Skip to main content
Log in

The Effects of Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with a Fixed Exchange Rate

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the empirical effects of fiscal policy in Denmark since the adoption of a fixed exchange rate policy in 1982. Denmark’s fixed exchange rate implies that the nominal interest rate remains fixed after a fiscal expansion, facilitating a substantial impact of the fiscal stimulus on the real economy. On the other hand, the large degree of openness of the Danish economy means that a sizeable share of the fiscal stimulus will be directed towards imported goods. Our results suggest that the ‘monetary accomodation channel’ dominates the ‘leakage effect’ in the short run. We demonstrate that fiscal stimulus has a rather large impact on economic activity in the very short run, with a government spending multiplier of 1.1 on impact in our preferred specification. We also find that the effects of fiscal stimulus are rather short-lived in Denmark, with the effect on output becoming insignificant after around two years. The fiscal multiplier is above 1 only in the first quarter, and drops to 0.6 one year after the shock. We also find that in the short run, the government spending multiplier is larger than the tax multiplier. Finally, we demonstrate that exogenous shocks to government spending account for less than 10 % of the movements in output over the business cycle in Denmark.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We refer the reader to Coenen et al. (2012) or Hebous (2011) for extensive surveys on this literature.

  2. In addition, international capital mobility has increased during our sample due to financial liberalization. In accordance with the description of the effects of fiscal policy under a fixed exchange rate in the Mundell-Fleming model above, this also suggests an increase in the fiscal multiplier over time.

  3. The reason why the fiscal multiplier can be larger than 1 even though private consumption drops is that we find a rise in private investment on impact, after which it becomes insignificant

  4. This literature focuses on anticipation effects by assuming that agents react to fiscal policy shocks when they are announced, rather than when they are implemented.

  5. Importantly, the same critique does not apply to the automatic elasticity of government spending with respect to output.

  6. Indeed, Blanchard and Perotti (2002) also present evidence from a specification in which private consumption is included along with government spending, taxes, and output.

  7. Moreover, beginning in early 1983, an automatic indexation of wages and transfers to the rate of inflation was suspended. This is likely to have played an important role in bringing down the inflation rate.

  8. Recall that \(e_{t}^{f}=f_{t}\).

  9. Of course, when we set \(b_{3}=0\) so that \(g_{t}^{\prime }=g_{t}\), the use of \(g_{t}^{\prime }\) as an instrument in practice becomes redundant. On the other hand, when we set \(b_{3}\neq 0\), or in the specification with taxes instead of government spending, this step becomes relevant.

  10. It should be noted that the multiplier reported by Ilzetzki et al. (2013) is a cumulative multiplier, measuring the accumulated increase in output over a number of quarters. The impact multiplier is substantially smaller in their study.

  11. In particular, it may seem puzzling that the government spending multiplier is above 1 despite the drop in consumption. In results not reported, we find that this is explained by an increase in private investment on impact. The increase in investment is large on impact, after which it quickly reverts back around zero. In effect, the impulse response of investment mirrors that of private consumption.

  12. In results not reported, we observe that consumption rises on impact when b 3 is sufficiently low. In fact, we find that this explains the divergence between the negative consumption response in the present study and the positive response obtained by Bergman and Hutchison (2010), who setb 3 = −0.2.

  13. Note that the shock to tax revenues has been normalized to 1, so as to facilitate comparison with the shock to government spending. The response of tax revenues, however, is smaller than 1 already on impact, as the rise in taxes implies a drop in output, and hence in the tax base.

  14. The figure also suggests that fiscal policy was not tightened sufficiently in the years leading up to the recent crisis. As seen from Fig. 6 in the Appendix A that Denmark’s trading partners exerted a strong, positive impact on the Danish economy in 2006–07. Moreover, a recent study by Ravn (2012) suggests that, as a consequence of Denmark’s fixed exchange rate towards the euro, the Danish interest rate was substantially lower than what would have been prescribed by a Taylor rule for Denmark in the years 2005–2007. These factors would have called for an even tighter stance of fiscal policy during these years than what can be observed from Fig. 3.

  15. Our SVAR-model is of course much more rudimentary, and in particular does not feature shocks to the labor supply. In our setup, however, such shocks are likely to show up as fundamental shocks to Y t ; or perhaps to C t through the consumption/labor decision of households.

  16. See Hamilton (1994) or Altig et al. (2005).

References

  • Alesina A, Ardagna S (2010) Large changes in fiscal policy: taxes versus spending. Tax Policy Macroeconomy 24(1):35–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Altig D, Christiano L, Eichenbaum M, Lindé J (2005) Technical appendix to firm-specific capital, nominal rigidities and the business cycle. Technical appendices 09-191. Rev Econ Dyn

  • Andersen TM (1994) Disinflationary stabilization policy - Denmark in the 1980’s. In: Åkerholm J, Giovannini A (eds) Exchange rate policies in the nordic countries. CEPR, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach A, Gorodnichenko Y (2012) Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. Am Econ J Econ Pol 4(2):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beetsma R, Giuliodori M (2011) The effects of government purchases shocks review and estimates for the EU. Econ J 121(550):4–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergman M, Hutchison M (2010) Expansionary fiscal contractions: re-evaluating the danish case. Int Econ J 24(1):71–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bilbiie F, Meier A, Müller G (2008) What accounts for the changes in US fiscal policy transmission? J Money Credit Bank 40(7):1439–1469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Leigh D (2013) Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers. IMF Work Pap 13/1

  • Blanchard O, Perotti R (2002) An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Q J Econ 117(4):1329–1368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldara D, Kamps C (2012) The analytics of SVARs: a unified framework to measure fiscal multipliers. Finance and economics discussion series 2012-20, board of governors of the federal reserve system

  • Coenen Günter, Erceg C, Freedman C, Furceri D, Kumhof M, Lalonde R, Laxton D, Lindé J, Mourougane A, Muir D, Mursula S, de Resende C, Roberts J, Roeger W, Snudden S, Trabandt M, in’t Veld J (2012) Effects of fiscal stimulus in structural models. Am Econ J Macroecon 4(1):1–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Meier A, Müller G (2012) What determines government spending multipliers? Econ Policy 27(72):521–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dam NA (2008) Business cycles in Denmark and Europe. Dan J Econ 146(2):135–155

    Google Scholar 

  • Dam NA, Linaa JG (2005) What drives business cycles in a small open economy with a fixed exchange rate? EPRU working paper series, 05-02, Economic policy research unit, University of Copenhagen

  • Dickey D, Wayne F (1979) Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time series with a unit root. J Am Stat Assoc 74:427–431

    Google Scholar 

  • Duygan-Bump B, Grant C (2009) Household debt repayment behaviour: what role do institutions play? Econ Policy 24:107–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Favero C, Giavazzi F, Perego J (2011) Country heterogeneity and the international evidence on the effects of fiscal policy. IMF Econ Rev 59(4):652–682

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gali J, Vallés J, Lopez-Salido D (2007) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. J Eur Econ 5(1):227–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Giavazzi F, Pagano M (1990) Can severe fiscal contractions be expansionary? Tales of two small european countries. In: Blanchard O, Fischer S (eds) NBER macroeconomics annual. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Giorno C, Richardson P, Roseveare D, van den Noord P (1995) Estimating potential output, output gaps and structural budget balances. OECD economics department working papers, no. 152, OECD

  • Girouard N, André C (2005) Measuring cyclically-adjusted budet balances for OECD countries. OECD economics department working papers, no. 434, OECD

  • Hall P (1992) The bootstrap and edgeworth expansion. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton J (1994) Time series analysis. Princeton, Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Hebous S (2011) The effects of discretionary fiscal policy on macroeconomic aggregates: a reappraisal. J Econ Surv 25(4):674–707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ilzetzki E, Mendoza E, Vegh C (2013) How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? J Monet Econ 60(2):239–254

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jappelli T (2010) Economic literacy: an international comparison. Econ J 120(548):429–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwiatkowski D, Phillips P, Schmidt P, Shin Y (1992) Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root. How sure are we that economic time series have a unit root? J Econ 54:159–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lane P (2003) The cyclical behaviour of fiscal policy: evidence from the OECD. J Public Econ 87:2661–2675

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lindé J (2003) Monetary policy shocks and business cycle fluctuations in a small open economy: Sweden 1986–2002. Sveriges Riksbank working paper series, no. 153

  • Mertens K, Ravn M (2013) A reconciliation of SVAR and narrative estimates of tax multipliers. J Monet Econ, forthcoming

  • Monacelli T, Perotti R (2008) Openness and the sectoral effects of fiscal policy. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(2–3):395–403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monacelli T, Perotti R (2010) Fiscal policy, the real exchange rate, and traded goods. Econ J 120(544):437–461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura E, Steinsson J (2013) Fiscal stimulus in a monetary union: evidence from US regions. Am Econ Rev, forthcoming

  • Pedersen EH, Plagborg-Møller M (2010) New calculation of Danmarks Nationalbank’s effective krone-rate index. Dan Nationalbank Monet Rev 2:139–144

    Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R (2005) Estimating the effects of fiscal policy. In: Proceedings OECD countries, federal reserve bank of San Francisco

  • Ramey V (2011) Can government purchases stimulate the economy? J Econ Lit 49(3):673–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey V, Shapiro M (1998) Costly capital reallocation and the effects of government spending. Carnegie-Rochester Conf Ser on Public Policy 48(1):145–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravn M, Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (2012) Consumption, government spending, and the real exchange rate. J Monet Econ 59(3):215–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ravn SH (2012) Rules versus dictation: a Taylor rule for Denmark. Dan J Econ 150(1):22–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer C, Romer D (2010) The macroeconomic effects of tax changes: estimates based on a new measure of fiscal shocks. Am Econ Rev 100(3):763–801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang Z, Zhang W (2011) The road to recovery fiscal stimulus financial sector rehabilitation, and potential risks ahead. J Asian Econ 22(4):311–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Søren Hove Ravn.

Additional information

The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors, and do not necessarily correspond to those of Danmarks Nationalbank. The authors would like to thank Michael Bergman, Ester Faia, Francesco Furlanetto, Jesper Lind´e, Ivan Petrella, two anonymous referees, and colleagues at Danmarks Nationalbank for useful comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are our own.

Appendices

Appendix A: Additional Tables and Figures

Table 3 Unit root and stationarity tests
Table 4 Specificationtests for the VAR
Fig. 4
figure 4

The effects of a shock to government spending, specification with stochastic trend

Fig. 5
figure 5

The sensitivity of the estimated impact multiplier of government spending to the elasticity of government spending to output. The red dot indicates our baseline estimate of b 3 = 0

Fig. 6
figure 6

Historical decomposition. The blue line shows deviations in output growth relative to its trend growth. The red line shows the share explained by deviations in the growth rate of F t relative to its trend

Fig. 7
figure 7

Historical decomposition. The blue line shows deviations in output growth relative to its trend growth. The red line shows the share explained by deviations from trend in other domestic variables than government spending

Appendix B: Computing the Output Elasticity of Taxes

This appendix provides a detailed account of how we obtain an estimate of the elasticity of taxes to changes in output, as employed in Section 4.

We decompose the total tax revenue into four categories: Income taxes, corporate taxes, indirect taxes, and social contributions. We then obtain the elasticity of each of these types of taxes from a study by the OECD (Girouard and André 2005). Moreover, recall that we use a measure of taxes net of transfers. We therefore also need an estimate of the elasticity of transfers to changes in output. Finally, we weigh the elasticities together according to their average share of total net revenues during our sample period.

The tax elasticities estimated by Girouard and André (2005) for Denmark are the following: Income taxes; 1.0. Indirect taxes; 1.0. Corporate taxes; 1.6. Social contributions; 0.7. We refer the reader to that study for further details.

As for transfers, we follow Girouard and André and assume that unemployment benefits is the only type of transfers that contains a significant cyclical component. We therefore compute the sample average share of unemployment-related transfers to total transfers, and multiply this share by the elasticity of unemployment with respect to the output gap, which Girouard and André estimate to −7.9 for Denmark.

As noted in the main text, we arrive at an output elasticity of net tax revenues of 2.09.

Appendix C: Computing Variance Decompositions

To perform the variance decompositions, we rely on results from spectral analysis. Recall that any covariance-stationary time series can be represented equally well in the frequency domain as in the time domain (Hamilton 1994). In the frequency domain, the spectral density of the process is a measure of the share of the overall variance of the process accounted for at various frequencies. If the spectral density is high at low frequencies, much of the variation of the process can be interpreted as long-term movements in the data, perhaps reflecting an underlying trend.

For our VAR-model outlined in Section 2, the spectral density of X t at any frequency ω is given by:Footnote 16

$$ S_{X}\left( \omega \right) =\left[ I-A\left( e^{-i\omega }\right) \right]^{-1}CC^{\prime }\left[ I-A\left( e^{-i\omega }\right)^{\prime }\right]^{-1} $$
(11)

Here, A is the coefficient matrix from the VAR regression, and I is the identity matrix. C is the matrix linking the reduced-form residuals of the VAR-regression to the structural shocks of the model, with the property CC′ = V, as described in Subsection 2.2. i denotes complex i, so that i 2 = −1. Thus, the function assigns to any frequency ω a square matrix of complex numbers. However, as pointed out in Hamilton (1994), the complex part of the diagonal elements in this matrix will in fact be zero. The spectral density at frequency ω for each of the variables in Y t is given exactly by these (real and non-negative) diagonal elements of the matrix.

We want to compute the variance of each of the variables in X t that is accounted for by each of the shocks in ε t . Recall that in the expression for the spectral density, CC′ = V denotes the variance-covariance matrix when all the shocks are ‘turned on’. Following Altig et al. (2005), in order to compute the spectral density of X t when only the j’th shock (j = 1,..,4) is turned on, we can replace CC′ by \(CI_{j}C^{\prime }\), where I j is a square matrix of zeros, except for a unit entry in the j’th diagonal element. In other words,

$$ S_{X}^{j}\left( \omega \right) =\left[ I-A\left( e^{-i\omega }\right) \right]^{-1}CI_{j}C^{\prime }\left[ I-A\left( e^{-i\omega }\right)^{\prime }\right]^{-1} $$
(12)

denotes the spectral density of X t when only shock j is active.

As the spectral density for variable k is given by the k’th diagonal element of \(S_{X}\left ( \omega \right ) \), we can then compute the fraction of the variance of the k’th variable accounted for by the j’th shock at frequency ω as:

$$ var_{k,j}\left( \omega \right) =\frac{\left[ S_{X}^{j}\left( \omega \right) \right]_{kk}}{\left[ S_{X}\left( \omega \right) \right]_{kk}} $$
(13)

-where \(\left [ M\right ]_{kk}\) denotes element (k,k) of matrix M. Observe that by construction:

$$ \sum\limits_{j=1}^{4}var_{k,j}\left( \omega \right) =1 $$
(14)

Having decomposed the variance of any variable at any frequency, we can then sum the variance ratios over various frequency bands, for example the business cycle frequencies, and see how important each shock is for each variable within these frequency bands.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ravn, S.H., Spange, M. The Effects of Fiscal Policy in a Small Open Economy with a Fixed Exchange Rate. Open Econ Rev 25, 451–476 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-013-9288-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-013-9288-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation