Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Exchange Rate Volatility and Productivity Growth: The Role of Liability Dollarization

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies how liability dollarization conditions the effect of exchange rate flexibility on growth. It develops a model with credit-constrained firms facing liquidity shocks denominated in tradables while their revenues are both in tradable and nontradables. With frictions in the reallocation between tradables and nontradables, a peg is more growth-enhancing than a float in countries with dollarized debt because it stabilizes firms’ cash flows and therefore allows them to face liquidity shock and complete their innovation process. However, this relative advantage diminishes when dollarization decreases. These theoretical predictions are confirmed by an empirical analysis on a panel of 76 countries spanning 1995–2004: the higher the degree of dollarization, the more negative the impact of exchange rate flexibility on growth. The empirical results are robust to various specifications and to the treatment of endogeneity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Baxter and Stockman (1989) were the first to bring this “instability puzzle” forward. The literature has since been inconclusive on the subject: Husain et al. (2005) find that exchange rate flexibility is growth-enhancing in industrial countries and neutral in developing economies, while Dubas et al. (2005), relying on an alternative exchange-rate classification, find that a fixed exchange rate has good growth performances in the latter while it is neutral in the former. Levy-Yeyati and Sturzenegger (2003) find that, on average, countries with a fixed exchange rate regime grow at a slower rate. See Tavlas et al. (2008) for a recent survey on this literature.

  2. Early contributions include, among others, Calvo (2000; Krugman (2000; Aghion et al. (2000).

  3. Note that even in the Mundell-Fleming model, the type of shocks and capital controls can also reverse this oft-quoted result. See Ball (2010).

  4. See for example on liability dollarization Arteta (2005), Calvo et al. (2004), De Nicolo et al. (2003), Reinhart et al. (2003), Levy-Yeyati (2006), Eichengreen et al. (2005), Bleaney and Vargas (2009) and in particular, on its impact on growth Reinhart et al. (2003), Levy-Yeyati (2006) and Bleaney and Vargas (2009).

  5. See for example Eichengreen and Hausmann (1999).

  6. Yet, some authors find that exchange rate regimes do affect firms’ balance sheets. In particular, the adoption of a floating exchange rate regime leads to a higher degree of currency matching (and the opposite for the adoption of fixed regimes), as Galiani et al. (2003) show for the case of Argentina’s currency board and Kamil (2008) does for a panel of emerging countries. However, these studies are conducted on developing countries only. On our macro data set, for a given exchange rate regime, developing countries still exhibit higher liability dollarization than industrial ones, which is a symptom of imposed original sin.

  7. Existing explanations point at time inconsistency problems related to the temptation to “default” on local currency debt through inflation (Calvo and Guidotti 1989), the incidence of implicit debtor guarantees (Burnside et al. 2001) and signaling problems (De la Torre et al. 2003), among others. De Nicolo et al. (2003) provides evidence that the credibility of macroeconomic policy and the quality of institutions are both key determinants of cross-country variations in dollarization.

  8. The current account in the tradable sector is balanced because we have assumed that there is no intertemporal trading, that is no asset trade. This assumption simplifies the analysis but is not crucial. Qualitatively, the results would be unchanged if we introduced intertemporal trade in bonds. This is because, as long as there is imperfect risk sharing, a productivity shock leads households to alter their consumption, which is at the origin of the mechanisms of the model. Trade in bonds only limits the impact of productivity shocks on consumption by sharing their effect between current and future consumption; it does not suppress it. The difference with the model without trade in bonds is only quantitative and does not alter the comparison between regimes.

  9. The log-linearized version of the model as well as the proofs of Propositions 1 and 2 are available in the technical appendix at: https://docs.google.com/viewer?a=v&pid=explorer&chrome=true&srcid=0Bwb2sZ9M2da4YTcwNTE3MTMtMDM3OC00Y2RmLWI4MTEtNzMzNDc0ZWZmOTUw&hl=en.

  10. See the technical appendix for the definition of κ.

  11. In practice, Eq. 14 is differentiated and the second lag of the endogenous variable \(y_{t-2}^i\) is used as an instrument for \(\Delta y_{t-1}^i\), as well as further lags. Though our sample has only two available observations because of the scarcity of dollarization data, we can rely on lags of \(y_{t}^i\) beyond the limits of our data. To limit the number of instruments, I use only \(y_{t-2}^i\) and \(y_{t-3}^i\) to instrument \(\Delta y_{t-1}^i\). Since we assume that the other regressors are predetermined, we use their first and second lags as instruments. The system-GMM method consists in adding Eq. 14 in level as additional observations to limit the problem of weak instruments in presence of persistence. \(y_{t-1}^i\) is then instrumented with \(\Delta y_{t-1}^i\) and the other regressors in levels.

  12. This assumption has also been chosen for practical reasons. Because of data scarcity, it is impossible to use second order lags of original sin. It can be therefore considered at best as predetermined (the other variables, in particular the lagged explained variable, can still be instrumented thanks to the available higher lags).

  13. For further discussion of the endogeneity issues associated with exchange rate flexibility, see Aghion et al. (2009).

  14. Interestingly, when adding additional variables and controlling for endogeneity, the linear term becomes unsignificant, which does not contradict previous evidence in the literature.

References

  • Aghion P, Bacchetta P, Banerjee A (2000) A simple model of monetary policy and currency crises. Eur Econ Rev 44(4–6):728–738

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Angeletos G-M, Banerjee A, Manova K (2005) Volatility and growth: credit constraints and productivity-enhancing investment

  • Aghion P, Askenazy P, Berman N, Cette G, Eymard L (2007) Credit constraints and the cyclicality of r&d investment: evidence from france. Working Paper 2007-4, Weatherhead Center for International Affairs, Harvard University

  • Aghion P, Bacchetta P, Rancière R, Rogoff K (2009) Exchange rate volatility and productivity growth: the role of financial development. J Monet Econ 56:494–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bover O (1995) Another look at the instrumental-variable estimation of error components models. J Econom 68:29–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Q J Econ 120(1):173–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Arteta C (2005) Exchange rate regimes and financial dollarization: does flexibility reduce currency mismatches in bank intermediation? Topics Macroecon 5(1):1226–1226. Available at: http://www.bepress.com/bejm/topics/vol5/iss1/art10

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailliu J, Lafrance R, Perrault J-F (2003) Does exchange rate policy matter for growth? International Finance 6(3):381–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball L (2010) Policy responses to exchange-rate movements. Open Econ Rev 21(2):187–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i Martin X (1995) Economic growth. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Lee J-W (2000) International data on educational attainment: updates and implications

  • Baxter M, Stockman A (1989) Business cycles and the exchange rate regime: some international evidence. J Monet Econ 23(3):377–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Demirguc-Kunt A, Levine R (1999) A new database on financial developement and structure. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2146

  • Bleaney M, Vargas LC (2009) Real exchange rates, valuation effects and growth in emerging markets. Open Econ Rev 20:631–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (1998) Initial conditions and moment conditions in dynamic panel data models. J Econom 87:115–143

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (2000) Gmm estimation with persistent panel data: An application to production functions. Econom Rev 19:321–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bubula A, Otker-Robe I (2003) Are pegged and intermediate regimes more crisis prone? IMF Working Papers 03/223, International Monetary Fund

  • Burnside C, Eichenbaum M, Rebelo S (2001) Hedging and financial fragility in fixed exchange rate regimes. Eur Econ Rev 45(7):1151–1193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA, Reinhart CM (2002) Fear of floating. Q J Econ 117:379–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G, Guidotti P (1989) Credibility and nominal debt: exploring the role of maturity in managing inflation. IMF Working Paper No. 89/73

  • Calvo G (2000) Capital markets and the exchange rate with special reference to the dollarization debate in Latin America. http://www.bsos.umd.edu/econ/ciecrp9.pdf

  • Calvo G, Izquierdo A, Mejia L-F (2004) On the empirics of sudden stops: the relevance of balance-sheet effects

  • Cespedes LF, Chang R, Velasco A (2002) Balance sheets and exchange rate policy. Am Econ Rev 94(4):1183–1193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano L, Gust C, Roldos J (2004) Monetary policy in a financial crisis. J Econ Theory 119:64–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook D (2004) Monetary policy in emerging markets: can liability dollarization explain contractionary devaluations? J Monet Econ 51:1155–1181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook WG, Cook D (2002) Liability dollarization and the bank balance sheet channel. IMF Working Paper No WP/02/141

  • De la Torre A, Levy Yeyati E, Schmukler SL (2003) Living and dying with hard pegs: the rise and fall of Argentina’s currency board. Economia 3(2):43–99

    Google Scholar 

  • De Nicolo G, Honohan P, Ize A (2003) Dollarization of the banking system: good or bad? Policy Research Working Paper Series 3116, The World Bank

  • Devereux MB, Lane PR, Xu J (2006) Exchange rates and monetary policy in emerging market economies. Econ J 116(511):478–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubas JM, Lee B-J, Mark NC (2005) Effective exchange rate classifications and growth. NBER Working Paper No. 11272

  • Eichengreen B, Hausmann R, Panizza U (2005) The pain of original sin. In: Eichengreen B, Hausmann R (eds) Other people’s money: debt denomination and financial instability in emerging-market economies. University of Chicago Press

  • Eichengreen B, Hausmann R (1999) Exchange rates and financial fragility. NBER Working Paper No. 7418

  • Fischer S (2001) Exchange rate regimes: is the bipolar view correct? J Econ Perspect 15(2):3–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galiani S, Levy-Yeyati E, Schargrodsky E (2003) Financial dollarization and debt deflation under a currency board. Emerging Markets Review 4:340–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hau H (2002) Real exchange rate volatility and economic openness: theory and evidence. J Money Credit Bank 34(3):611–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Panizza U, Rigobon R (2006) The long-run volatility puzzle of the exchange rate. J Int Money Financ 25:93–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Panizza H (2003) On the determinants of original sin: an empirical investigation. J Int Money Financ 22(7):957–990

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausmann R, Panizza H, Stein E (2001) Why do countries float the way they float? J Dev Econ 2(66):387–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Husain AM, Mody A, Rogoff K (2005) Exchange rate regime durability and performance in developing versus advanced economies. J Monet Econ 52(1):35–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamil H (2009) How do exchange rate regimes affect firms’ incentives to hedge currency risk in emerging markets? http://www.eea-esem.com/files/papers/EEA-ESEM/2009/3215/Herman_Kamil_Barcelona_2009.pdf. Accessed 21 May 2011

  • Kaufmann D, Kraay A, Zoido-Lobaton P (1999) Aggregating governance indicators. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2195

  • Krugman P (2000) Analytical afterthoughts on the Asian crisis. In: http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/MINICRIS.htm

  • Lane PR, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2006) The external wealth of nations mark II: revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities for industrial and developing countries, 1970–2004. IMF Working Paper (69)

  • Levine R, Loayza N, Beck T (2000) Financial intermediation and growth: causality and causes. J Monet Econ 46(1):31–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy-Yeyati E, Sturzenegger F (2002) Classifying exchange rate regimes: deeds vs. words. Mimeo, Universidad Torcuato Di Tella available at www.utdt.edu/~fsturzen

  • Levy-Yeyati E, Sturzenegger F (2003) To float or to fix: evidence on the impact of exchange rate regimes on growth. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1173–1193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy-Yeyati E (2006) Financial dollarization: evaluating the consequences. Econ Policy 21:61–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenzo F, Aboal D, Osimani R (2005) The elasticity of substitution in demand for non-tradable goods in Uruguay. Inter-American Development Bank Research Network Working Paper No. R-480

  • Mehl A, Reynaud J (2005) The determinants of “domestic” original sin in emerging market economies. ECB Working Paper No. 560

  • Mendoza E (1997) Terms-of-trade uncertainty and economic growth. J Dev Econ 54(2):323–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG (2001) Credit, prices and crashes: business cycles with a sudden stop. NBER Working Paper No. 8338

  • Obstfeld M, Shambaugh JC, Taylor AM (2005) The trilemma in history: tradeoffs among exchange rates, monetary policies, and capital mobility. Rev Econ Stat 87(3):423–438

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Razin A, Rubinstein Y (2006) Evaluation of currency regimes: the unique role of sudden stops. Econ Policy 46:119–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS (2004) The modern history of exchange rate arrangements: a reinterpretation. Q J Econ 119(1):1–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart CM, Rogoff KS, Savastano M (2003). Addicted to dollars. NBER Working Paper No. 10015

  • Tavlas G, Dellas H, Stockman AC (2008) The classification and performance of alternative exchange-rate systems. Eur Econ Rev 52(6):941–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Windmeijer F (2004) A finite sample correction for the variance of linear two-step gmm estimator. J Econom 126(1):25–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support by CREST-INSEE is gratefully acknowledged. I would like to thank two referees, for many useful comments that helped improve the paper. Earlier versions of this paper also benefited from helpful comments from Agnès Bénassy-Quéré, Daniel Cohen, Guy Laroque, Philippe Martin, Valérie Mignon, Romain Rancière, Hélène Rey, seminar participants at CREST and EQUIPPE (Lille), the RIEF 2007 conference and 2008 doctoral meeting, the 2007 ESEM meeting, the 2008 T2M conference and the 2008 SMYE meeting.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kenza Benhima.

Appendices

Appendix A: Countries in Sample

Appendix B: Descriptive Statistics

Summary statistics 1995–2004 (data in five-year averages)

Variable

Observations

Mean

Std. Dev.

Min

Max

Productivity growth

134

0.02

0.02

−0.05

0.10

Initial productivity

134

26,413.24

18,668.75

2,172.53

70,091.68

Financial development

134

0.53

0.39

0.03

1.63

Education

134

83.79

28.43

14.00

158.76

Trade openness

134

81.38

46.03

18.11

322.35

Inflation

134

0.08

0.11

−0.02

0.78

Government burden

134

15.87

5.17

5.52

29.21

Kaufman governance index

134

3.19

4.83

−7.06

11.69

Net external debt

134

0.24

0.42

−2.15

1.88

 

REER vol.

90

0.06

0.04

0.01

0.19

LS index of ER flex.

129

2.40

1.18

1.00

4.00

Original sin

134

0.86

0.22

0.20

1.00

Sample correlations 1995–2004 (data in five-year averages)

 

Prod. growth

Initial prod.

Fin. dev.

Education

Trade open.

Inflation

Prod. growth

     

Initial prod.

0.13

    

Fin. dev.

0.19

0.61

   

Education

0.22

0.74

0.51

  

Trade open.

0.11

−0.05

0.00

0.01

 

Inflation

−0.44

−0.44

−0.48

−0.34

−0.01

Gov. burden

−0.09

0.50

0.20

0.62

0.06

−0.20

Gov. index

0.29

0.84

0.63

0.80

0.02

−0.48

Net ext. debt

−0.24

−0.39

−0.36

−0.22

−0.24

0.18

REER vol.

−0.51

−0.37

−0.31

−0.25

−0.07

0.59

LS index of ER flex.

−0.22

−0.18

−0.21

−0.06

−0.30

0.10

O. sin

−0.02

−0.68

−0.65

−0.50

0.24

0.35

Sample correlations 1995–2004 (data in five-year averages)

 

Gov. burden

Gov. index

Net external debt

REER vol.

LS index of ER flex.

Prod. growth

     

Initial prod.

     

Fin. dev.

     

Education

     

Trade open.

     

Inflation

     

Gov. burden

    

Gov. index

0.44

   

Net ext. debt

0.01

−0.31

  

REER vol.

−0.16

−0.42

0.11

 

LS index of ER flex.

−0.07

−0.16

0.09

0.26

O. sin

−0.23

−0.59

0.31

0.17

0.00

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Benhima, K. Exchange Rate Volatility and Productivity Growth: The Role of Liability Dollarization. Open Econ Rev 23, 501–529 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-011-9205-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-011-9205-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation