Skip to main content
Log in

Happiness and International Migration

  • Published:
Journal of Happiness Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, we consider the extent to which the aggregate happiness of a country affects the flow of people across its borders. We merge data from the World Values Survey, which produces happiness indices for 84 countries between 1981 and 2004, with three different migration datasets: emigration rates from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, immigration rates from the U.S. Census, and net migration rates from the United Nations. We find that happiness has a U-shaped relationship with emigration rates: emigration rates fall in happiness for relatively unhappy countries, but rise for relatively happy countries. The U-shaped relationship also holds for migrant flows into the U.S. When analyzing net migration rates, we find that the reverse relationship exists. Net migration is associated with an increase in happiness for relatively unhappy countries, but after a threshold level of happiness, net migration is associated with a decrease in happiness. Our findings are robust to various empirical specifications and datasets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Hatton and Williamson (2005) have a nice discussion about how the pressures to limit migration have increased globally during this period, even though actual migrant flows have not decreased.

  2. http://www.un.org/esa/population/publications/2006Migration_Chart/Migration2006.pdf.

  3. Frey and Stutzer (2002) and Di Tella and MacCulloch (2006) offer excellent reviews of this literature.

  4. http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/.

  5. The WVS also reports a life-satisfaction measure, but there is no clear pattern in the economics literature about the use of happiness indices compared to measures of life-satisfaction. Life satisfaction is measured on a 10-point scale compared to the 4-point scale of the happiness index. Not surprisingly, the two indices are highly correlated. We report results using the happiness indices for ease of interpretation. However, results using the life satisfaction data are almost identical and can be obtained from the authors.

  6. Specifically, we computed weighted averages of each country-year cell using the ‘s018’ weight. Weights are defined at: http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org/services/index.html.

  7. http://www.oecd.org/document/51/0,2340,en_2649_37415_34063091_1_1_1_37415,00.html.

  8. We use this measure to be consistent across datasets.

  9. GDP data is not available for Iraq in 1995. Instead of dropping the observations, we used the 1997 GDP level to compute its growth rate. Thus, Iraq grew 58.7% between 1997 and 1999!

  10. Regions are classified using the UN groupings, http://esa.un.org/unpp/index.asp?panel=5.

  11. Source: United Nations Migration Report 1996.

  12. http://esa.un.org/unpp/index.asp?panel=2.

  13. These data were obtained from Weil (2005) and the WDI.

  14. We use a 5-year period in calculating GDP growth rates to represent the recent growth experience of the country. The results are robust to using annual GDP growth rates.

  15. We considered turning Model 2 into a model of immigration, where the independent variables would be unique to the destination country (the U.S.) But since the destination country is the same across the observations, we do not get enough variation in the variables to yield significant coefficient estimates. We also considered a model where the independent variables are in relative terms (for example, relative happiness was defined as U.S. happiness divided by the source country happiness). Once again, there was little variation in U.S. happiness over the time period. Thus, we arrive at Model 2 that represents the flow of people out of country i and into the U.S. in each year as a fraction of country i’s population.

  16. For all three models, various statistical models were considered, specifically, OLS models with log and square root transformations as well as generalized linear models with Gaussian and gamma families and multiple link functions. Using AIC as a model-selection criterion, none of these models were substantially better than the OLS model, and due to the ease of interpretation of the OLS model, it was chosen. In fact, the predictions from all models considered gave similar results.

  17. We calculate the inflection point by differentiating the estimated models. h* is based on the estimated coefficients for the happiness indicator (β1) and its square (β2), holding all other variables constant. That is, h* = −β1/2β2.

  18. Note that we also consider past GDP growth. The results are similar to those presented. Ideally, we would use GDP in the previous 5 years to be consistent with the other models, but in doing so we lose eight observations.

  19. The set of control variables considered is smaller than in Model 1 because we do not have time series data on variables such as Gini coefficients, corruption, rule of law, etc.

  20. These thresholds are calculated for specification C in all three cases.

  21. In their study, the life orientation test was used to measure optimistic versus pessimistic attitudes towards the future.

