Skip to main content
Log in

Monotonicity violations under plurality with a runoff: the case of French presidential elections

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

A voting rule is monotonic if a winning candidate never becomes a loser by being raised in voters’ rankings of candidates, ceteris paribus. Plurality with a runoff is known to fail monotonicity. To see how widespread this failure is, we focus on French presidential elections since 1965. We identify mathematical conditions that allow a logically conceivable scenario of vote shifts between candidates that may lead to a monotonicity violation. We show that eight among the ten elections held since 1965 (those in 1965 and 1974 being the exceptions) exhibit this theoretical vulnerability. To be sure, the conceived scenario of vote shifts that enables a monotonicity violation may not be plausible under the political context of the considered election. Thus, we analyze the political landscape of these eight elections and argue that for two of them (2002 and 2007 elections), the monotonicity violation scenario was plausible within the conjuncture of the time.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Black (1958) and Brams and Fishburn (2002) give a comprehensive account of this condition, which should be distinguished from other stronger monotonicity conditions that are more oriented to the implementability of collective choice rules. For those different monotonicities of implementation theory, once can see Maskin and Sjöström (2002).

  2. Felsenthal and Nurmi (2017) present a detailed account of monotonicity failures.

  3. See Doron and Kronick (1977) for arguments against using non-monotonic voting rules.

  4. Golder (2005) discusses the use of PwR in different elections around the world.

  5. The qualification “restricted” implicitly assumes that voters’ preferences do not change between the two rounds and that strategic voting is not a concern. See Conitzer and Sandholm (2005) for a formalization of PwR as a protocol.

  6. Under this adaptation that overlooks preferences, the question on whether voters’ preferences change between the two rounds vanish. In a similar vein, strategic voting is not a concern. See Footnote 5.

  7. Although we postpone the discussion on the runoff outcome to the next section where we use real election data, we note right away that the condition “\({C}_{1}\) not exceeding the threshold of 50 votes” ensures that \({C}_{1}\) does not become the PwR winner without needing a runoff.

  8. on that particularly prevails when the elec.

  9. Although in French politics candidates typically stand out more than the party they are associated with, to be more informative to a larger audience, we gave the party names in the tables and used their English translations.

  10. The data is from:.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1965/656pdr.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1965/6510pdr.htm.

  11. The data is from:.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1969/6920PDR.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1969/6922pdr.htm.

  12. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1974/7430pdr.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1974/7432PDR.htm.

  13. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1981/8145pdr.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1981/8147pdr.htm.

  14. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1988/8856pdr.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1988/8860PDR.htm.

  15. Although the inequality in Proposition 1 requires \(x\) < 30.06, the actual vote of Chirac which is 19.94 is the binding upper bound on \(x\). This issue applies to the 1995, 2002 and 2017 elections as well.

  16. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/1995/9581PDR.htm.

    https://www.france-politique.fr/election-presidentielle-1995.htm.

  17. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/election-presidentielle-2002/bilan-du-premier-tour-de-l-election-presidentielle-de-2002.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/election-presidentielle-2002/bilan-du-second-tour-de-l-election-presidentielle-de-2002.

  18. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/election-presidentielle-2007/bilan-du-premier-tour.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/2007/2007141pdr.htm.

  19. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/2012/2012152PDR.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/2012/2012154PDR.htm.

  20. The data is from.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/2017/2017169PDR.htm.

    https://www.conseil-constitutionnel.fr/decision/2017/2017171PDR.htm.

  21. Some changes may be more unlikely than others but for the purpose of our analysis a single category that reflects unlikeliness suffices.

  22. Among the reasons for such a shift was the steady move of Christian west towards left and the popularity of socialism among youngsters who vote for the first time in 1981.

  23. https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/barometre-election-presidentiellevote-transfert-de-voix-cote-des-candidats.

    https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/barometre-cote-des-presidentiables-et-intentions-de-vote.

    https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/presidentielle-88-intentions-de-vote-et-candidature-le-pen.

    https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/barometre-election-presidentiellevote-transfert-de-voix-cote-des-candidats-0.

  24. https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/barometre-cote-des-presidentiables-et-intentions-de-vote.

  25. https://www.liberation.fr/evenement/1995/03/03/sondages-chirac-devance-balladur-au-second-tour_128284.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/08/sondages-chirac-donne-vainqueur-dans-tous-les-cas-de-figure_127767.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/24/sondages-chirac-recule-mais-gagne-dans-tous-les-cas-de-figure_126037.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/29/sondages-chirac-fait-du-sur-place-balladur-en-profite-un-peu_125598.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/30/sondage-derriere-chirac-jospin-devance-balladur-de-trois-points_125427.

    https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/intentions-de-vote-la-presidentielle-21.

  26. https://www.liberation.fr/evenement/1995/03/03/sondages-chirac-devance-balladur-au-second-tour_128284.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/08/sondages-chirac-donne-vainqueur-dans-tous-les-cas-de-figure_127767.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/15/chirac-reste-en-tete-selon-un-sondage_127015.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/29/sondages-chirac-fait-du-sur-place-balladur-en-profite-un-peu_125598.

    https://www.liberation.fr/france-archive/1995/03/30/sondage-derriere-chirac-jospin-devance-balladur-de-trois-points_125427.

    https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/intentions-de-vote-la-presidentielle-21.

  27. https://web.archive.org/web/20020425110704/http://www.ifop.com/europe/sondages/OPINIONF/presidv8.asp.

    https://web.archive.org/web/20061123034026/http://www.lh2.fr/_upload/ressources/sondages/election/LHFLibeAOLIntentdevote1617avril.pdf.

    https://web.archive.org/web/20030822222733/http://www.tns-sofres.com/etudes/pol/190402_intentions_r.htm.

    https://www.ipsos.com/fr-fr/le-barometre-presidentielle-legislatives-2002-vague-7.

    https://web.archive.org/web/20020618193356/http://www.csa-fr.com/fra/dataset/data2002/indic20020418.htm.

    https://web.archive.org/web/20020611091604/http://www.bva.fr/new/baro_observatoire_presidentiel20011127.html.

  28. At the end of our analysis, we are able to qualify the 2002 election as one which is practically open to an upward 1.1 monotonicity violation.Thus, we do not analyze the plausibility of other 1.k violation scenarios for k > 1.

  29. https://www.ifop.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/intentions2203.pdf.

    https://web.archive.org/web/20070913134736/http://www.lh2.fr/_upload/ressources/sondages/politique_nationale/lh2rmcbfmtv20mn26_27mars07.pdf.

    https://www.ifop.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/flash_presi.pdf.

    https://web.archive.org/web/20070605010944/http://www.ipsos.fr/presidentielle-2007/pdf/200407-2.pdf.

  30. https://web.archive.org/web/20110516022607/http://www.lh2.fr/_upload/ressources/sondages/politique_nationale/lh2yahoointentionsvotepresidentielle2012_07mai11.pdf.

    https://www.ifop.com/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/1480-1-study_file.pdf.

  31. psos.com/sites/default/files/files-fr-fr/doc_associe/rapport_vague13.pdf.

    http://harris-interactive.fr/wp-content/uploads/sites/6/2017/04/rapport-Harris-Indeed-Intentions-vote-election-presidentielle-LCP.pdf.

    https://elabe.fr/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/20042017_bfmtv_lexpress_intentions-de-vote-presidentielles-vague-10.pdf.

    http://www.odoxa.fr/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/Intention-de-vote-presidentielle-Odoxa-LePoint_210417.pdf.

  32. https://www.ipsos.com/sites/default/files/files-fr-fr/doc_associe/rapport_vague13.pdf.

    http://harris-interactive.fr/wp-content/uploads/sites/6/2017/04/rapport-Harris-Indeed-Intentions-vote-election-presidentielle-LCP.pdf.

    https://elabe.fr/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/20042017_bfmtv_lexpress_intentions-de-vote-presidentielles-vague-10.pdf.

  33. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this perspective.

  34. A well-known instance of manipulative vote transfers under non-monotonic voting rules is the referendum in Italy held on 12 June 2005 under the (non-monotonic) majority with quorum rule, where the Catholic Church, being against the withdrawal of a law dealing with medically assisted procreation, asked its supporters to abstain rather than casting a negative vote (Houy (2009)).

References

  • Black D (1958) The Theory of Committees and Elections. Springer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradley P (1995) STV and monotonicity: a hands-on assessment. Representation 33(2):46–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brams SJ, Fishburn PC (2002) Voting procedures. In: Arrow JK, Sen AK, Suzumura K (eds) Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 173–236

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Conitzer V, Sandholm T (2005) Communication complexity of common voting rules. In: Proceedings of the 6th ACM Conference on Electronic Commerce, 78–87

  • Criddle B, Bell DS (1981) The 1981 French elections: the victory of the left. The World Today 37(7/8):282–292

    Google Scholar 

  • Doron G, Kronick R (1977) Single transferable vote: an example of perverse social choice function. Am J Polit Sci 21:303–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durand C, Blais A, Larochelle M (2004) The polls in the 2002 French presidential election: an autopsy. Public Opin Q 68(4):602–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felsenthal DS, Nurmi H (2017) Monotonicity failures afflicting procedures for electing a single candidate. Springer, Switzerland

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frears J (1988) The 1988 French presidential election. Gov Oppos 23(3):276–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golder M (2005) Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2000. Elect Stud 24:103–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham-Squire A, Zayatz N (2020) Lack of monotonicity anomalies in empirical data of Instant Runoff elections. Representation. https://doi.org/10.1080/00344893.2020.1785536

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houy NA (2009) Characterization of majority voting rules with quorums. Theor Decis 67:295–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keskin U, Sanver MR, Tosunlu HB (2020) Recovering non-monotonicity problems of voting rules. Social Choice and Welfare. Forthcoming

  • Lepelley D, Chantreuil F, Berg S (1996) The likelihood of monotonicity paradoxes in run-off elections. Math Soc Sci 31(3):133–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin E, Sjöström T (2002) Implementation theory. Handb Soc Choice Welf 1:237–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miller NR (2017) Closeness matters: monotonicity failure in IRV elections with three candidates. Public Choice 173(1–2):91–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muller E, Satterthwaite MA (1977) The equivalence of strong positive association and strategy-proofness. J Econ Theory 14(2):412–418

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ornstein JT, Norman RZ (2014) Frequency of monotonicity failure under Instant Runoff Voting: estimates based on a spatial model of elections. Public Choice 161(1–2):1–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penniman H (1969) French elections, 1969. World Affairs 132(2):101–117

    Google Scholar 

  • Quas A (2004) Anomalous outcomes in preferential voting. Stochastics Dyn 04(1):95–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sauger N (2007) The French legislative and presidential elections of 2007. West Eur Polit 30(5):1166–1175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith JH (1973) Aggregation of preferences with variable electorate. Econometrica 41(6):1027–1041

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Straeten K, Laslier JF, Blais A (2013) Vote au pluriel: how people vote when offered to vote under different rules. Polit Sci Polit 46(2):324–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Denis Bouyssou, Olivier Cailloux, Uğur Özdemir and Jérôme Lang for their precious comments on earlier version of this paper; Jean Lainé, Jean-François Laslier, Vincent Merlin and Ali Özkes for very useful discussions; an anonymous referee and an anonymous associate editor for their thoughtful reviews that improved our work. This paper is a part of ‘Polarization viewed from a social choice perspective’ (POSOP) research project that is carried on under the RDI program funded by İstanbul Bilgi University. We would like to thank POSOP for the support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. Remzi Sanver.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Keskin, U., Sanver, M.R. & Tosunlu, H.B. Monotonicity violations under plurality with a runoff: the case of French presidential elections. Soc Choice Welf 59, 305–333 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-022-01397-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-022-01397-4

Navigation