Skip to main content
Log in

The Complex Relationship Between Education and Happiness: The Case of Highly Educated Individuals in Italy

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Happiness Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The present work aims to explore whether there exists a systematic frustration in terms of income expectations among those who have obtained high level of education in Italy, and if this mismatch between expected and effective incomes negatively affects their perception of happiness. We adopt a reference-dependent preferences model combined with the concept of “illusory superiority bias” to analyse data on “happiness” in Italy, provided by the biennial survey conducted by the Bank of Italy on the Italian households’ incomes and wealth between 2004 and 2014. Our results show a positive effect produced by education on incomes. High educated workers have on average higher income than other people, and this difference is statistically significant controlling for working experience and other possible confounding factors. However, the disutility resulting from the frustration of expectations produces negative effects on perceived happiness. Even though highly educated people are actually able to find better job matching in comparison to less educated workers, they are also more likely to seeing their income expectations frustrated.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The illusory superiority bias may be defined as a perceptual distorsion that affects individuals when they compare themselves to other people. In particular, when people are affected by ISB they tend to believe that they are better than others and they will have a brighter future.

  2. We are implicitly assuming that µ > 0 since a µ = 0 will imply that workers do not receive a wage for their job.

  3. Obviously when expectations are perfectly realized, i.e. w = E(w), the second term of Eq. (1) is equal to zero, and therefore the derivate is calculated only for the first term.

  4. The question is asked only to survey’s respondent and not to all his/her family members. Furthermore, from 2004 to 2010, only a random half of the respondents were interviewed about their perceived happiness. The discussion about an appropriate measure of well-being goes behind the scope of this paper. As observed by Stevenson and Wolvers (2008), even though happiness and life satisfaction may be considered as two different concepts, much of the economics literature assessing subjective well-being used the measures of “life satisfaction” and “happiness” interchangeably. Indeed, these alternative measures of well-being are highly correlated and have similar covariates. See also Frey and Stutzer (2002) for a discussion of the reason why question about subjective happiness may be a good proxy for perceived utility. Unfortunately, in Bank of Italy’s survey a question on job satisfaction was introduced only in two waves (2006–2008) and asked only to half of the occupied respondents implying thus a modest sample size (around 2000 individuals). This has prevented us to test if the effect of frustrated expectations on happiness passes only through a possible relation with job satisfaction.

  5. For more information on the sampling techniques used by the Bank of Italy, see the Supplements to the Statistical Bulletin: http://www.bancaditalia.it/statistiche/indcamp/bilfait/boll_stat.

  6. For each individual, we demeaned the variable years of experience by subtracting the sample mean. Hence, the demeaned variable and its square were used in the model, instead of the original one. This operation was necessary to reduce the obvious collinearity that exists between the original variable and its square.

  7. Note that the sample size differs in this case from that reported in Table 3, because of missing observations for the dependent variable (we remind that this question is not asked to all the participants to the survey).

References

  • AlmaLaurea. (2015). Indagine Almalaurea 2015 sui Dottori di Ricerca. Tra perfomance di studio e mercato del lavoro. https://www.almalaurea.it/.

  • Argentin, G., Ballarino, G., & Colombo, S. (2014). Investire in formazione dopo la laurea: Il dottorato di ricerca in Italia. Working papers no. 60, February, AlmaLaurea Inter-University Consortium. http://www2.almalaurea.it.

  • Bank of Italy. (2015). Survey on household income and wealth. Years 2004, 2006, 2008, 2010, 2012, 2014.

  • Clark, A. E., Frijters, P., & Shields, M. A. (2008). Relative income, happiness and utility: An explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. Journal of Economic Literature,46(1), 95–144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark, A. E., & Oswald, A. J. (1996). Satisfaction and comparison income. Journal of Public Economics,61, 359–381.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunado, J., & Pérez de Gracia, F. (2012). Does education affect happiness? Evidence for Spain. Social Indicator Research,108, 185–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M., & Lleras-Muney, A. (2006). Education and health: Evaluating theories and evidences. NBER working paper no. 12352, July, National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). http://www.nber.org/papers/w12352.

  • De la Garza, A., Mastrobuoni, G., Sannabe, A., & Yamada, K. (2010). The relative utility hypothesis with and without self-reported reference wages. ISER discussion paper no. 798, Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University.

  • Di Tella, R., MacCulloch, R. J., & Oswald, A. J. (2001). Preferences over inflation and unemployment: Evidence from surveys of happiness. American Economic Review,91, 335–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (2006). Life cycle happiness and its sources. Intersections of psychology, economics, and demography. Journal of Economic Psychology,27, 463–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, M. D. R., & Kelley, J. (2004). Subjective social location: Data from 21 nations. International Journal of Public Opinion Research,16, 3–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrante, F. (2009). Education, aspirations and life satisfaction. Kyklos,62(4), 542–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fiaschi, D., & Gabbriellini, C. (2013). Wage function and rate of returns to education. Unpublished manuscript, University of Pisa. http://www.ecineq.org/ecineq_bari13/FILESxBari13/CR2/p253.pdf.

  • Frey, B. S., & Stutzer, A. (2002). What can economists lean from happiness research? Journal of Economic Literature,40, 402–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gneezy, A., Gneezy, U., & Oliè Lauga, D. (2014). A reference-dependent model of the price-quality heuristic. Journal of Marketing Research,LI, 153–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoorens, V. (1995). Self-favoring biases, self-presentation, and the self-other asymmetry in social comparison. Journal of Personality, 63(4), 793–817.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Inglehart, R., & Klingemann, H. D. (2000). Genes, culture, democracy and happiness. In E. Diener & M. S. Eunkook (Eds.), Culture and subjective wellbeing (pp. 165–183). Boston: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ishikawa, T. (2001). Income and wealth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Istat. (2015). L’inserimento professionale dei Dottori di Ricerca. Anno 2014. Statistiche report. https://www.Istat.it.

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica,47(2), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Köszegi, B., & Rabin, M. (2006). A model of reference-dependent preferences. Quarterly Journal of Economics,121(4), 1133–1165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann, W. (2009). University as vocational education: Working-class students’ expectations for university. British Journal of Sociology of Education,30(2), 137–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manfra, P. (2002). Entrepreneurship, firm size and the structure of the Italian economy. Journal of Entrepreneurial Finance and Business Ventures,7(3), 99–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson, B., & Wolvers, J. (2008). Economic growth and subjective well-being: Reassessing the Easterlin paradox. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Economic Studies Program,39(1), 1–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (2003). Reference-dependent subjective expected utility. Journal of Economic Theory,111(2), 172–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (1995). Selection corrections for panel data models under conditional mean independence assumptions. Journal of Econometrics,68, 115–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Funding

Funding

The research activity carried out by Gabriele Ruiu has been in part financed by the “Fondo per il finanziamento dei dipartimenti universitari di eccellenza” (Law nr. 232/2016).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gabriele Ruiu.

Appendix

Appendix

Tables 5, 6 and 7.

Table 5 Other descriptive statisticsa
Table 6 The probability of observing unfulfilled expectations: Alternative specification
Table 7 Happiness determinants: alternative specification

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ruiu, G., Ruiu, M.L. The Complex Relationship Between Education and Happiness: The Case of Highly Educated Individuals in Italy. J Happiness Stud 20, 2631–2653 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-018-0062-4

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10902-018-0062-4

Keywords

Navigation