References

  • Alesina, A., Di Tella, R., & MacCulloch, R. (2004). Inequality and happiness: Are Europeans and Americans different? Journal of Public Economics, 88(9–10), 2009–2042.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2004a). Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7–8), 1359–1386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. G., & Oswald, A. J. (2004b). Money, sex and happiness: An empirical study. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 3, 393–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. J. (1987). Self-selection and the earnings of immigrants. American Economic Review, 77, 531–553.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G. J. (1989). Economic theory and international migration. International Migration Review, 23(3), 457–485.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borjas, G., & Bratsberg, B. (1996). Who leaves? The outmigration of the foreign-born. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78(1), 165–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick, B. (2000). Are immigrants favorably self-selected? An economic analysis. In C. D. Brettell & J. F. Hollifield (Eds.), Migration theory: talking across disciplines (pp. 61–76). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, X., Hatton, T. J., & Williamson, J. G. (2007). Explaining U.S. immigration, 1971–1998. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(2), 359–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., & MacCulloch, R. (2006). Some uses of happiness data in economics. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 25–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R., & Oswald, A. J. (2003). The macroeconomics of happiness. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 809–827.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. David & M. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth: essays in honour of Moses Abramovitz (pp. 98–125). New York and London: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (2003). Explaining happiness. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 100(19), 11176–11183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckersley, R. (2000). The mixed blessings of material progress: Diminishing returns in the pursuit of happiness. Journal of Happiness Studies, 1(3), 267–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ek, E., Koiranena, M., Raatikkaa, V. P., Järvelinc, M. R., & Taanila, A. (2008). Psychosocial factors as mediators between migration and subjective well-being among young Finnish adults. Social Science and Medicine, 66(7), 1545–1556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2000a). Happiness prospers in democracy. Journal of Happiness Studies, 1(1), 79–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2000b). Happiness, economy and institutions. Economic Journal, 110(466), 918–938.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B., & Stutzer, A. (2002). What can economists learn from happiness research? Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 402–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, C. (2005). Insights on development from the economics of happiness. World Bank Research Observer, 20(2), 201–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, M., McDowell, J., Waldman, D., & Zahniser, S. (1999). The influence of social programs in source countries on various classes of U.S. immigration. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 94, 64–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatton, T. J., & Williamson, J. G. (1998). The age of mass migration: causes and economic impact. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatton, T. J., & Williamson, J. G. (2005). What fundamentals drive world migration? In G. Borjas & J. Crisp (Eds.), Poverty, international migration and asylum (pp. 15–38). New York: Palgrave Macmillan in association with the United Nations University-World Institute for Development Economics Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. F. (2007). Well-being and social capital: Does suicide pose a puzzle? Social Indicators Research, 81, 455–496.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helliwell, J. F., & Huang, H. (2008). How’s your government? International evidence linking good government and well-being. British Journal of Political Science, 38, 595–619.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1932). The theory of wages. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Krueger, A. B. (2006). Developments in the measurement of subjective well-being. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(1), 3–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karemera, D., Oguledo, V. I., & Davis, B. (2000). A gravity model analysis of international migration to North America. Applied Economics, 32(13), 1745–1755.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (1980). Human satisfactions and public policy. The Economic Journal, 90(360), 737–750.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Layard, R. (2005). Happiness: lessons from a new science. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D. (2006). Who says money cannot buy happiness? Independent Review, 10(3), 385–400.

    Google Scholar 

  • Massey, D. S. (1988). Economic development and international migration in comparative perspective. Population and Development Review, 14(3), 383–413.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Massey, D. S., Arango, J., Hugo, G., Kouaouci, A., Pellegrino, A., & Taylor, J. E. (1993). Theories of international migration: A review and appraisal. Population and Development Review, 19(3), 431–466.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayda, A.M. (2008). International migration: a panel data analysis of the determinants of bilateral flows, Journal of Population Economics. doi:10.1007/s00148-009-0251-x.

  • Oswald, A. J. (1997). Happiness and economic performance. The Economic Journal, 107(445), 1815–1831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rotte, R., & Vogler, M. (2000). The effects of development on migration: Theoretical issues and new empirical evidence. Journal of Population Economics, 13(3), 485–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sjaastad, L. A. (1962). The costs and returns to human migration. Journal of Political Economy, 70, 80–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stalker, P. (2000). Workers without frontiers: The impact of globalisation on international migration. London: Lynne Reinner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B. & Wolfers, J. (2008). Economic growth and subjective well-being: reassessing the Easterlin Paradox. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 1–87.

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolfers, J. (2009). The paradox of declining female happiness. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2), 190–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stuart, J. (2005). Dr. Feelgood. The Independent Review, 3, 2–3.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vendrik, M., & Woltjer, G. (2007). Happiness and loss aversion: Is utility concave or convex in relative income? Journal of Public Economics, 91, 1423–1448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil, D. (2005). Economic growth. Upper Saddle River, NJ: Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We wish to thank Michelle Wiggins for excellent research assistance. This paper benefited from helpful comments made by Takao Kato, Giovanni Peri, Ann Own, seminar participants at Lafayette College, the Midwest Economic Association 2007 meetings in Minneapolis, and the American Economic Association 2009 meetings in San Francisco, CA. All errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Linnea A. Polgreen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Polgreen, L.A., Simpson, N.B. Happiness and International Migration. J Happiness Stud 12, 819–840 (2011). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-010-9229-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-010-9229-3

Keywords

Navigation