Skip to main content
Log in

Religious decline in the 20th century West: testing alternative explanations

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Retrospective questions from recent surveys let us estimate rates of church attendance among children and their parents in ten Western democracies throughout most of the 20th century. We combine these time series with standard sources to test competing theories of religious change. Although our attendance estimates affirm the prevalence of religious decline, our statistical tests offer no support for traditional theories of secularization (which link decline to changes in income, education, industrialization, urbanization, and family life). Nor can we attribute much of the observed decline to growth in the welfare state. But increased school spending by governments does reduce church attendance, and this effect is not the result of greater educational attainment. In shaping the content of schooling, governments may strongly influence long-run religious trends.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. José Casanova (1994: 17) has noted that “secularization may be the only theory which was able to attain a truly paradigmatic status within the modern social sciences … shared by all the founding fathers: from Karl Marx to John Stuart Mill, from Auguste Comte to Herbert Spencer, from E.B. Tylor to James Frazer, from Ferdinand Toennies to Georg Simmel, from Émile Durkheim to Max Weber, from Wihelm Wundt to Sigmund Freud, from Lester Ward to William G. Summer, from Robert Park to George H. Mead.”

  2. Even the most ardent contemporary proponents of secularization distinguish their “modern” theories from those of their 19th century counterparts, especially with regard to the impact of science. See, for example, Bruce (2002: 2, 26, 106; and 2011: 43).

  3. Finke (1990) and Finke and Stark (1988, 1992) published their path-breaking work on religious economies and deregulation around the same time that Iannaccone (1988, 1990, 1991, 1992b) began writing about religious markets and rational choice as a “new paradigm” for religious research. Finke and Iannaccone’s (1993) “supply-side” account of American religious history and Warner’s (1993) much-cited analysis of the new paradigm literature strongly shaped the language of subsequent debate.

  4. See, for example, Bruce (2002: 1–44, 2011: 24–56), Casanova (1994: 11–39), and Norris and Inglehart (2004: 3–29), who also summarize the claims of their 19th century and mid-20th century predecessors.

  5. In the first paper to apply the “supply” versus “demand” distinction, Finke and Iannaccone (1993: 27–28) likewise argued that

    “the most significant changes in American religion … derive from changes in the incentives and opportunities facing religious producers, not some sudden shift in the material or psychological state of the populace. Of course, religious markets respond to the equilibrating forces of both supply and demand, but, as a matter of historical fact, religious demand proves much more stable than religious supply … because the underlying determinants of religious demand—people’s tastes, beliefs, socialization, and so forth—are rooted in fundamental human needs, whereas religious supply is strongly affected by government policy.”

  6. The emphasis on religion as a source of “existential security” is also quite closely related to “deprivation” theories of religion popular among sociologists in the 1950s through 1970s, which lost currency as more and more surveys found little or no evidence of reduced religiosity among individuals with greater income, more education, or better health (Stark and Bainbridge 1985).

  7. As Hout and Greeley (1987) explain, the situation is only slightly better in the United States, where Gallop polls provide spotty data on church attendance rates stretching back to the 1940s, but reliable repeated surveys with good religious and demographic items begin with the National Election Surveys of the 1960s and the General Social Surveys of the 1970s.

  8. See, for example, Iannaccone (1998), Gill and Lundsgaarde (2004), Norris and Inglehart (2004), Becker et al. (2013); and McCleary and Barro (2006a, 2006b).

  9. Questions of this form first appear in a 1963 National Opinion Research Center (NORC) study of American Catholics conducted by Greeley et al. (1976), and we owe to Andrew Greeley that they appear also in special years of the General Social Surveys and ISSP. But Greeley and others used the responses solely to capture the influence of personal background.

  10. For one last “sanity check” on the method, readers might consider their own ability to recall their religious identity and church attendance around age 11 or 12.

  11. During the twentieth century, these ten countries obtain a positive score on the democracy index in the Polity IV dataset (see Marshall and Jaggers 2009). Still, it must be noted that four countries in our sample, i.e., Denmark, France, the Netherlands and Norway, came under the occupation of Nazi Germany between 1940 and 1944 and were governed during those years by puppet regimes. However, none of these governments, and not even the Vichy regime in France which had extensive ties to parts of the French Catholic clergy, launched major campaigns to either encourage or discourage church attendance. Therefore, we consider that these four countries were democratic regimes throughout the twentieth century.

  12. Though in principle we might have tried including non-Western, less-developed, or non-Christian nations, the number of such nations in the ISSP was too small to warrant the necessary additional fixed effects (as for the one Jewish nation, Israel, or the one Latin American nation, Chile, or the non-Western, Shinto-Buddhist nation of Japan).

  13. Rollet (1958) likewise notes that the “social doctrine” of the 1891 papal encyclical De Rerum Novarum specifically encouraged Catholics to alleviate workers’ hardships in the new industrial era.

  14. Government spending on education is, in fact, negatively correlated with both Secondary Education (ρ=−0.20) and Post-Secondary Education (ρ=−0.080) over time—in part because educational attainment rose most rapidly in the early to mid 20th-century, whereas government expenditures on education rose most rapidly from the century’s middle to its end.

  15. These estimates are similar in magnitude to those computed by Gill and Lundsgaarde (2004). Their 1995 cross-section of 16 to 33 countries implied that a 1 % increase in the share of GDP devoted to welfare spending decreases church attendance by about 0.28 % to 0.63 %.

  16. Most nations set a single minimum school leaving age, but minimums varied somewhat across Canadian provinces, Swiss cantons and American states. For each of these countries, we used the average of their minimums.

  17. We made no attempt to create instruments for health, family, or old age spending because these variables had little impact on attendance. We also made no attempt to employ instruments for industrialization and urbanization because we could find no scholarly tradition claiming that decreased religiosity induced urbanization or industrialization.

  18. A weak instrument leads to underestimating the IV variance in small samples and thereby inflates significance estimates (Moreira 2003; Stock and Yogo 2005).

  19. Much as we would like to examine the different strands of Protestantism as other research highlights the importance of the ‘liberal-to-conservative’ denominational spectrum (Iannaccone 1998; Finke and Stark 1992), our samples are too small to offer any insight into Protestant denominational differences. In Denmark, Norway, and Sweden nearly all Protestants are members of the historically “established” church. And in Canada and the United States, where no one Protestant denomination predominates, the ISSP denominational samples are too small to be of use and, worse yet, the character of these denominations (such as Baptists) varies greatly across nations.

  20. We exclude from our subsampled attendance series any estimates from a five-year interval with fewer than 50 retrospective observations. Ireland thus supplies no estimates of Protestant attendance for any five-year interval, the Scandinavian countries provide no Catholic estimates, and other countries are missing estimates for various subgroups in the earliest or latest years of our sample.

  21. https://docs.google.com/file/d/0B23UuRyWxT3lR29pYTlOWTB6eEk/edit?usp=sharing.

  22. They often also mandated religious observance, as when King Louis XIV (1638–1715) threatened to jail Parisians who failed to attend Sunday mass (Bluche 1990) or the courts of Colonial Virginia required Anglicans to attend their parish church at least once per month, and failure could be punished by a fine of 5 shillings, 50 pounds of tobacco, or a whipping of ten lashes (http://score.rims.k12.ca.us/score_lessons/colonial_court/html/colonial.html).

  23. Governments can secularize schools in many ways, not merely in the adversarial manner of the French Republicans, who in 1881 made state-funded primary schooling “public, secular, and mandatory” in order to undermine the power of the Catholic Church (Franck and Johnson 2013), or in the “neutral” manner of the US Supreme Court, which declared mandatory school prayers and Bible reading unconstitutional in 1963, but even by providing explicit religious instruction after the manner of England and Germany, which may inadvertently undermine the authority of any particular tradition by portraying all traditions as equally true (Glenn 2004).

References

  • Azzi, C., & Ehrenberg, R. G. (1975). Household allocation of time and church attendance. Journal of Political Economy, 83(1), 27–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., & Woessman, L. (2009). Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of Protestant economic history. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(2), 531–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. O., Nagler, M., & Woessman, L. (2013). Education promoted secularization. Working paper.

  • Berman, E. (2000). Sect, subsidy, and sacrifice. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 905–953.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bluche, F. (1990). Louis XIV. Paris: Hachette. English translation by Mark Greengrass (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, S. (2002). God is dead. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruce, S. (2011). Secularization: in defence of an unfashionable theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunello, G., Fort, M., & Weber, G. (2009). Changes in compulsory schooling, education and the distribution of wages in Europe. The Economic Journal, 119(536), 516–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caron, N. (2007). Laïcité and secular attitudes in France. In B. Kosmin & A. K. Hartford (Eds.), Secularism & secularity: contemporary international perspectives. Hartford: Institute for the Study of Secularism in Society and Culture (pp. 113–124).

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, S. B., Gartner, S. S., Haines, M. R., Olmstead, A. L., Sutch, R., & Wright, G. (2006). Historical statistics of the United States: earliest times to the present—millennial edition. 5 vols. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casanova, J. (1994). Public religions in the modern world. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chiswick, C. U. (2008). Economics of American Judaism. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durkin, J. T. Jr., & Greeley, A. M. (1991). A model of religious choice under uncertainty: on responding rationally to the nonrational. Rationality and Society, 1991(3), 178–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, R. (1990). Religious deregulation: origins and consequences. Journal of Church and State, 32(3), 609–626.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, R., & Iannaccone, L. R. (1993). Supply-side explanations for religious change in America. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 527, 27–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, R., & Stark, R. (1988). Religious economies and sacred canopies: religious mobilization in American cities. American Sociological Review, 53(1), 41–49. 1906.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, R., & Stark, R. (1992). The churching of America, 1776–1990: winners and losers in our religious economy. Rutgers: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flora, P., & Alber, J. (1983). State, economy, and society in western Europe 1815–1975: a data handbook in two volumes (Vol. 1). Frankfurt: Campus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Franck, R. (2010). Economic growth and the separation of church and state: the French case. Economic Inquiry, 48(4), 841–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franck, R., & Johnson, N. D. (2013). Resilient religiosity: evidence from school choice in late 19th century France. Working Paper, Bar-Ilan University, Israel.

  • Gill, A. (2007). The political origins of religious liberty. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gill, A., & Lundsgaarde, E. (2004). State welfare spending and religiosity: a cross-national analysis. Rationality and Society, 16(4), 399–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glenn, C. L. (2004). Historical background to conflicts over religion in public schools. Pro Rege, 33(1), 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greeley, A. M., McCready, W. C., & McCourt, K. (1976). Catholic schools in a declining church. Kansas City: Sheed & Ward.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J., & Hungerman, D. M. (2007). Faith-based charity and crowd out during the great depression. Journal of Public Economics, 91(5–6), 1043–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J., & Hungerman, D. M. (2008). The church versus the mall: what happens when religion faces increased secular competition? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2), 831–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hout, M., & Greeley, A. M. (1987). The center doesn’t hold: church attendance in the United States, 1940–1984. American Sociological Review, 52(3), 325–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hungerman, D. M. (2005). Are church and state substitutes? Evidence from the 1996 welfare reform. Journal of Public Economics, 89(11), 2245–2267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hungerman, D. M. (2009). Crowd-out and diversity. Journal of Public Economics, 93(5–6), 729–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1984). Consumption capital and habit formation, with an application to religion. Ph.D. thesis, University of Chicago.

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1988). A formal model of church and sect. American Journal of Sociology, 94(Supplement), s241–s268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1990). Religious practice: a human capital approach. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 29(3), 297–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1991). The consequences of religious market regulation: Adam Smith and the economics of religion. Rationality and Society, 3(2), 156–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1992a). Sacrifice and stigma: reducing free-riding in cults, communes, and other collectives. Journal of Political Economy, 100(2), 271–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1992b). Religious markets and the economics of religion. Social Compass, 39(1), 123–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1995). Risk, rationality, and religious portfolios. Economic Inquiry, 33(2), 285–295.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (1998). Introduction to the economics of religion. Journal of Economic Literature, 36(3), 1465–1495.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R. (2003). Looking backward: a cross-national study of religious trends. George Mason University Working paper.

  • Iannaccone, L. R., & Berman, E. (2006). Religious extremism: the good, the bad, and the deadly. Public Choice, 128(1–2), 109–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iannaccone, L. R., Finke, R., & Stark, R. (1997). Deregulating religion: the economics of church and state. Economic Inquiry, 35(2), 350–364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R. (1990). An explanation for public provision of schooling: the importance of indoctrination. The Journal of Law & Economics, 33(2), 199–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R. (1999). Public schooling, indoctrination, and totalitarianism. Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), s127–s157. Part 2.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (2003). The world economy: historical statistics. Paris: Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2009). Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2007. Polity IV project, University of Maryland.

  • McCleary, R. M. (2011). In R. M. McCleary (Ed.). The Oxford handbook of the economics of religion. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006a). Religion and political economy in an international panel. Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion, 45(2), 149–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006b). Religion and economy. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 49–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. (2006). The bourgeois virtues: ethics for an age of commerce. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Miller, A. S., & Stark, R. (2002). Gender and religiousness: can socialization explanations be saved? The American Journal of Sociology, 107(6), 1399–1423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, B. R. (2007a). International historical statistics: the Americas, 1750–2005. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, B. R. (2007b). International historical statistics: Europe, 1750–2005. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moreira, M. J. (2003). A conditional likelihood test for structural models. Econometrica, 71(4), 1027–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murtin, F., & Viarengo, M. (2011). The expansion and convergence of compulsory schooling in western Europe, 1950–2000. Economica, 78(311), 501–522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norris, P., & Inglehart, R. (2004). Sacred and secular: religion and politics worldwide. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Oreopoulos, P. (2006). The compelling effects of compulsory schooling: evidence from Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(1), 32–52.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfaff, S. (2011). Religion under communism. In R. M. McClearly (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of the economics of religion (pp. 235–256). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richardson, G., & McBride, M. (2009). Religion, longevity, and cooperation: the case of the craft guild. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 71(2), 172–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rollet, H. (1958). L’action sociale des catholiques en France, 1871–1914. Paris: Desclée de Brouwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1981). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations (Vol. 2). Indianapolis: Liberty Classics. [1776].

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark, R., & Bainbridge, W. S. (1985). The future of religion: secularization, revival and cult formation. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark, R., & Finke, R. (2000). Acts of faith: explaining the human side of religion. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. H., & Yogo, M. (2005). Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. In J. H. Stock & D. W. K. Andrews (Eds.), Identification and inference for econometric models: essays in honor of Thomas J. Rothenberg (pp. 80–108). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Stolzenberg, R. M., Blair-Loy, M., & Waite, L. J. (1995). Religious participation over the life course: age and family life cycle effects on church membership. American Sociological Review, 60(1), 84–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warner, R. S. (1993). Work in progress toward a new paradigm for the sociological study of religion in the United States. American Journal of Sociology, 98(5), 1044–1093.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (2002). [1905]. The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. Los Angeles: Roxbury Publishing Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziliak, S. T., & Underhill Hannon, J. (2006). Public assistance: colonial times to the 1920s. In S. B. Carter, S. S. Gartner, M. R. Haines, A. L. Olmstead, R. Sutch, & G. Wright (Eds.), Historical statistics of the United States, earliest times to the present: millennial edition (pp. 2-693–2-700). New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Raphaël Franck gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Adar Foundation of the Economics Department at Bar Ilan University, and Laurence R. Iannaccone gratefully acknowledges financial support from the John Templeton Foundation and the Metanexus Institute. We also thank Leonid Azarnert, Samia Costa, Guillaume Daudin, Dror Goldberg, Jonathan Gruber, Daniel Hungerman, Miriam Krausz, Michael Makowsky, Rachel McCleary, Vai-Lam Mui, Jared Rubin, and Peter Temin as well as participants in seminars and conferences at the University of Haifa, Bar Ilan University, ASREC, and the NBER. Previous drafts of this article were circulated as “Why did Religiosity Decrease in the Western World during the Twentieth Century?”.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raphaël Franck.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 6, 7, 8.

Table 6 Minimum school leaving age, government spending on education and religiosity
Table 7 Determinants of church attendance rates for catholics: regressions with lagged dependent variables
Table 8 Determinants of church attendance rates for protestants: regressions with lagged dependent variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Franck, R., Iannaccone, L.R. Religious decline in the 20th century West: testing alternative explanations. Public Choice 159, 385–414 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0103-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0103-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation