Skip to main content
Log in

Do we need behavioral economics to explain law?

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Do we need behavioral economics to explain law? I analyze Judge Guido Calabresi’s claim that we do. I find that, actually, we don’t; traditional economic theory can explain law just fine.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. On the difficulty of giving meaning to “society’s preferences” under assumptions more general than those that underlie the median voter model, see for instance, Arrow (1951) and Buchanan (1954).

References

  • Anderson, G. M., Halcoussis, D., & Tollison, R. D. (1996). Drafting the competition: Labor unions and military conscription. Defence and Peace Economics, 7, 189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. J. (1951). Social choice and individual values. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, A. H., Beard, T. R., & Kaserman, D. L. (1993). The medical community’s opposition to organ markets: Ethics or economics? Review of Industrial Organization, 7, 669–678.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1973). The control of politicians: An economic model. Public Choice, 14, 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T. (2006). Principled agents? The political economy of good government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1948). On the rationale of group decision-making. Journal of Political Economy, 56, 23–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1954). Social choice, democracy, and free markets. Journal of Political Economy, 62, 114–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calabresi, G. (2016). The future of law and economics. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davidson, A. B., Davis, E. D., & Ekelund, R. B., Jr. (1995). Political choice and the child labor statute of 1938: Public interest or interest group regulation? Public Choice, 82, 85–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J. (1986). Incumbent performance and electoral control. Public Choice, 50, 5–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilens, M., & Page, B. I. (2014). Testing theories of American politics: Elites, interest groups, and average citizens. Perspectives on Politics, 12, 564–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guttman, A., & Guttman, R. D. (1993). Attitudes of healthcare professionals and the public towards the sale of kidneys for transplantation. Journal of Medical Ethics, 19, 148–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaserman, D. L., & Barnett, A. H. (1991). An economic analysis of transplant organs: A comment and extension. Atlantic Economic Journal, 19, 57–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leider, S., & Roth, A. E. (2010). Kidneys for sale: Who disapproves, and why? American Journal of Transplantation, 10, 1221–1227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mulligan, C. B., & Shleifer, A. (2005). Conscription as regulation. American Law and Economics Review, 7, 85–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K. (1984). The relevance of the median voter theorem. Kyklos, 140, 104–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C. K., & Schneider, F. (2004). The encyclopedia of public choice (Vol. 2). New York: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Satel, S. (2006). The waiting game. In Character (pp. 36–47). Spring.

  • Somin, I. (2016). Democracy and political ignorance: Why smaller government is smarter. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1992). Law or economics? Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 455–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yandle, B. (1983). Bootleggers and baptists: The education of a regulatory economist. Regulation, 7, 12–16.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank Paola Suarez, the Editors, and two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter T. Leeson.

Additional information

This paper was prepared for the Conference on the Future of Law and Economics at Boston University School of Law, June 1–2, 2017.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Leeson, P.T. Do we need behavioral economics to explain law?. Eur J Law Econ 48, 29–42 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-017-9573-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-017-9573-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation