Skip to main content
Log in

Environmental Information, Asymmetric Information, and Financial Markets: A Game-Theoretic Approach

  • Published:
Environmental Modeling & Assessment Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the problem of asymmetric information in financial markets due to a lack of essential environmental information. The literature indicates that asymmetric information generates various problems for the actors of financial markets such as incomplete information for investment decisions and lending procedures, misallocation of financial market funds, the underestimating of stock price securities, and poor environmental risk management choices. To this end, this paper develops a game-theoretic approach to examine both the persistent nature of asymmetric information caused by the absence of accurate environmental information and to indicate how a well-organized, trustworthy, internationally agreed auditing accounting certification scheme could play a critical role in limiting the magnitude of this problem.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Many financial institutions may offer the same amount of investment but with better crediting conditions–terms such as lower interests rates. We thank an anonymous referee for pointing this out. In both cases, the ultimate result is a higher value of investment for the recipient firm.

  2. To better visualize this, imagine a checklist that a firm has to complete in order to be considered environmentally responsible. Each tick represents a specific ER action. This way, by breaking down environmentally responsible behavior into a specific series of actions, we simplify and are able to model the complex phenomenon of firm behavior.

  3. In reality, this may be more complicated with different probabilities on different percentages of investment that can be lost. This can be described by an integral containing all possible probabilities for all possible percentages of loss. Without loss of generality and for simplicity reasons, the integral is expressed with the probability of losing the whole investment (firm goes bankrupt).

  4. We thank an anonymous referee for making this point clear.

References

  1. O’Dwyer, B. (2005). Stakeholder democracy: challenges and contributions from social accounting. Business Ethics: A European Review, 14(1), 28–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Blowfield, M. (2005). Corporate social responsibility: reinvesting the meaning of development? International Affairs, 81(3), 515–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Gale, R. (2006). Environmental management accounting as a reflexive modernization strategy in cleaner production. Journal of Cleaner Production, 14, 1228–1236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Lorraine, N. H. S., Collison, D. J., & Power, D. M. (2004). An analysis of the stock market impact of environmental performance information. Account Forum, 28, 7–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Lanoie, P., Laplante, B., & Roy, M. (1998). Can capital markets create incentives for pollution control? Ecological Economics, 26, 31–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. de Beer, P., & Friend, F. (2006). Environmental accounting: a management tool for enhancing corporate environmental and economic performance. Ecological Economics, 58, 548–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Tucker, M. (1997). Climate change and the insurance industry: the cost of increased risk and the impetus for action. Ecological Economics, 22, 85–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Cormier, C., & Magnan, M. (2007). The revisited contribution of environmental reporting to investors’ valuation of firm’s earnings: an international perspectives. Ecological Economics, 62, 613–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Schaltegger, S. (1997). Information costs, quality of information and stakeholder involvement—the necessity of international standards of ecological accounting. Eco-Management and Auditing, 4, 87–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Dorweiler, P. V., & Yakhou, M. (2005). A perspective on the environment’s balance sheet. Journal American Academy and Business, 7(2), 16–22.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Curran, M. M., & Moran, D. (2007). Impact of the FTSE4Good index on firm price: an event study. Journal of Environmental Management, 82, 529–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Nikolaou, I. E., & Yannacopoulos, N. A. (2009). The effect of environmental accounting on financial risk management of firms via insurance. International Journal Monetary Economics Finance, 2(1,8), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  13. Boyd, J. (1997). ‘Green Money’ in the bank: firm responses to environmental financial responsibility values. Management and Decision Economics, 18, 491–506.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Boyer, M., & Laffont, J. J. (1997). Environmental risks and bank liability. European Economic Review, 41, 1427–1459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Williamson, O. E. (1988). The logic of economic organization. Journal Law Economics Organization, 4(1), 65–93.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Spence, A. M. (1973). Job market signaling. Quarterly Journal Economics, 87, 355–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Hoque, Z. (2005). Linking environmental uncertainty to non-financial performance measures and performance: a research note. The British Account Review, 37, 471–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Healy, M. P., & Palepu, G. K. (2001). Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: a review of the empirical disclosure literature. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 31(1–3), 405–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Barth, E. M., Landsman, R. W., & Lang, H. M. (2008). International accounting standards and accounting quality. Journal of Accounting Research, 46(3), 467–498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Lam, S.-S., & Du, J. (2004). Information asymmetry and estimation risk: preliminary evidence form Chinese equity markets. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 12, 311–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Verrecchia, R. (1983). Discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 5, 179–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Suijs, J. (2005). Voluntary disclosure of bad news. Journal Business Finance and Accounting, 32(7, 8), 1423–1435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Dye, R. (1985). Disclosure of nonproprietary information. Journal of Accounting Research, 23, 123–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Wagenhofer, A. (1990). Voluntary disclosure with a strategic opponent. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 12, 341–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Skinner, D. (1994). Why firms voluntarily disclose bad news. Journal of Accounting Research, 32, 38–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Berhelot, S., Cormier, D., & Magnan, M. (2003). Environmental disclosure research: review and synthesis. Journal of Accounting Literature, 22, 1–44.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Neu, D., Warsame, H., & Pedwell, K. (1998). Managing public impressions: environmental disclosures in annual reports. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 23(3), 265–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Bewley, K. (2005). The impact of financial reporting regulation on the market valuation of reported environmental liabilities: preliminary evidence from US and Canadian public companies. Journal International Finance Management Accounting, 16(1), 1–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  30. EC, 2001. Commission recommendation of 30 May on the recognition, Measurement and disclosure of environmental issues in the annual accounts and annual reports of companies, European Commission, 2001/453/EC.

  31. Cooper, M. S., & Owen, L. D. (2007). Corporate social reporting and stakeholder accountability: the missing link. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 32, 649–667.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Gao, S. S., Heravi, S., & Xiao, Z. J. (2005). Determinants of corporate social and environmental reporting in Hong Kong: a research note. Account Forum, 29, 233–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Synnestvedt, T. (2001). Debates over environmental information to stakeholders as a policy instrument. Eco-Management and Auditing, 8, 165–178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  34. Nikolaou, E. I. (2007). Environmental accounting as a tool of qualitative improvement of bank’s services: the case of Greece. International Journal Finance Services Management, 2(1–2), 133–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Dixon, R., Mousa, A. G., & Woodhead, D. A. (2004). The necessary characteristics of environmental auditors: a review of the contribution of financial auditing profession. Account Forum, 28, 119–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  36. Dittenhofer, M. (1995). Environmental accounting and auditing. Management Audting Journal, 10(8), 40–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Power, M. (1997). Expertise and the construction of relevance: accountants and environmental audit. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 22(2), 123–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Gray, R. (2000). Current developments and trends in social and environmental auditing, reporting and attestation: a review and comment. International Journal of Auditing, 4, 247–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Watson, M., & MacKay, J. (2003). Auditing for the environment. Managerial Auditing Journal, 18(8), 625–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Holder-Webb, L., Cohen, J. R., Nath, L., & Wood, D. (2009). The supply of corporate social responsibility disclosures among U.S. firms. Journal Business Ethics, 84, 497–527.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Chymis, A. G., James, H. S., Konduru, S., Pierce, V. L., & Larson, R. L. (2007). Asymmetric information in cattle auctions: the problem of revaccinations. Agricultural Economics, 36, 79–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Chymis A.G. 2007. Using Friedman to understand the relationship between market competition and corporate financial performance. Published Dissertation, Department of Agricultural Economics University of Missouri-Columbia.

  43. Waddock, S. A., & Graves, S. (2000). Performance characteristics of social and traditional investments. Journal Investing, 9(2), 27–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  44. Griffin, J. J., & Mahon, J. F. (1997). The corporate social performance and corporate financial performance debate: twenty-five years of incomparable research. Business Social, 36(1), 5–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  45. Carmora, S., & Tromberta, M. (2008). On the global acceptance of IAS/IFRS accounting standards: the logic and implications of the principles-based system. Journal Accounting Public Policy, 27, 455–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Sunder, S. (2002). Regulatory competition among accounting standards within and across international boundaries. Journal Accounting Public Policy, 21, 219–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Akerlof, G. A. (1970). The market for “lemons”: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal Economy, 84, 488–500.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  49. Bansal, P., & Bongner, W. C. (2002). Deciding on ISO 14001: economics, institutions, and context. Long Range Planning, 35, 269–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Praksh, A., & Potoski, M. (2007). Investing up: FDI and the cross-country diffusion of ISO 14001 management systems. International Studies Quarterly, 51, 723–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Eckerman, I. (2005). The Bhopal gas leak: analyses of causes and consequences by three different models. Journal of Loss Prevention in the process industry, 18, 213–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Kleindorfer, P. R., Belke, J. C., Elliott, M. R., Lee, K., Lowe, R. A., & Feldman, H. I. (2003). Accident epidemiology and the U.S. chemical industry: accident history and worst-case data form. RMP*Info, Risk Analysis, 23(5), 865–881.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Sharfman, M. P., & Fernando, C. S. (2008). Environmental risk management and the cost of capital. Strategic Management Journal, 29, 569–592.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Miles, M. P., Munilla, L. S., & Russel, G. R. (1997). Marketing and environmental registration/certification: what industrial marketers should understand about ISO 14000. Industrial Marketing Management, 26, 363–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ioannis E. Nikolaou.

Appendix

Appendix

e(i,r,k):

The expected value of investment of FI is assumed to be $150,000.

c er :

A cost for ER action will occur as the average cost of EMS implementation. For instance, Bansal and Bogner [49] estimated the costs of ISO 14001 as $20,000 for SMEs and $200,000 for large firms, while Prakash and Potoski [50] calculated the same cost to range from $25,000 to $100,000 correspondingly. For the purpose of our examples, the cost of ER will be $150,000 (an average value of $100,000 and $200,000 for large firms).

c re :

The lack of an auditing system to assure the reliability of firm’s environmental information could be translated by the financial institution as high loan loss provisions to evade the potential financial risks from a future accident. The height of a provision could range from 0 to 100 % of the expected investment. Even though international accounting standards (e.g., SFAS 5) have compelled the banking sector to acknowledge the likelihood of future financial losses by incorporating bad debt expense into its balance sheet, there are no standard methods and percentages to record it. For the purpose our examples, it is assumed as 60 % of investment, namely $90,000 (0.6 × e(i, r, k)).

u :

The height of remedy costs is related to the strength of the damages, the severity of legislation and ensuing penalties. For instance, Union Carbide India Limited paid $3.3 billion for the clean-up costs after the chemical accident at its plant in Bhopal, India in 1984 [51: p. 876]. For the purpose of these examples, based on the work of Kleindorfer et al. [52], the total cost per chemical industry accident will be estimated approximately up to $600,000 (sum of on-site property damage and of site property damage per accident).

\( p_u^{er } \) :

This probability is estimated by drawing data for the chemical industry from FACTS-Hazardous Materials Accidents Knowledge Base (http://www.factsonline.nl/browse-chemical-accidents-in-database/4). According to the data from the last 5 years, the average probability of an accident taking place in a chemical plant will be approximately 0.161 (as seen in the following table). The lack of information on whether these accidents have occurred by ER chemical firms or not leads to the assumption that the probability for an accident to happen by ER firms should be lower than the average probability (0.161). For the purpose of the examples, the probability is 0.1.

\( p_u^n \) :

Given the limitation of the model (\( p_u^{er } > p_u^n \)) and the above judgment, the probability of a firm which has not taken ER to have an accident is 0.3, higher than the average of 0.161.

\( p_l^{er } \) :

The height of this probability is associated with the intensity of environmental accidents, firms’ environmental performance and subsequent on-site property damage and of site property damage (including penalties). Sharfman and Fernando [53: pp. 773] stated that “undertaking environmental risk management activities by improving environmental performance can reduce the likelihood that firms will encounter extreme environmental events that can require heavy cash flows arising from compensation and clean up costs, and thereby make firms more vulnerable to bankruptcy”. The probability is estimated to be near to 0. For the purpose of the examples, it is assumed to be 0.01.

Years

2005

2006

2007

2008

2009

2010

Number of Accidents

43

60

39

48

33

6

Probabilities

(43/365) = 0.117

(60/365) = 0.164

(39/365) = 0.106

(48/365) = 0.131

(33/365) = 0.271

(6/365) = 0.016

Probability mean

0.117 + 0.164 + 0.106 + 0.131 + 0.271 + 0.016 = 0.161

\( p_l^n \) :

This probability will be high when the accident is large scale and accompanied by high penalties. The probability may be close to 1. Nevertheless, for the purpose of the examples, it is assumed to be 0.7.

c c :

This includes the costs for certification by an external auditing certification system. This may be the sum of the costs of certification of ER action (e.g., ISO 14001) as well as the cost for certification for environmental accounting disclosures. Miles et al. [54] estimated certification fees of ER action to be approximately $30,000, while the certification costs for environmental accounting disclosures is considered to be $20,000 as evidenced by the price lists of charter accountants for conventional accounting auditing. Consequently, the total cost is $50,000.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Nikolaou, I.E., Chymis, A. & Evangelinos, K. Environmental Information, Asymmetric Information, and Financial Markets: A Game-Theoretic Approach. Environ Model Assess 18, 615–628 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-013-9371-5

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10666-013-9371-5

Keywords

Navigation