Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

“You reap what you sow”: Do active labour market policies always increase job security? Evidence from the Youth Guarantee

  • Published:
European Journal of Law and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Youth is the best time to be rich, and the best time to be poor.

Euripides, 416 b.C.

Abstract

The paper uses non-experimental longitudinal data to study the effects of participation in the Youth Guarantee programme aimed at fighting youth inactivity in the European Union territory. Particularly, this analysis questions the value of active labour market policy as a valid instrument to help individuals otherwise isolated from the labour market and, thus, at risk of deterioration of human capital overcome their condition of occupational inactivity. A difference-in-differences model is exploited in this regard to investigate whether there exists an advantage for participants of the Youth Guarantee in terms of employment and job stability. Results show that participants are 7.4 and 4.4 percentage points more likely to, respectively, become employed and be offered an open-ended contract. An assessment of profiling is also provided.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Cirillo et al. (2017).

  2. See Albert et al. in Schömann and O’Connell (2002).

  3. For instance, Spain and Italy.

  4. Council of the European Union, 2013.

  5. The financial contribution expected from all the member states of the European Union to fight youth unemployment makes the management and impact of the Youth Guarantee of relevance for both the poorest and the richest countries in the Community.

  6. In 2015, public expenditure on passive and active measures was, respectively, equal to € 21 billion and to € 6.8 billion in Italy.

  7. The latter are not always fruitful for their recipients. In Australia, reducing childcare expenditure through monetary benefits increased the labour supply of the parents only by 0.75 to 1 h per week. See Guest and Parr (2013).

  8. See Andor and Veselý (2018).

  9. See Sect. 3.

  10. See Art. 3 of the Legislative Decree 276/2003.

  11. See Art. 4 of the Legislative Decree 276/2003.

  12. See Art. 13 of the Legislative Decree 276/2003.

  13. See Art. 18 (c. 1) of Law 300/1970.

  14. See Art. 1 (c. 4p) of Law 183/2014.

  15. See Art. 1 (c. 7c) of Law 183/2014.

  16. See Vasta and Di Martino (2017).

  17. See Barbieri (2011), pp. 19, 31.

  18. See Brunner and Kuhn (2014).

  19. With respect to exploiting vulnerable segments of the population, Korkeamäki and Kyyrä (2012) showed how employers of growing establishments in Finland tend to take advantage of disability retirement so as not to resort to standard dismissals.

  20. See Lenzi et al. (2018) and Acconcia and Graziano (2017).

  21. (5), p. 1 of 2013/C 120/01.

  22. (22), p. 3 of 2013/C 120/01.

  23. (1), p. 1 of 2013/C 120/01.

  24. For Italy equal to € 567 million from the Youth European Initiative, € 567 million from the European Social Fund, and an additional 40% of national co-funding, for a total of about € 1513 billion.

  25. (1), p. 3 of 2013/C 120/01.

  26. The document is available on the website of the European Commission and was drafted in Strasbourg on 4 October 2016.

  27. On the Commission’s website, such a statement can be found in “The Youth Guarantee country by country” section.

  28. (4b), p. 12, European Pillar of Social Rights.

  29. This is relevant when considering the argument by Gaddis and Klasen (2013) according to which female labour force participation is more likely to increase due to local conditions and institutions rather than secular trends.

  30. Andor and Veselý (2018), p. 13.

  31. While Central Italy may share features of both South and North, it is never the case that conclusions for Sicily could, for instance, apply to Lombardy or vice versa.

  32. See Isfol’s report for 2016.

  33. Ibid.

  34. The fact that the former secretary of state for education Ugolini (2013) wrote an article on the national paper Corriere della Sera entitled “Why Do Apprenticeships Not Work in Italy?” is emblematic in this regard.

  35. The current programmes available online on the Youth Guarantee website refer to the modified EU Commission’s Decision C(2017) 8927 of 18/12/2017.

  36. The reason why Italy decided to increase the age limits from 24 years, as recommended by the EU Commission, to 29 years probably originates from the existence of the 181/2000 Law Decree that guaranteed an offer of training, or professional retraining, to people up to the age of 29 years within 4 months from registration as unemployed. Moreover, the amount of European and national funds that Italy received for the programme were sufficient to cover not only the number of potential NEETs predisposed by the European Union 120/01 Recommendation (those under 24 years old, equal to 1,274,000 in Italy), but the annual flow of actual NEETs (those under 29 years old, namely 2,254,000 individuals). Additional information can be found on www.garanziagiovani.gov.it.

  37. For mathematical reasons, the probability of being offered an open-ended contract in a given period \({Pr(Y}_{OPEN\_ t} = 1)\) is equal to the sum of the probability of being offered an open-ended contract conditional on the probability of becoming employed in a given period multiplied by the probability of becoming employed in a given period \({Pr(Y}_{OPEN\_t} = 1| Y_{EMPLOYED\_t} = 1){Pr(Y}_{EMPLOYED\_t} = 1)\) and of the probability of being offered an open-ended contract conditional on the probability of not becoming employed in a given period multiplied by the probability of not becoming employed in a given period \({Pr(Y}_{OPEN\_t} = 1|Y_{EMPLOYED\_t} = 0){Pr(Y}_{EMPLOYED\_t} = 0)\). As this last expression is null, then the the probability of being offered an open-ended contract in a given period \({Pr(Y}_{OPEN\_t} = 1)\) is equal to the sum of the probability of being offered an open-ended contract conditional on the probability of becoming employed in a given period multiplied by the probability of becoming employed in a given period \({Pr(Y}_{OPEN\_t} = 1| Y_{EMPLOYED\_t} = 1){Pr(Y}_{EMPLOYED\_t} = 1)\).

  38. Assumed all training programmes have an average duration of minimum a year and based on the individual’s birth date, eligibility is, for instance, flagged as equal to 1 in 2015 when at the check date of the year before the individual was observed as being under the age of 30 years old.

  39. The lower the profiling indicator, the lower the difficulty to reinstate the subject into the labour market and vice versa.

  40. Which is expected to be direct and exclusive.

  41. Co.co.co.s expect the worker to work independently in the company and without obligations of subordination, but through a permanent and coordinated relationship with the customer, i.e. the employer of the company.

  42. Co.co.pro.s were abrogated with the 81/2015 Law Decree but are still active for those contracts registered as such. They, too, expect a service from the worker but the latter is independent and can either be involved for a whole project, a programme, or just part of it.

  43. If unemployed individuals have difficulty reaching for social networks in general, this is even harder for those NEETs who are totally inactive and, thus, probably socially isolated.

  44. Educational tool that uses work experience to facilitate the entry of socially weak categories, as are some not-in-employment, not-in-education, not-in-training individuals, into the labour market.

  45. The agent promotes the conclusion of the contract between the interested third party and the worker, but leaves them with the responsibility of concluding and perfecting it, without taking any risk.

  46. Created with the 30/2003 Biagi Law to substitute the 196/1997 Law on the temporary, or ad interim, agency contract.

  47. For more information see “Piano di Attuazione Regionale Toscana N. 992”, pp. 12–13.

  48. The Youth Guarantee offers a wide range of active measures.

  49. Isfol, Rapporto Sulla “Garanzia Giovani in Italia” (2016) for Italy and “Piano di Attuazione Regionale Toscana N. 992”, pp. 12–13 for Tuscany.

  50. See Katz (1994); Bonnal et al. (1997); Meager (2008); Stephan (2008); Saniter and Siedler (2014); Card et al. (2011, 2010); Escudero (2018); and others.

  51. (22), p. 3 of 2013/C 120/01.

  52. See Berton et al. (2009).

  53. See Andor and Veselý (2018).

  54. See Heckman (2000), pp. 7, 42.

  55. Ibid., p. 42.

  56. See Andor and Veselý (2018), p. 5.

  57. Ibid., pp. 7–8.

  58. Istat report “L’Economia Non Osservata Nei Conti Nazionali” (11 October 2017).

  59. See Angrist and Pischke (2008).

  60. Namely, training.

  61. See Andor and Veselý (2018).

  62. For instance, Austria.

  63. With reference to Heckman (2000), it is recommended to invest in the highly skilled, tax them, and provide older and unskilled workers with alternative measures of welfare, such as wage subsidies, so as to avoid ineffective training.

  64. This is line with the studies of Svejnar (2002), Bergemann and van den Berg (2008), and Card et al. (2011, 2010).

  65. \({\hbox {R}}^{2}\) goes from 9.3% in the short term to 2.3% in the long term as regards the probability to become employed and from 5.1% to 1.8% as regards the probability to be offered an open-ended contract.

References

  • Acconcia, G., & Graziano, P. (2017). The Youth Guarantee: The cases of Milan (Lombardy) and Naples (Campania). In The political economy of local regulation: Theoretical frameworks and international case studies. London: Palgrave Macmillan UK.

  • Acemoglu, D., & Autor, D. (2012). The basic theory of human capital. In: Lectures in labour economics. Semantic Scholar.

  • Albert, C., Davia, M., Hernanz, V., & Toharia, L. (2002). Choosing between education, training and labour market entry’. In E. Elgar (Eds.), Education, training and employment dynamics: Transitional labour markets in the European Union.

  • Albert, D., Chein, J., & Steinberg, L. (2013). The teenage brain: Peer influences on adolescent decision making. Current Directions in Psychological Science, 22(2), 114–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altavilla, C., & Caroleo, F. (2018). The effect of active labour market policies on crime: Incapacitation and program effects. Labour Economics, 52, 263–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, C. (2009). The private consequence of public policies: Active labour market policies and social ties in Europe. European Political Science Review, 1(3), 341–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andor, L., & Veselý, L. (2018). The EU Youth Guarantee: A broadly accepted reform in need of full implementation. European Social Observatory Paper Series (19).

  • Angrist, J., & Pischke, J. S. (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Audier, F. (2002). Segmentation in the labour market: An analysis of recruitment. In E. Elgar (Eds.), Education, training and employment dynamics: Transitional labour markets in the European Union.

  • Barbieri, P. (2011). Italy: No country for young men (and women). The Italian way of coping with increasing demands for labor market flexibility and rising welfare problems. In Globalized labour markets and social inequality in Europe. Palgrave Macmillan.

  • Bergemann, A., Caliendo, M., & van den Berg, G. (2009). The effect of active labour market programs on not-yet treated unemployed individuals. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(2/3), 606–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergemann, A., Caliendo, M., van den Berg, G. J., & Zimmermann, K. F. (2011). The threat effect of participation in active labor market programs on job search behavior of migrants in Germany. International Journal of Manpower, 32(7), 777–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergemann, A., & van den Berg, G. (2008). Active labor market policy effects for women in Europe—A survey. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 85(91–92), 385–408.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berton, F., Richiardi, M., & Sacchi, S. (2009). Flex-insecurity: Perché in Italia la Flessibilità Diventa Precarietà. Il Mulino.

  • Bertrand, M., & Crépon, B. (2017). J-PAL skills for youth program review paper. J-PAL.

  • Biavaschi, C., Eichhorst, W., Giulietti, C., Kendzia, M., Muravyev, A., Pieters, J., et al. (2013). Youth unemployment and vocational training. Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics, 9(1–2), 1–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Biewen, M., Fitzenberger, B., Osikomi, A., & Waller, M. (2014). The effectiveness of public-sponsored training revisited: The importance of data and methodological choices. Journal of Labor Economics, 32(4), 837–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. A., Smith, J. A., Berger, M. C., & Noel, B. J. (2003). Is the threat of reemployment services more effective than the services themselves? Evidence from random assignment in the UI system. American Economic Review, 93(4), 1313–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blasco, S., & Rosholm, M. (2011). The impact of active labour market policy on post-unemployment outcomes: Evidence from a social experiment in Denmark. IZA discussion papers (5631).

  • Boeri, T., & Burda, M. (1996). Active labor market policies, job matching and the Czech miracle. European Economic Review, 40(3–5), 805–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonnal, L., Fougère, D., & Sérandon, A. (1997). Evaluating the impact of French employment policies on individual labour market histories. The Review of Economic Studies, 64(1), 683–713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonoli, G. (2010). The political economy of active labour market policies. Politics and Society, 38(4), 435–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone, J., & van Ours, J. (2009). Bringing unemployed back to work: Effective active labour market policies. De Economist, 157(3), 293–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, A., & Koettl, J. (2015). Active labour market programs: Employment gain or fiscal drain. IZA Journal of Labor Economics, 4, 12.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunello, G., Garibaldi, P., & Wasmer, (2007). Education and training in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Brunner, B., & Kuhn, A. (2014). The impact of labor market entry conditions on initial job assignment, human capital accumulation, and wages. Journal of Population Economics, 27(3), 705–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budría, S., & Pereira, P. T. (2008). The contribution of vocational training to employment, job-related skills and productivity. Evidence from Madeira Island. International Journal of Training and Development, 13(1), 53–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo, M., Falk, A., Kaiser, L., Schneider, H., Uhlendorff, A., van den Berg, G., et al. (2011a). The IZA evaluation dataset: Towards evidence-based labor policy making. International Journal of Manpower, 32, 731–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo, M., & Künn, J. (2015). Getting back into the labor market: The effects of start-up subsidies for unemployed females. Journal of Population Economics, 28(4), 1005–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo, M., Künn, S., & Schmidl, R. (2011b). Fighting youth unemployment: The effects of active labour market policies performance. IZA discussion papers (6222).

  • Caliendo, M., & Schmidl, R. (2016). Youth unemployment and active labour market policies in Europe. IZA Journal of Labor Policy, 5(1), 1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calmfors, L., Forslund, A., & M., H. (2002). Does active labour market policy work? Lessons from the Swedish experience. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 8(2).

  • Cammeraat, E., Jongen, E., & Koning, P. (2017). Preventing NEETs during the great recession. The effects of a mandatory activation: Program for young welfare recipients. IZA discussion papers (11090).

  • Cappellini, E., Duranti, S., Patacchini, V., & Sciclone, N. (2018). The Youth Guarantee: A real opportunity for NEETS?. XXXIII AIEL conference.

  • Card, D., Kluve, J., & Weber, A. (2010). Active labor market policy evaluations: A meta-analysis. Economic Journal, 120(148), 452–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D., Kluve, J., & Weber, A. (2011). Fighting youth unemployment: The effects of active labour market policies performance. Journal of the European Economic Association, 16(3), 894–931.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Card, D., & Shore-Sheppard, L. (2004). Using discontinuous eligibility rules to identify the effects of the Federal Medicaid expansions on low-income children. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 752–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cerulli-Harms, A. (2017). Generation internship—The impact of internships on early labour market performance. IZA Discussion papers (11163).

  • Cirillo, V., Fana, M., & Guarascio, D. (2016). Did Italy need more flexibility? Intereconomics, 51(2), 79–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cirillo, V., Fana, M., & Guarascio, D. (2017). Labour market reforms in Italy: Evaluating the effects of the Jobs Act. Economia Politica, 34(3), 1–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Connelly, B., & Certo, T. (2011). Signaling theory: A review and assessment. Journal of Management, 37(1), 854–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Council, E. U. (2013). Council recommendation of 22 April 2012 on establishing a Youth Guarantee (2013/c 120/01). Official Journal of the European Union.

  • Cox, R. (1998). From safety net to trampoline: Labour market activation in the Netherlands and Denmark. Governance, 11(4), 397–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crépon, B., Ferracci, M., Jolivet, G., & van den Berg, G. J. (2010). Active labour market policy effects in a dynamic setting. Journal of the European Economic Policy, 7(2–3), 595–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crépon, B., & van den Berg, G. (2016). Active labour market policies. Annual Review of Economics, 8, 521–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dar, A., & Tzannatos, Z. (1999). Active labour market programs: A review of the evidence from evaluations. World bank social protection discussion paper series (9901).

  • Deaton, A. (1997). The analysis of household surveys: A microeconometric approach to development policy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Del Bono, E., Weber, A., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (2014). Fertility and economics instability: The role of unemployment and job displacement. Journal of Population Economics, 28(2), 463–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dingeldey, I. (2007). Welfare state transformation between workfare and an enabling state: A comparative analysis. European Journal of Political Research, 46, 823–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Doerr, A., Fitzenberger, B., Kruppe, T., Paul, M., & Strittmatter, A. (2016). Employment and earnings effects of awarding training vouchers in Germany. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 70(3), 767–812.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichhorst, W., & Konle-Seidl, R. (2016). Evaluating labour market policy. IZA discussion papers (9966).

  • Eichhorst, W., & Neder, F. (2014). Youth unemployment in Mediterranean Countries. IZA policy papers (80).

  • Eichhorst, W., & Rinne, U. (2017). The European Youth Guarantee: A preliminary assessment and broader conceptual implications. CESifo Forum, 18(2), 34–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichhorst, W., & Zimmermann, K. (2017). And then there were four: How many (and which) measures of active labour market policies do we still need. Applied Economics Quarterly, 53(3), 243–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • Escudero, V. (2018). Are active labour market policies effective in activating and integrating low-skilled individuals? An international comparison. IZA Journal of Labor Policy, 7(1), 4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Escudero, V., Kluve, J., Mourelo, E. L., & Pignatti, C. (2018). Active labour market programmes in Latin America and the Caribbean: Evidence from a meta-analysis. Journal of Development Studies, 1–18.

  • Estevao, M. (2003). Do active labour market policies increase employment? IMF working papers, 3(234).

  • Fallesen, P., Lars, P., Susumu, I., & Torben, T. (2006). Evaluating the dynamic effects of active labour market policies in Italy. Labour Economics, 20(2), 349–382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fertig, M., Schmidt, C., & Schneider, H. (2002). Active labour market policies in Germany: Is it there a successful policy strategy? Regional Science and Urban Economics, 36(3), 399–430.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forrier, A., & Sels, L. (2003). Temporary employment and employability: Training opportunities and efforts of temporary and permanent employees in Belgium. Work Employment and Society, 17(4), 641–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franzese, R., & Hays, J. (2006). Strategic interactions among eu government in active labour market policies making: Subsidiarity and policy coordination under the european employment strategy. European Union Politics, 7(2), 167–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P., & Johansson, P. (2008). Dynamic treatment assignment: The consequences for evaluations using observational data. Journal of Business and Economics Statistics, 26(4), 435–445.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gaddis, I., & Klasen, S. (2013). Economic development, structural change and womens labor force participation: A reexamination of the feminization u hypothesis. Journal of Population Economics, 27(3), 639–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerfin, M., & Lechner, M. (2002). A microeconometric evaluation of the active labour market policy in Switzerland. Economic Journal, 112(482), 854–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guest, R., & Parr, N. (2013). Family policy and couples’ labour supply: An empirical assessment. Journal of Population Economics, 26(4), 1631–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. (2000). Policies to foster human capital. Research in Economics, 54(1), 3–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J., & Rubinstein, Y. (2001). The importance of non-cognitive skills: Lessons from the GED testing program. American Economic Review, 91(2), 145–9.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J., Stixrud, J., & Urzua, S. (2006). The effect of cognitive and non-cognitive abilities on labour market outcomes and social behaviour. Journal of Labor Economics, 24(3), 411–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins, E. (2012). Job market signaling of relative position, or Becker married to Spence. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(12), 854–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howell, D., Baker, D., Glyn, A., & Schmitt, J. (2007). Are protective labor market institutions at the root of unemployment? A critical review of the evidence. Capitalism and Society, 2(1).

  • Hujer, R., Blien, U., Caliendo, M., & Zeiss, C. (2006). Macroeconomic evaluation of active labour market policies in Germany: A dynamic panel approach using regional data. In The European labour market. Regional dimensions. Physica Verlag.

  • Ichino, A., Nannicini, T., & Mealli, F. (2008). From temporary help jobs to permanent employment: What can we learn from matching estimators and their sensitivity? Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23(3), 305–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Isfol, Rapporto 2016 sulla “Garanzia Giovani in Italia” and “Piano di Attuazione Regionale Toscana N. 992”, pp. 12–13.

  • Jessoula, M., Graziano, P., & Madama, I. (2010). Selective flexicurity in segmented labour markets: The case of Italian mid-siders. Journal of Social Policy, 39(4), 561–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katz, L. (1994). Active labour market policies to expand employment and opportunity. In Proceedings economic policy symposium Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.

  • Kazepov, K., & Ranci, C. (2016). Is every country fit for social investment? Italy as an adverse case. Journal of European Social Policy, 27(1), 90–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kluve, J. (2010). The effectiveness of European active labor market policy. Labor Economics, 17(6), 904–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Korkeamäki, O., & Kyyrä, T. (2012). Institutional rules, labour demand and retirement through disability programme participation. Journal of Population Economics, 25(2), 439–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuddo, A. (2009). Employment services and active labour market programs in Eastern and Central Asian countries. World bank social protection discussion paper series, (918).

  • Lalive, R., & Zweimüller, J. (2008). The impact of active labour market programs on the duration of unemployment. The Economic Journal, 118(525), 235–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lechner, M., & Wiehler, S. (2011). Kids or courses? Gender differeces in the effects of active labour market policies. Journal of Population Economics, 24(3), 783–812.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lechner, M., & Wunsch, C. (2009). Active labour market policy in East Germany: Waiting for the economy to take off. The Economics of Transition, 17, 661–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenzi, G., Cuconato, M., Laasch, C., & Minguzzi, L. (2018). National report for the project youth policies and participation for Italy. Dipartimento di Scienze dell’Educazione Università degli Studi di Bologna.

  • Lindqvist, E., & Westman, R. (2011). The labour market returns to cognitive and noncognitive ability: Evidence from the Swedish enlistment. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 3, 101–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. (2015). Activation and active labour market policies in OECD countries: Stylized facts and evidence on their effectiveness. IZA Journal of Labor Policy, 4(1), 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. P., & Grubb, D. (2001). What works and for whom. A review of OECD countries experiences with active labour market policies. Swedish Economic Policy Review, 8, 9–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mckenzie, D. (2017). How effective are active labour market policies in developing countries. The World Bank Research Observer, 32(2), 127–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meager, N. (2008). The role of training and skills development in active labour market policies. International Journal of Training and Development, 13(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mechtel, M., & Potrafke, N. (2013). Electoral cycles in active labour market policies. Public Choice, 156(1/2), 181–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muntenau, B. (2016). Youth unemployment in EU: A pressure to avoid long term social empoverishment. Europolity, 10(2), 169–204.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myck, M., & Reed, H. (2006). A review of static and dynamic models of labour supply and labour market transitions. Institute for fiscal studies working paper (W06/15).

  • Nickell, S. (1997). Unemployment and market rigidities: Europe versus North America. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 55–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Higgins, N. (2001). Youth unemployment and employment policy: A global perspective. Geneva: ILO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pastore, F. (2015). The European Youth Guarantee: Labor market context, conditions and opportunities in Italy. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 4, 11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pehkonen, J. (1997). Displacement effects of active labour market policy: The youth labour market in Finland. Empirica, 24, 195–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perez, C., Vellinga, P., de Buck, P., Faulstich, M., Girouard, N., Gregori, G., et al. (2011). Europeanisation and the political economy of active labour market policies. European Union Politics, 12(2), 217–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piva, M. C., Santarelli, E., & Vivarelli, M. (2005). The skill bias effect of technological and organisational change: Evidence and policy implications. Research Policy, 34(2), 141–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puhani, P. A. (2012). The treatment effect, the cross difference, and the interaction term in nonlinear “difference-in-differences” models. Economic Letters, 115, 85–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rouault, S. (2002). Assessing the impact of experimental EU training policies in France, Germany and Ireland’. In E. Elgar (Eds.), Education, training and employment dynamics: Transitional labour markets in the European Union.

  • Rueda, D. (2006). Social democracy and active labour market policies: (insiders), outsiders, and the politics of employment promotion. British Journal of Political Science, 36(3), 385–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, C., & Whelan, S. (2013). Age pension eligibility and female labour force participation. Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social Research.

  • Sanfey, A., Stallen, M., & Chang, L. (2014). Norms and expectations in social decision-making. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 18(4), 172–4.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saniter, N., & Siedler, T. (2014). Door opener or waste of time? The effects of student internships on labor market outcomes. IZA Discussion Papers (8141).

  • Sarvimäki, M., & Hämäläinen, K. (2016). Integrating immigrants: The impact of restructuring active labor market programs. Journal of Labor Economics, 34(2), 479–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schömann, K., & O’Connell, P. (2002). Education, training and employment dynamics: Transitional labour markets in the European Union. E. Elgar.

  • Scoville, J. (1969). A theory of jobs and training. Industrial Relations, 9(1), 36–53.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. (2000). A critical survey of empirical methods for evaluating active labor market policies. Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics, 136(3), 247–68.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spence, M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(3), 355–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephan, G. (2008). The effects of active labour market programs in Germany. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik, 228(5–6), 586–611.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svejnar, J. (1999). Labor markets in the transitional Central and East European economies. Handbook of Labor Economics, 3(B), 2809–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svejnar, J. (2002). Labor market flexibility in central and east Europe. William Davidson Working Paper (496).

  • Trattara, G., & Valentini, M. (2008). Can employment subsidies and greater labour market flexibility increase opportunities for youth? Revisiting the Italian on-the-job training programme. Journal for Labour Market Research, 42(3), 197–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ugolini, E. (2013). Vi spiego perché in Italia non funziona l’apprendistato.

  • van Vliet, O., & Koster, F. (2011). Europeanisation and the political economy of active labour market policies. European Union Politics, 12(2), 217–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vasta, M., & Di Martino, P. (2017). Ricchi per caso: La parabola dello sviluppo economico italiano. Il Mulino.

  • Verga, G. (1881). I Malavoglia. Treves.

  • Vesan, P., & Lizzi, R. (2017). The youth guarantee in Italy and the new policy design approach: Expectations, hopes and delusions. World Political Science. https://doi.org/10.1515/wps-2017-0005.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vinci, F. (2017). Youth and employment: The effectiveness of the Youth Guarantee plan in Emilia Romagna and Sicily. Sociology Study, 7(1), 43–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolfbein, S. (1967). Education and training for full employment. Columbia: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zweimüller, J., & Winter-Ebmer, R. (1996). Manpower training programs and employment. Economica, 63(249), 113–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chiara Natalie Focacci.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The author thanks the participants of the “Shifting from Welfare to Social Investment States” Conference at Erasmus University Rotterdam, the 35th European Association of Law and Economics Conference in Milan, the 15th Academic International Conference on Law, Economics and Politics in Oxford, and the 6th Polish Law and Economics Association Conference in Warsaw. Useful comments were given during the internal seminars at the Department of Economics of the University of Bologna, the Institute of Law and Economics at the Universität Hamburg, and the Rotterdam Institute of Law and Economics at Erasmus University. The author is thankful to the Agency of Labour of Trento for their collaboration as well as to two anonymous referees, Enrico Santarelli, Robson Tigre, Yuki Takahashi, Yu Bai, Margherita Fort, Jonathan Klick, Michael Faure, Chris Reinders Folmer, Peter Mascini, Jerg Gutmann, Paul Aubrecht, and Giulio Zanella for their comments.

Appendices

Appendix

Profiling and the Youth Guarantee

On the occasion of signing the service pact with the job centre of reference, individuals are ‘profiled’ according to their degree of risk of remaining inactive. The indicator of profiling is computed statistically for each youth and is considered itself an active labour market policy (ALMP). The profiling is based on a series of individual characteristics such as the individual’s presence in Italy; her level of education; her situation of employment 1 year before the start of the Youth Guarantee; and other local features including entrepreneurial density and variation in the unemployment rate of the area of origin. The indicator ranges from 0 to 1. Lower and higher values of the profiling indicator signal, respectively, a higher and lower probability for the individual to be reintegrated in the labour market. A youth’s profiling indicator is low if its value falls between 0.000 and 0.250000; medium if it falls between 0.250001 and 0.50000; high if it falls between 0.50001 and 0.750000; and finally, very high if the indicator’s value falls between 0.750001 and 1.

While participation in ALMPs may or may not have beneficial effects for participants, the threat caused by their mere existence may have an impact on the occupational prospects of the individuals involved. The study by Black et al. (2003), for instance, examined the consequences of profiling on unemployment insurance claimants. In particular, they found that the former reduced both the number of weeks of benefit receipt and the amount received. At the same time, the activity led to a significant increase in earnings for the treated individuals in the year after their claim for unemployment benefits, suggesting an anticipated entry in the labour market. Similar results were observed by Bergemann et al. (2008, 2011) for Germany and by Blasco and Rosholm (2011) for Denmark. Scholars agree on the fact that systems that guarantee active labour market policies usually increase the effort in job search so as to avoid actual participation in ALMPs. On this subject, there might be valid reasons for individuals to be significantly influenced by the presence of ALMPs in their labour market. Heckman and Rubinstein (2001), for instance, associated this threat effect to the fear of having to renounce alternative activities or of being stigmatised. As a result, individuals may accept non-quality jobs rather than attend active measures that demand a long-term commitment. The fear of producing a negative signal to external subjects such as potential employers has been widely discussed in the literature. Spence (1973), before all, defined the job market as a market where signaling is paramount, due to the lack of information on job candidates. On the one hand, the employer lacks the necessary knowledge about the real skills of the job candidates. On the other hand, the individuals have to select the information they aim to signal at a certain cost. This is particularly true for the more disadvantaged subjects who compete with better educated and, sometimes, more productive individuals. As observed by Connelly and Certo (2011), inferior signalers may take the risk of producing false signals, or cheat, for they are aware of their chances being lower anyway. In this regard, Hopkins (2012) shed light on the stronger signals sent by high-quality workers to firms. This would explain the different degree of difficulty for low- and high-profiled individuals to get a job in the first place.

A comparison between individuals who are and who are not profiled would be more useful in order to identify the potential ex-ante effect of profiling in the Youth Guarantee. On this occasion, however, we will present an analysis that focuses exclusively on the participants of the Youth Guarantee. This allows us to exploit the information relevant for the individuals on their profiling and the duration of their training in the selected firms. In particular, we aim to investigate how the different types of profiling indicators with which NEETs are assessed influence their job opportunities. For the purpose of this analysis, we retain only those individuals who participate in the programme of the Youth Guarantee and, thus, who are profiled before starting their on-the-job training experience. The Youth Guarantee expects participants not to be engaged in employment, education, or training, and to be younger than 30 years old. In order not to produce biased estimates, associated to the duration of training, individuals who are still participating and who have 2100 as their year end date are dropped. As regards the most relevant controls, we account for the nationality of the participating individuals, their age, and their gender. A dummy \({IT}_{{i}}\) for whether the individual observed is Italian or not is included in the model. Indeed, in contrast to Northern countries like Denmark or the Netherlands, job vacancies in the Italian labour market are likely to require candidates to have a perfect knowledge of the Italian language. To verify this, it is sufficient to check some of the job offers promoted online by Italian firms or the number of blogs that provide suggestions for foreigners on what actions to take in order to find a job in Italy. With regard to the average age of the labour force in Italy, the fact that there is a tendency on the part of individuals to live with their parents long after reaching their majority, developed a labour market where firms are used to older candidates. Recent statistics by Eurostat show that the average age at which Italians left their family nest in 2017 was about 30.1 years old, in comparison with Germans and Swedes who moved out at, respectively, 23.7 and 21. This justifies the need to consider the individuals’ \({AGE}_{{i}}\) as well. Because of the traditional history of female discrimination in the Italian labour market, we also account for a dummy \({FEMALE}_{i}\). On this subject, the use of illegal undated letters of resignation that employers obliged female employees to sign, so as to prevent the costs of maternity leave, only stopped recently, with the 2014–2015 Jobs Act.

In this analysis, we are particularly interested in investigating whether the profiling of an individual can actually influence employers when opting for a candidate rather than for another one. Additionally, we are curious about understanding whether attending the programme for a longer duration can work as a remedial to the potential ‘stigma’ brought by the initial assessment of the individual. The longer a disadvantaged youth attends the programme, the more likely it could be for her to acquire and develop any lacking skill or, vice versa, to fall victim to potential locking-in effects. Using standard OLS, we first look at the association of the different types of profiling \({PROF}_{i}\) with the two labour outcomes of interest \({{Y}}_{{i}}\); namely, the likelihood of the participants to become employed and to be offered an open-ended contract. In particular, we include the \({LOW}_{i}\), \({MEDIUM}_{i}\), and \({VHIGH}_{i}\) dummies for having, respectively, a low, medium, and very high profiling and use the dummy of high profiling as the base category. We then incorporate \({DUR}_{i}\) in the model, or the duration of the internship measured in intervals of 100 days, to see whether there exists any compensation for having a particularly risky profile. A stronger commitment in the programme, or simply more time, may help the more vulnerable individuals overcome their occupational prospects. A distinction is made between short, medium, and long terms since the implementation of the Youth Guarantee, intended as the years 2015, 2016, and 2017.

$$\begin{aligned} Y_i = \alpha + \beta AGE_i + \theta _f FEMALE_i + \delta IT_i + \sum _{m=1}^{3} \theta _p PROF_{m,i} + \omega DUR_i + \epsilon _i \end{aligned}$$
(14)

The descriptive statistics of Table 16 show that individuals are on average about 24.2 years old, with male participants being slightly younger. As regards the nationality of participating individuals, Italians make up the majority of the sample analysed. NEETs participate in the on-the-job training for 324 days averagely, with a variation of less than 2 months. In respect to the profiling, we observe that 21.8% of the individuals are assessed with a low profiling; 29.3% with a medium profiling; 32.7% with a high profiling; and 16.3% with a very high profiling. In particular, individuals who are at a low risk of staying unemployed are 25.1 years old on average, while NEETs with a high profiling are usually 23.1 years old. Conversely, there is no particular pattern when trying to understand the relationship between the type of profiling assessed and the gender of the individual. Indeed, women are the minority in both low- and very high-profiling categories with a proportion of, respectively, 44.1% and 40.1%. On the contrary, Italians are the predominant nationality in all the categories. Indeed, they make up 90% of the low-risk group and 79.9% of the high-risk group. As regards participation in the on-the-job training, individuals usually attend the programme for about 11 months, with low and medium profiles participating slightly longer. In terms of the relationship between the occupational prospects of the NEETs and their profiling, there is a moderate contrast between low and high profiles. Table 17, in particular, shows that employed NEETs are assessed with a low profiling 54.4% of the time and with a very high profiling 31% of the time. The gap is also present to a modest degree when looking at the type of individuals who are offered an open-ended contract, independent of becoming employed. While we only find 12.1% of the NEETs with a very high profiling ending up with an open-ended contract, the proportion increases up to 26.1% for those assessed with a low profiling.

Table 16 Descriptive statistics for individuals registered at Agency of Labour of Trento, 2014–2017
Table 17 Descriptive statistics for individuals registered at Agency of Labour of Trento by profiling, 2014–2017

As regards our identification strategy, the OLS estimates of Table 18 show that an increase in age corresponds to an increase in the probability for participants to exit from their unemployment condition in both short and medium terms. For Italian participants, there is an additional comparative advantage in the medium term of about 4.3 percentage points, significant at 10% level. The training programme appears to be more beneficial for female participants too, compared to their male colleagues.Footnote 64 At least in the short term, women are 3.6 percentage points more likely to become employed. However, no such advantage is observed in the following periods. This is not particularly surprising given that the phenomenon of undated letters of resignation preventing maternity leave stopped with the 2014–2015 Jobs Act. While the latter might help explain the positive change in job opportunities observed for women in 2015, it did not guarantee its stability over time. Similarly, the fact that older and Italian job candidates are slightly favoured confirms the hypothesis of the existing literature of a labour market in Italy that is used to older employees and that prefers compatriot individuals. In regard to our main covariate of interest, we are interested in understanding how much of the variation observed in the labour outcomes is explained by being assessed with a certain type of profiling. Table 18 shows that being assessed with a low profiling corresponds to a positive change in the probability to be offered a job of, respectively, 24.9, 15.3, and 13.3 percentage points in the short, medium, and long terms. Compared to high profiles, a similar pattern is also found for individuals assigned with a medium profiling. Having a very high profiling, on the other hand, contributes to explaining a negative variation in the probability to become employed by 6.7 percentage points in the long term. Estimates are similar as regards job stability. Table 19 shows that being assessed with a low or medium profiling indicator contributes to a positive variation in the probability of participants to be offered an open-ended contract. In the long term, for instance, the change is equal to, respectively, 13.8 and 7.3 percentage points. Results seem to suggest a greater difficulty for high profiles to produce positive signals to the potential employers in the labour market.

Table 18 OLS: explaining the probability to become employed through profiling
Table 19 OLS: explaining the probability to be offered an open-ended contract through profiling

In this regard, we also take into account the possibility for participants to experience locking-in effects during their internship at the selected firms. Table 18 shows that attending the programme at the firm for 100 additional days corresponds to a reduction in the probability to become employed of 3.8 and 3.3 percentage points in, respectively, the medium and long terms. The latter supports the theory by Cerulli-Harms (2017) on the risks of becoming ‘eternal interns’. Results do not differ as regards the probability of the participants to be offered an open-ended contract. Indeed, a longer participation in the programme does not appear to be remedial for the candidates. The assignment of a low or medium profiling, on the other hand, contributes to explaining part of the positive variation in this labour outcome. However, and as anticipated by the weak correlation coefficients in Table 20, findings are not powerful in terms of the extent to which profiling explains the labour outcomes of the individuals.Footnote 65 The latter is in line with the alternative parallel trends assumption provided in Sect. 6.2 according to which results are not driven by specific profiling types but solely by participation. Nevertheless, individuals who are profiled with a certain type of profiling may experience an emotional shock that increases awareness on their condition. This would then lead them to accept any job offer they receive in line with the idea that the latter is the best they can get anyway. One may consider whether individuals fear social stigma with respect to participation in active labour market policies or social pressure on the part of their families and peers. Further research should investigate the nature of the question.

Table 20 Correlation matrix for labour outcomes and profiling

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Focacci, C.N. “You reap what you sow”: Do active labour market policies always increase job security? Evidence from the Youth Guarantee. Eur J Law Econ 49, 373–429 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-020-09654-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10657-020-09654-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation