Skip to main content
Log in

On the optimal number of advertising slots in a generalized second-price auction

  • Published:
Marketing Letters Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In search advertising, a search engine uses a generalized second-price auction to sell advertising slots adjacent to search results on its webpage. In this paper, we study an interesting question related to the design of the generalized second-price auction: how should a search engine strategically decide on the number of advertising slots? To answer this question, we analyze the implication of varying the number of slots in a base model in which the click-through rates are assumed to be independent of the number of slots. When deciding the number of slots, we find that a search engine’s profit is based on two counteracting factors: the incremental clicks from an extra slot and the influence of the extra slot on advertisers’ payments per click. Our analysis characterizes the conditions for optimality of the number of slots and the implications of different distributions for advertiser valuations. We also extend the base model to allow for attraction and cannibalization of clicks from existing slots by new ad slots and show how such effects affect the optimal number of slots. Our overall results show that search engines need to optimize the number of ad slots offered for auction in order to maximize profit.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. An alternative research stream develops empirical models of advertiser, consumer, and search engine behavior using consumer click data. Rutz and Bucklin (2007) and Ghose and Yang (2009) present qualitative response models of the relationship between various search ad metrics such as click-through rates, conversion rates, ad ranking, or position and cost per click. Yao and Mela (2011) develop a dynamic structural model of advertisers’ bidding behavior and consumers’ clicking behavior to empirically evaluate the impact of search results page design, auction pricing policy and advertiser bidding process on search engine revenues.

  2. The maximum number of ad slots varies across search engines. For example, Bing has a maximum of nine ad slots, whereas Google has 11 slots.

  3. Further, if advertisers expect that the publisher would use their bids to decide on the number of slots, they may bid strategically, thus making implementation difficult.

  4. Our results are also applicable to web publishers that import and display the ads from search advertising service providers, e.g., NYTimes.com imports ads from Google.

  5. Advertisers may participate as long as they see an opportunity to make a profit which will typically mean at least K + 1 advertisers would participate in the auction when K < N.

  6. The superscript again accounts for the total number of ad slots available.

  7. Note that our results do not require all N potential advertisers participate in the auction. It is sufficient if the top K + 1 advertisers in terms of v i participate in an auction with K slots. Thus, our analysis allows for the number of bidders to depend on K.

  8. The function f(x) is said to be log-concave if ln(f(x)) is concave. If f(x) is log-concave, so is 1 − F(x), hence the hazard rate is increasing in x, meaning IHR.

  9. When the shape parameter is less than 1, the appendix shows that J(v) is always negative.

  10. From Proposition 3 in Balachander et al. (2009), \( p_k^K = \frac{1}{{\alpha_k^K{\chi_{{g(k)}}}}}\left\{ {\sum\nolimits_{{j = k}}^K {{v_{{j + 1}}}\left( {\alpha_j^K - \alpha_{{j + 1}}^K} \right)} } \right\} \) and \( p_k^{{K + 1}} = \frac{1}{{\alpha_k^{{K + 1}}{\chi_{{g(k)}}}}}\left\{ {\sum\nolimits_{{j = k}}^{{K + 1}} {{v_{{j + 1}}}\left( {\alpha_j^{{K + 1}} - \alpha_{{j + 1}}^{{K + 1}}} \right)} } \right\} \). Note that \( \alpha_j^K = \alpha_j^{{K + 1}} \), for 1 ≤ j ≤ K, \( \alpha_{{K + 1}}^K \) = 0, \( \alpha_{{K + 1}}^{{K + 1}} \) > 0, and \( \alpha_{{K + 2}}^{{K + 1}} \) = 0. Then, we have \( p_k^K - p_k^{{K + 1}} = \frac{{\alpha_{{K + 1}}^{{K + 1}}}}{{\alpha_k^K{\chi_{{g(k)}}}}}\left\{ {{v_{{K + 1}}} - {v_{{K + 2}}}} \right\} > 0 \).

  11. For example, with a uniform distribution on valuations over [0,1], Edelman and Schwarz (2006) would suggest a minimum bid of \( {b_{{\min }}} = \frac{1}{2} \), which results from solving \( v = \frac{{1 - F(v)}}{{f(v)}} \). Note that b min depends on the range of valuations.

  12. We skip the details of equilibrium analysis for equilibrium bids and profits in the second stage. See Balachander et al. (2009) for the details of equilibrium analysis

References

  • Arnold, B. C., Balakrishnan, N., & Nagaraja, H. N. (1992). A first course in order statistics. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli, M., & Bergstrom, T. (2004). Log-concave probability and its applications. UC Santa Barbara, Department of Economics.

  • Balachander, S., Kannan, K., & Schwartz, D. (2009). A theoretical and empirical analysis of alternative auction polcies for search advertisements. Review of Marketing Science, 7.

  • Brynjolfsson, E., Hu, Y., & Simester, D. (2012). Goodbye Pareto principle, hello long tail: the effect of search costs on the concentration of product. Management Science (in press)

  • Chen, Y., & He, C. (2007). Paid placement: advertising and search on the internet. Working Paper, University of Colorado.

  • Chen, J., Liu, D., & Whinston, A. B. (2009). Auctioning keywords in online search. Journal of Marketing, 73, 125–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, P., & Shin, W. (2009). Advertiser-specific minimum bids in keyword search auctions. Working Paper, Duke University.

  • Edelman, B., & Schwarz, M. (2006). Optimal auction design in a milti-unit environment: the case of sponsored search auctions. mimeo, Harvard University and Yahoo! Research.

  • Edelman, B., Ostrovsky, M., & Schwarz, M. (2007). Internet advertising and the generalized second price auctions: selling billions of dollars worth keywords. American Economic Review, 97(1), 242–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • eMarketer. (2009, Jan). “What happened to search spending in 2008?” eMarketer News Report.

  • Feng, J., Bhargava, H., & Pennock, D. (2005). Inplementing sponsored search in web search engines: computational evaluation of alternative mechanisms. INFORMS Journal on Computing, 19–1, 137–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ghose, A., & Yang, S. (2009). An empirical analysis of search engine advertising: sponsored search in electronic markets. Management Science, 55(10), 1605–1622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J. S. (1975). A note on order statistics from Pareto distribution. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 3, 187–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J., & Puto, C. (1983). Market boundaries and product choice: illustrating attraction and substitution effects. Journal of Consumer Research, 10, 31–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katona, Z., & Sarvary, M. (2010). The race for sponsored links: bidding patterns for search advertising. Marketing Science, 29(2), 199–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAfee, P., & McMillan, J. (1987). Auctions and biddings. Journal of Economic Literature, 15, 699–738.

    Google Scholar 

  • NYTimes. (2008). Stuck in Google’s Doghouse.” nytimes.com.

  • Renyi, A. (1953). On the theory of order statistics. Acta Mathematica Academiae Scientiarum Hungaricae, 4, 191–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutz, O., & Bucklin, R. E. (2007). A model of individual keyword performance in paid search advertising. Working Paper, UCLA.

  • Varian, H. R. (2007). Position auctions. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 25, 1163–1178.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yao, S., & Mela, C. M. (2011). A dynamic model of sponsored search advertising. Marketing Science, 30(3), 447–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Subramanian Balachander.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

From Proposition 3 in Balachander et al. (2009), we have the total profit with K slots asFootnote 12

$$ \pi_K^S = \sum\nolimits_{{k = 1}}^K {\sum\nolimits_{{j = k}}^k {{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right)\left( {{\alpha_j} - {\alpha_{{j + 1}}}} \right) = \sum\limits_{{j = 1}}^K {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right)\left( {{\alpha_j} - {\alpha_{{j + 1}}}} \right)} } } $$
(A.1)

Then,

$$ \pi_K^S = \sum\limits_{{j = 1}}^{{K - 1}} {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right)\left( {{\alpha_j} - {\alpha_{{j + 1}}}} \right) + K{E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right){\alpha_K}} $$
(A.2)
$$ \pi_{{K + 1}}^S = \sum\limits_{{j = 1}}^{{K - 1}} {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right)\left( {{\alpha_j} - {\alpha_{{j + 1}}}} \right) + K{E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)\left( {{\alpha_K} - {\alpha_{{K + 1}}}} \right) + \left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right)} $$
(A.3)

To compute the marginal profit we subtract (A.2) from (A.3).

$$ \pi_{{K + 1}}^S - \pi_K^S = - {\text{K}}{{\text{E}}_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right){\alpha_{{K + 1}}} + \left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right){\alpha_{{K + 1}}} $$
(A.4)

If Eq. (A.4) is positive, then a search engine has an incentive to increase the number of slot to K + 1. In other words, the marginal profit condition becomes

$$ \left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right) - {\text{K}}{{\text{E}}_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right) \geqslant 0 $$
(A.5)

Using property of order statistics, the expected valuation of K + 1th and K + 2th advertisers is given as follows:

$$ {E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right) = \int_0^{\infty } {\left\{ {v\frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!K!}}f(v){{\left[ {F(v)} \right]}^{{N - K - 1}}}{{\left[ {1 - F(v)} \right]}^K}} \right\}dv.} $$
(A.6)
$$ {E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right) = \int_0^{\infty } {\left\{ {v\frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 2} \right)!\left( {K + 1} \right)!}}f(v){{\left[ {F(v)} \right]}^{{N - K - 2}}}{{\left[ {1 - F(v)} \right]}^{{K + 1}}}} \right\}dv} $$
(A.7)

Then, integrating E N (v K + 2) by parts we have

$$ \matrix{ {{E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right)} \hfill \\ { = \frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!\left( {K + 1} \right)!}}\left\{ { - \int_0^{\infty } {{{\left[ {F(v)} \right]}^{{N - K - 1}}}{{\left[ {1 - F(v)} \right]}^{{K + 1}}}dv - \left( {K + 1} \right)\int_0^{\infty } {vf(v)F{{(v)}^{{N - K - 1}}}{{\left[ {1 - F(v)} \right]}^K}dv} } } \right\}} \hfill \\ { = - \frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!\left( {K + 1} \right)!}}\int_0^{\infty } {{{\left[ {F(v)} \right]}^{{N - K - 1}}}{{\left[ {1 - F(v)} \right]}^{{K + 1}}}dv + {E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} } \hfill \\ }<!end array> $$
(A.8)

Plugging (A.8) and (A.6) into (A.5) gives (A.9).

$$ \int_0^{\infty } {\left\{ {\frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!K!}}f(v){{\left[ {F(v)} \right]}^{{N - K - 1}}}{{\left[ {1 - F(v)} \right]}^K}\left[ {v - \frac{{1 - F(v)}}{{f(v)}}} \right]} \right\}dv \geqslant 0} $$
(A.9)

Let \( J(v) = v - \frac{{1 - F(v)}}{{f(v)}} \), then (A.9) becomes E N (J(v K + 1)).

1.2 Proof of Proposition 3(a)

For the uniform valuation distribution, Eq. (A.5) reduces to the following:

$$ \frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 2} \right)!K!}}\int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K - 1}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}} \right]dv - \frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!\left( {K - 1} \right)!}}\int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^K}} \right]dv \geqslant 0} } $$
(A.10)

By letting \( \int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K - 1}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}} \right]dv} \) be A and \( \int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^K}} \right]dv} \) be B, (A.10) reduces to

$$ \frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 2} \right)!K!}}\left\{ A \right\} - \frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!\left( {K - 1} \right)!}}\left\{ B \right\} \geqslant 0 $$

Through integration by parts, B becomes

$$ \int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\frac{{{v^{{N - K}}}{{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}}}{{K + 1}}dv + \frac{{N - K}}{{K + 1}}\int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K - 1}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}} \right]dv} } $$
(A.11)

Since the first term in (A.11) reduces to zero, (A.11) reduces to the following:

$$ \frac{{N - K}}{{K + 1}}\int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K - 1}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}} \right]dv} $$
(A.12)

Plugging (A.12) into (A.10), (A.10) becomes

$$ \left[ {\frac{{N!}}{{\left( {N - K - 2} \right)!K!}} - \frac{{N!\left( {N - K} \right)}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!\left( {K - 1} \right)!\left( {K + 1} \right)}}} \right]\int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K - 1}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}} \right]dv \geqslant 0} $$
(A.13)

Inequality (A.13) further reduces to \( \left[ {\frac{{N!\left( {N - 2K - 1} \right)}}{{\left( {N - K - 1} \right)!\left( {K + 1} \right)!}}} \right]\int_0^{{{v^{{\max }}}}} {\left[ {{v^{{N - K - 1}}} - {{\left( {1 - v} \right)}^{{K + 1}}}} \right]dv \geqslant 0} \), and by simplifying this we can show that this inequality holds if \( K \leqslant \frac{{N - 1}}{2} \). Since the number of slots is an integer, we assume that a search engine increases K until the marginal profit becomes zero or negative. This implies \( {K^{ * }} = \left\lceil {\frac{{N - 1}}{2}} \right\rceil \) .

1.3 Proof of Proposition 3(b)

Let the CDF of the Pareto distribution be \( F\left( {v;a,\beta } \right) = 1 - {\left( {\frac{a}{v}} \right)^{\beta }},v > a \), where a is the lower bound of v, a > 0, and β > 0, which is the shape parameter.

According to the well-known representation theorem of Renyi (1953) and Huang (1975),

$$ {v_K} = a\prod\nolimits_{{i = k}}^N {{\eta_i}} $$
(A.14)

Where η i ,…,η N are independent Pareto variables, with η i  ∼ F(1,). Because the mean of F(1,) is \( \frac{{a\beta }}{{\beta - 1}} \) for β > 1and η i  ∼ F(1,), we can easily obtain that (Arnold et al. 1992)

$$ {E_N}\left( {{v_K}} \right) = \frac{{a\Gamma \left( {N + 1} \right)\Gamma \left( {K - 1/\beta } \right)}}{{\Gamma (K)\Gamma \left( {N + 1 - 1/\beta } \right)}} \;{\text{for}}\;\beta \; > \;1 $$
(A.15)

Using (A.15), the marginal profit condition, (A.5) reduces to

$$ \Gamma \left( {K + 2 - 1/\beta } \right) - K\Gamma \left( {K + 1 - 1/\beta } \right) = \left[ {K + 1 - 1/\beta } \right]\Gamma \left( {K + 1 - 1/\beta } \right) \geqslant 0 $$
(A.16)

Because 1 − 1/β > 0, we have

$$ \matrix{ {\Gamma \left( {K + 1 - 1/\beta } \right) = \left( {K - 1/\beta } \right)\left( {K - 1/\beta - 1} \right) \ldots \left( {1 - 1/\beta } \right)\Gamma \left( {1 - 1/\beta } \right)} \hfill \\ { = \left( {1 - 1/\beta } \right)\Gamma \left( {1 - 1/\beta } \right)\sum\nolimits_{{r = 1}}^{{K - 1}} {\left( {K + 1 - 1/\beta - r} \right)} = \left( {K \frac{{ - 1}}{2} } \right)\left( {\beta \left( {K + 2} \right) - 2} \right) \geqslant 0} \hfill \\ }<!end array> $$
(A.17)

(A.17) implies that the marginal profit condition is positive for all K because β > 1. Therefore, K* = N.

1.4 Proof of Proposition 3(c)

According to Arnold et al. (1992), the (ξ − 1)th moment of v i:N , the ith order statistic of N valuations, is given by

$$ \mu_{{i:N}}^{{\xi - 1}} = B{\left( {i,N - i + 1} \right)^{{ - 1}}}\int_0^{\infty } {{v^{{\xi - 1}}}{{\left( {1 - {e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{N - i}}}{{\left( {{e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^i}dv} $$
(A.18)

Integrating this by parts with v ξ−1 dv and (1 − e v)Ni (e v)i, we have

$$ \matrix{ {\mu_{{i:N}}^{{\xi - 1}}} \hfill \\ { = B{{\left( {i,N - i + 1} \right)}^{{ - 1}}}\left[ { - \int_0^{\infty } {\frac{{{v^{\xi }}}}{\xi }\left( {N - i} \right){{\left( {1 - {e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{N - i - 1}}}{{\left( {{e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{i + 1}}}dv + \int_0^{\infty } {\frac{{{v^{\xi }}}}{\xi }\left( {N - i} \right){{\left( {1 - {e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{N - i}}}{{\left( {{e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^i}(i)dv} } } \right]} \hfill \\ { = - \frac{{N!(i)}}{{\left( {N - i - 1} \right)!(i)!\xi }}\int_0^{\infty } {{v^{\xi }}{{\left( {1 - {e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{N - i - 1}}}{{\left( {{e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{i + 1}}}dv} + \frac{{N!(i)}}{{\left( {N - 1} \right)!\left( {i - 1} \right)!\xi }}\int_0^{\infty } {{v^{\xi }}{{\left( {1 - {e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^{{N - i}}}{{\left( {{e^{{ - v}}}} \right)}^i}dv} } \hfill \\ { = - \mu_{{i + 1:N}}^{\xi }\frac{i}{\xi } + \mu_{{i + 1:N}}^{\xi }\frac{i}{\xi }} \hfill \\ }<!end array> $$
(A.19)

Thus, \( \mu_{{i:N}}^{\xi } = - \mu_{{i + 1:N}}^{\xi } + \frac{{\xi \mu_{{i:N}}^{{\xi - 1}}}}{i} \). Using this last identity and recursively plugging the E N (v i ), i = 1,…,N, we obtain

$$ {E_N}\left( {{v_K}} \right) = \sum\nolimits_{{r = K}}^N {K\frac{1}{r}} $$
(A.20)

Thus, the marginal profit condition becomes

$$ \left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right) - K{E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right) = \left( {K + 1} \right)\sum\nolimits_{{r = K + 2}}^N {\frac{1}{r} - K} \sum\nolimits_{{r = K + 1}}^N {\frac{1}{r} = K} \left\lceil { - \frac{1}{{K + 1}}} \right\rceil + \sum\nolimits_{{r = K + 2}}^N {\frac{1}{r} \geqslant 0} $$
(A.21)

1.5 Proof of Proposition 4(a)

From Proposition 3 in Balachander et al. (2009), we have the total profit with K slots as

$$ \pi_K^S = \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right)\left( {\alpha_j^K - \alpha_{{j + 1}}^K} \right) = \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\alpha_j^K\left[ {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right) - \left( {j - 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right]} } . $$
(A.22)

Then, we have

$$ \matrix{ {\pi_{{K + 1}}^S - \pi_K^S = \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\alpha_j^{{K + 1}}\left[ {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right) - \left( {j - 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right]} - \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\alpha_j^K\left[ {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right) - \left( {j - 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right]} } \hfill \\ { + \alpha_{{K + 1}}^{{K + 1}}\left[ {\left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right) - (K){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right]} \hfill \\ { = \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\left( {\alpha_j^{{K + 1}} - \alpha_j^K} \right)\left[ {j{E_N}\left( {{v_{{j + 1}}}} \right) - \left( {j - 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right] + \alpha_{{K + 1}}^{{K + 1}}\left[ {\left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right) - (K){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right]} } \hfill \\ }<!end array> $$
(A.23)

Using the relation in Proposition 1 that \( \left( {K + 1} \right){E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 2}}}} \right) - K{E_N}\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right) = {E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right) \), Eq. (A.23) becomes

$$ \matrix{ {\pi_{{K + 1}}^S - \pi_K^S = \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\left\{ {\left[ {\alpha_j^{{K + 1}} - \alpha_j^K} \right]{E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right)} \right\} + \alpha_{{K + 1}}^{{K + 1}}\left[ {{E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{k + 1}}}} \right)} \right)} \right]} } \hfill \\ { = \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\left( {\alpha_j^{{K + 1}} - \alpha_j^K} \right){E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right) + \left[ {{Z^{{K + 1}}} - {Z^K} + \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\left( {\alpha_j^K - \alpha_j^{{K + 1}}} \right)} } \right]{E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right)} } \hfill \\ { = - \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\left( {\alpha_j^{{K + 1}} - \alpha_j^K} \right)\left[ {{E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right) - {E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right)} \right] + \left( {{Z^{{K + 1}}} - {Z^K}} \right){E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right)} } \hfill \\ }<!end array> $$
(A.24)

Since the search engine would add slots when (A.24) is non-negative, the condition to profitably add a slot is

$$ \left( {{Z^{{K + 1}}} - {Z^K}} \right){E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right) \geqslant \sum\nolimits_{{j = 1}}^K {\left( {\alpha_j^K - \alpha_j^{{K + 1}}} \right)\left[ {{E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_i}} \right)} \right) - {E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right)} \right]} . $$
(A.25)

1.6 Proof of Proposition 4(b-2)

When \( {Z^{{K + 1}}} = {Z^K},\forall K \), the left-hand side term in (A.25) is zero. However, the right-hand side term is always non-negative because, \( {v_j} > {v_{{j + 1}}},\forall j \) in equilibrium, J(v) is monotonically increasing in v, and \( \alpha_j^K > \alpha_j^{{K + 1}} \). Therefore K* = 1. When \( {Z^K} > {Z^{{K + 1}}},\forall K \), the optimal number of slots is one, because the left-hand side of (A.25) is negative for all K ≥ 1 while the right-hand side is non-negative.

1.7 Proof of Proposition 4(b-3)

Note that \( \alpha_j^K < \alpha_j^{{K + 1}} \) implies \( {Z^K} < {Z^{{K + 1}}} \). Thus, the left-hand side of (A.25) is always positive. However, the right-hand side is always negative because \( {E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_j}} \right)} \right) \geqslant {E_N}\left( {J\left( {{v_{{K + 1}}}} \right)} \right) \) given that \( {v_j} > {v_{{j + 1}}},\forall j \) in equilibrium and J(v) is monotonically increasing in v. Thus, K* = N.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kim, A., Balachander, S. & Kannan, K. On the optimal number of advertising slots in a generalized second-price auction. Mark Lett 23, 851–868 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-012-9193-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11002-012-9193-2

Keywords

Navigation