where the control variable (G in our case) jumps between two alternative states (0 and 1 in our case). Obviously, the value of λ plays an important role anyway in the dynamic of n, as the separatrix (12) draws the border between the region where the state (n, λ) is such that the representative influencer chooses G = 1 (above the curve), and the region where the opposite happens.

Moreover, the equilibrium value \(\overline {n}\) of n is determined by the equation \(\overset {\cdot }{n}=0\). Furthermore, to this equilibrium value there will correspond an equilibrium of the dynamic system if the equation \( \overset {\cdot }{\lambda }=0\) is met (given \(\overline {n}\)) for a value \( \overline {\lambda }\) of λ that belongs to the ‘right’ region. More specifically, it is required that:

  1. 1)

    If \(\overline {n}\) is the value of n at which the right hand side of equation (15) equals zero, and \(\overline {\lambda }\) is the value of λ at which (given \(\overline {n}\)) the right hand side of equation (16) equals zero, then the state (\(\overline {n}, \overline {\lambda }\)) is a stationary point of the system (15)-(16) only if it lies above the separatrix curve (12).

  2. 2)

    Likewise, if \(\overline {n}\) is the value of n at which the right hand side of equation (17) equals zero, and \(\overline {\lambda }\) is the value of λ at which the right hand side of equation (18) equals zero, then the state (\(\overline {n},\overline { \lambda }\)) is a stationary point of the system (17)-(18) only if it lies below the separatrix curve (12).

Taking into account the above, the state n = 1 corresponds to a stationary state of the system (15)-(16) if posing n = 1 in equation \(\overset {\cdot }{\lambda }=0\), the latter is satisfied for a value of λ larger than \(\widetilde {\lambda }(1)\), that is:

$$ \frac{\gamma (N-1)^{\beta }+\delta -\varepsilon }{r+b+a+cN}>-\frac{\alpha (N-1)}{c}^{\beta } $$
(19)

Condition (19) is satisfied if (ceteris paribus) the value of the influencers’ ‘persuasion strength’ c and that of the difference δε are high enough, whatever the signs of the parameters a and b (which characterize the natural dynamic of narratives (1)). Notice that (19) can be satisfied even if δε < 0; that is, even if the diffusion of Narrative 1 is undesirable in terms of the influencers’own inclinations.

Analogously, the state n = 0 corresponds to a stationary state of the system (17)-(18) if posing n = 0 in the equation \( \overset {\cdot }{\lambda }=0\), the latter is satisfied for a value of λ smaller than \(\widetilde {\lambda }(0)\), that is:

$$ \frac{\gamma (N-1)^{\beta }+\delta -\varepsilon }{r-a+cN}<\frac{\alpha (N-1) }{c}^{\beta } $$
(20)

Condition (20) is satisfied if the value of c is high enough and that of the difference δε is low enough, whatever the signs of the parameters a and b. Condition (20) can be satisfied even if δε > 0; that is, even if the diffusion of Narrative 2 is undesirable in terms of the influencers’own inclinations.

1.1 B.1 Dynamic with G = 1 (above the curve (12))

Equation (15) can be written as:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \overset{\cdot }{n}&=&n(1-n)(a+bn)+c N(1-n)\\ &=&(1-n)\left[ n(a+bn)+c N\right] \end{array} $$
(21)

where \(\overset {\cdot }{n}=0\) for n = 1 and for:

$$ n=-\frac{c N}{a}\text{ \ }if\text{ \ }a\neq 0\wedge b=0 $$
$$ n=-\frac{1}{2b}\left( a-\sqrt{a^{2}-4b c N}\right) ,\text{ }-\frac{1}{2b} \left( a+\sqrt{a^{2}-4b c N}\right) \text{ \ }if\text{ }b\neq 0 $$
(22)

It may be useful to consider the problem of the existence of the equilibrium values of n by means of a geometrical approach. To this purpose, we split the expression in square brackets in the equation (21) in two parts: n(a + bn) and cN. The graph of the former is a parabola (with upward concavity if b > 0) that meets the n axis at n = 0 and n = −a/b. By adding the (positive) constant cN we operate an upward translation of the parabola (the more upward, the stronger the ”persuasion capacity” c and the number of agents N). This causes in turn a shift of the zeros of \(\overset {\cdot }{n}\) in different directions according to the sign of b (they move further if b < 0, and get closer if b > 0). Remembering that n = −a/b is the internal steady state value of the natural dynamic (1), where both narratives coexist at equilibrium, we then notice that the cN term is the shift that is operated by the persuasive impact of Narrative 1 via the influencers’action. Moreover, if b < 0, we will have at most a single value of n ∈ (0, 1) at which \(\overset {\cdot }{n}\) goes to zero, whereas if b > 0 we could have two such values of n. If the value of cN is high enough, then no equilibrium value of n can belong to the interval (0,1).

Let us now analyze the stability properties of the equilibria of system (15)-(16). The Jacobian matrix of system (15)-(16) is:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} J_{G=1}(n,\lambda )\!\!&=&\!\!\left( \begin{array}{cc} \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n} & \frac{\partial \overset{ \cdot }{n}}{\partial \lambda } \\ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }}{\partial n} & \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }}{\partial \lambda } \end{array} \right)\\ \!\!&=&\!\!\left( \begin{array}{cc} (1-n)(a+2bn)-\left[ n(a+bn)+c N\right] & 0 \\ \lambda \left[ 6bn+2\left( a-b\right) \right] +\gamma (1-\gamma )(N - 1)^{\beta }n^{\gamma -2} & r + 3bn^{2} + 2\left( a - b\right) n - a + c N \end{array} \right) \end{array} $$

with eigenvalues:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n}=(1-n)(a+2bn)-\left[ n(a+bn)+c N\right] \text{ \ in direction of the }n-\text{axis} $$
(23)
$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }}{\partial \lambda } =r+3bn^{2}+2\left( a-b\right) n-a+c N $$

Note that by evaluating (23) at the equilibrium with n = 1 (when existing) we get:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n}=-a-b-cN<0\ \ if\ \ c>-\frac{ a+b}{N} $$
(24)

while evaluating it at an equilibrium with \(n=\overline {n}<1\)we get:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n}=(1-\overline{n})(a+2b \overline{n}) $$

From (24) we can conclude that when c and/or N are large enough, n = 1 becomes reachable as the associated eigenvalue is surely negative.

1.2 B.2 Dynamic with G = 0 (below the separatrix (12))

Equation (17) can be written as:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \overset{\cdot }{n}&=&n(1-n)(a+bn)-c Nn\\ &=&n\left[ (1-n)(a+bn)-c N\right] \end{array} $$
(25)

where \(\overset {\cdot }{n}=0\) for n = 0 and for:

$$ n=1-\frac{c N}{a}\text{ \ }if\text{ \ }a\neq 0\wedge b=0 $$
$$ n=-\frac{1}{2b}\left( a - b + \sqrt{(a + b)^{2} - 4b c N}\right) ,\!\text{ \ }\frac{1}{ 2b}\left( -a + b + \sqrt{(a + b)^{2} - 4b c N}\right) \text{ \ }if\text{ }b\!\neq\! 0 $$
(26)

By following, as above, a geometrical approach, we can split the expression in square brackets of the equation (25) into the sum of two elements: (1 − n)(a + bn) and − cN. The graph of the former is a parabola (with upward concavity if b < 0, the opposite of what occurs for the case with G = 1), that meets the n axis at n = 1 and n = −a/b. By subtracting the (positive) constant cN we get a downward translation of the parabola, which causes a shift of the zeros of \(\overset {\cdot }{n}\) in different directions according to the sign of b. If b < 0, we will have at most a single value of n ∈ (0, 1) at which \(\overset {\cdot }{n}\) goes to zero, whereas if b > 0 we could have two such values of n. If the value of cN is high enough, then no equilibrium value of n can belong to the interval (0, 1).

The stability properties of the equilibria of system (17)-(18) are determined by the Jacobian matrix of system (17)-(18):

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} J_{G=0}(n,\lambda )\!\!&=&\!\!\left( \begin{array}{cc} \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n} & \frac{\partial \overset{ \cdot }{n}}{\partial \lambda } \\ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }}{\partial n} & \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }}{\partial \lambda } \end{array} \right)\\ \!\!&=&\!\!\left( \begin{array}{cc} \left[ (1 - n)(a + bn) - c N\right] + n\left( b - a - 2bn\right) & 0 \\ \lambda \left[ 6bn + 2\left( a - b\right) \right] + c(1 - c )(N - 1)^{\beta }(1 - n)^{c -2} & r + 3bn^{2} + 2\left( a - b\right) n - a + cN \end{array} \right) \end{array} $$

The eigenvalues are:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n} = \left[ (1-n)(a+bn)-c N\right] +n\left( b-a-2bn\right) \text{ \ in direction of the }n-\text{axis} $$
(27)

and:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{\lambda }}{\partial \lambda } =r+3bn^{2}+2\left( a-b\right) n-a+c N $$

Note that by evaluating (27) at the equilibrium with n = 0 (when existing), we get:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n}=a-c N<0\ \ if\ \ c>\frac{a}{N } $$
(28)

while evaluating it at an equilibrium with \(n=\overline {n}>0\) we get:

$$ \frac{\partial \overset{\cdot }{n}}{\partial n}\mathbf{=}\overline{n}\left( b-a-2b\overline{n}\right) $$

Again as above, we find that strong persuasion and/or a high number of influencers, by ensuring that the eigenvalue evaluated at the steady state n = 0 in (28) is certainly negative, guarantees the reachability of the equilibrium where only Narrative 2 is present.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Antoci, A., Ferilli, G., Russu, P. et al. Rational populists: the social consequences of shared narratives. J Evol Econ 30, 479–506 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-019-00659-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-019-00659-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation