Skip to main content
Log in

Patriotism, taxation and international mobility

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Patriotic citizens intrinsically prefer living in their native country compared to living in the Diaspora. In this paper, we analyze the consequences of such a “patriotic lock-in” in a world with international migration and redistributive taxation. One implication is that countries with more patriotic populations are associated with higher redistributive taxes. We then combine ISSP survey data with OECD taxation data and provide empirical evidence supporting this hypothesis. Our results provide a word of caution: the Treasury’s inherent interest in patriotic taxpayers may strengthen the political push for patriotism in an age of globalization and increased mobility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aidt, T. S., & Dallal, B. (2008). Female voting power: the contribution of women’s suffrage to the growth of social spending in western Europe (1869–1960). Public Choice, 134(3), 391–417.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G., & Kranton, R. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, B. (1991). Imagined communities: reflections on the origin and spread of nationalism. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson, F., & Konrad, K. A. (2003). Human capital investment and globalization in extortionary states. Journal of Public Economics, 87(7–8), 1539–1555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armingeon, K., Careja, R., Gerber, M., & Leimgruber, P. (2008). Codebook: comparative political data set III, 1990–2004. Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.

  • Atkinson, A. B. (2008). The changing distribution of earnings in OECD countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (2000). Redistributing income under proportional representation. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1235–1269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R. E., & Krugman, P. (2004). Agglomeration, integration and tax harmonisation. European Economic Review, 48(1), 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bank, S. A., Stark, K. J., & Thorndike, J. J. (2008). War and taxes. Washington: Urban Institute Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beine, M., Docquier, F., & Rapoport, H. (2008). Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: winners and losers. Economic Journal, 118, 631–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benabou, R., & Ok, E. A. (2001). Social mobility and the demand for redistribution: the POUM hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116, 447–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J. (1976). The brain drain. International Social Science Journal, 28(4), 691–729.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J., & Dellalfar, W. (1973). The brain drain and income taxation. World Development, 1(1–2), 94–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blank, T., & Schmidt, P. (2003). National identity in a united Germany: nationalism or patriotism? An empirical test with representative data. Political Psychology, 24(2), 289–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, P., & Roland, G. (1996). Distributional conflicts, factor mobility, and political integration. American Economic Review, 86(2), 99–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, F., & Ursprung, H. W. (1998). Are the rich too rich to be expropriated? Economic power and the feasibility of constitutional limits to redistribution. Public Choice, 94, 135–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coffé, H., & Geys, B. (2005). Institutional performance and social capital: an application to the local government level. Journal of Urban Affairs, 27(5), 485–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Figueiredo, R. J. P. Jr., & Elkins, Z. (2003). Are patriots bigots? An inquiry into the vices of in-group pride. American Journal of Political Science, 47(1), 171–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Docquier, F., & Marfouk, A. (2006). International migration by education attainment, 1990–2000. In C. Ozden & M. Schiff (Eds.), International migration, brain drain and remittance (pp. 151–199). New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorsch, M. (2010). Social mobility and the demand for public consumption expenditures. Public Choice, 142(1), 25–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Sturm, J.-E., & Ursprung, H. W. (2008). The impact of globalization on the composition of government expenditures: evidence from panel data. Public Choice, 134(3–4), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Druckman, D. (1994). Nationalism, patriotism and group loyalty: a social psychological perspective. Mershon International Studies Review, 38(1), 43–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Durand, E. D. (1917). Taxation versus bond issues for financing the war. Journal of Political Economy, 25(9), 888–916.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egeberg, M. (2004). An organizational approach to European integration: outline of a complementary perspective. European Journal of Political Research, 43(2), 199–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epple, D., & Romano, R. E. (1996). Ends against the middle: determining public service provision when there are private alternatives. Journal of Public Economics, 62(3), 297–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P. (2000). Tax competition and income redistribution: an empirical analysis for Switzerland. Public Choice, 105(1–2), 125–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fuest, C., Huber, B., & Mintz, J. (2005). Capital mobility and tax competition. Foundations and Trends in Microeconomics, 1(1), 1–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., & Konrad, K. A. (1994). Intertemporal commitment problems and voting on redistributive taxation. Journal of Urban Economics, 36, 278–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harbaugh, W. T., Mayr, U., & Burghart, D. R. (2007). Neural responses to taxation and voluntary giving reveal motives for charitable donations. Science, 316(5831), 1622–1625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macro-economic policy. American Political Science Review, 71, 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hohaus, B., Konrad, K. A., & Thum, M. (1994). Too much conformity—a hotelling model of local public goods supply. Economics Letters, 44(3), 295–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R. G. (1989). The median voter model in public choice theory. Public Choice, 61(2), 115–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooghe, L. (2005). Several roads lead to international norms, but few via international socialization: a case study of the European Commission. International Organization, 59(Fall), 861–898.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huddy, L., & Khatib, N. (2007). American patriotism, national identity, and political involvement. American Journal of Political Science, 51(1), 63–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2001). An asset theory of social political preferences. American Political Science Review, 95(4), 875–893.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2006). Electoral institutions and the politics of coalitions: why some democracies redistribute more than others. American Political Science Review, 100, 165–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, A. I. (2005). Conclusions and extensions: toward mid-range theorizing and beyond Europe. International Organization, 59(Fall), 1013–1044.

    Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M., & Thisse, J.-F. (1997). Implications of the mobility of skilled labor for local public funding of higher education. Economics Letters, 55, 409–412.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justman, M., & Thisse, J.-F. (2000). Local public funding of higher education when skilled labor is imperfectly mobile. International Tax and Public Finance, 7, 247–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser, H. F. (1958). The varimax criterion for analytic rotation in factor analysis. Psychometrica, 23(3), 187–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser, H. F. (1974). An index of factorial simplicity. Psychometrica, 39(1), 31–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaiser, H. F., & Rice, J. (1974). Little Jiffy: Mark IV. Educational and Psychological Measurement, 34, 111–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy, P. (2005). A guide to econometrics (5th edn.). Maldon/Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klor, E., & Shayo, M. (2010). Social identity and preferences over redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 94(3–4), 269–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna, A., & Slemrod, J. (2003). Behavioral public finance: tax design as price presentation. International Tax and Public Finance, 10(2), 189–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. A. (2008). Mobile tax base as a global common. International Tax and Public Finance, 15(4), 395–414.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. A., & Qari, S. (2009). The last refuge of a scoundrel? Patriotism and tax compliance. In CEPR Discussion Papers, No. 7215.

  • Levi, M. (1997). Consent, dissent, and patriotism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lizzeri, A., & Persico, N. (2001). The provision of public goods under alternative electoral incentives. American Economic Review, 91, 225–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R. (1990). An explanation for public provision of schooling: the importance of indoctrination. Journal of Law & Economics, 33(1), 199–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansoorian, A., & Myers, G. M. (1993). Attachment to home and efficient purchases of population in a fiscal externality economy. Journal of Public Economics, 52(1), 117–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maosen, L. (1990). Moral education in the People’s Republic of China. Journal of Moral Education, 19(3), 159–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. F. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 914–927.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitsui, K., & Sato, M. (2001). Ex ante free mobility, ex post immobility, and time consistency in a federal system. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 445–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moene, K. O., & Wallerstein, M. (2001). Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 2001, 859–874.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mummendey, A., Klink, A., & Brown, R. (2001). Nationalism and patriotism: national identification and out-group rejection. British Journal of Social Psychology, 40(2), 159–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OED (2003). Shorter Oxford English dictionary. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogura, L. M. (2006). A note on tax competition, attachment to home, and underprovision of public goods. Journal of Urban Economics, 59(2), 252–258.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pennings, P., Keman, H., & Kleinnijenhuis, J. (1999). Doing research in political science: an introduction to comparative methods and statistic. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T. (1995). Social mobility and redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 551–584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potrafke, N. (2009). Did globalization restrict partisan politics? An empirical evaluation of social expenditures in a panel of OECD countries. Public Choice, 140(1–2), 105–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prizel, I. (1998). National identity and foreign policy: nationalism and leadership in Poland, Russia and Ukraine. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Qari, S., Konrad, K. A., & Geys, B. (2009). Patriotism, taxation and international mobility. CEPR Discussion Papers, No. 7216.

  • Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Swagel, P. (2002). The aging population and the size of the welfare state. Journal of Political Economy, 110, 900–918.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1998). Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy, 106(5), 997–1032.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schatz, R. T., Staub, E., & Lavine, H. (1999). On the varieties of national attachment: blind versus constructive patriotism. Political Psychology, 20(1), 151–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seligman, E. R. A. (1892). The shifting and incidence of taxation. Publications of the American Economic Association, 7(2/3), 7–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shayo, M. (2009). A model of social identity with an application to political economy: nation, class and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 103(2), 147–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sinn, H.-W. (1995). A theory of the welfare state. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97, 495–526.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solt, F. (2008). Economic inequality and democratic political engagement. American Journal of Political Science, 52, 48–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sørensen, P. B. (2007). The theory of optimal taxation: what is the policy relevance? International Tax and Public Finance, 14(4), 383–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stamp, J. (1932). Taxation during the war. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. (1979). An integrative theory of intergroup conflict. In S. Worchel & W. Austin (Eds.), The social psychology of intergroup relations (pp. 33–47). Monterey: Brooks-Cole.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turner, J., Hogg, M., Oakes, P. J., Reicher, S. D., & Wetherell, M. (1987). Rediscovering the social group: a self-categorization theory. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weck-Hannemann, H. (2001). Globalization as a challenge for public choice theory. Public Choice, 106(1–2), 77–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin, D. E. (2000). Labor-market integration, investment in risky human capital, and fiscal competition. American Economic Review, 90, 73–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, J. D. (1999). Theories of tax competition. National Tax Journal, 52(2), 269–304.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2003). Cluster-sample methods in applied econometrics. American Economic Review, 93(2), 133–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zissimos, B., & Wooders, M. (2008). Public good differentiation and the intensity of tax competition. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1105–1121.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Salmai Qari.

Additional information

The authors are given in reverse alphabetical order, and contributed equally.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Qari, S., Konrad, K.A. & Geys, B. Patriotism, taxation and international mobility. Public Choice 151, 695–717 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9765-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9765-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation