Skip to main content
Log in

Ministerial gatekeeping and parliamentary involvement in the implementation process of EU directives

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

According to the literature on parliamentary government, legislatures provide political parties with veto and amendment rights, which counterbalance executive power. This institutional feature is also said to help overcome ministerial “drift” within coalition governments. While this literature has focused on the situation of an unconstrained environment of parliamentary government, the European Union’s Member States continuously delegate policy competencies to Brussels, whose directives must in turn be transposed into national law to take effect. Because the minister in charge enjoys informational advantages and has the sole right to begin the process of implementing directives, he can completely control the agenda in this constrained environment. We evaluate the empirical implications of a ministerial gatekeeping model by investigating the (in)activities of 15 countries with respect to 2,756 EU directives adopted between December 1978 and November 2009. Our findings show that partisan ministerial approval is necessary to start the implementation process which conditions the counterbalancing response of parliaments. Accordingly, the delegation of policy competencies to the European Union changes the power relationship in parliamentary governments and increases the risk of partisan ministerial drift.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Until the Lisbon Treaty came into force in December 2009, most EU legislation was adopted under the consultation procedure, while only the co-decision procedure provided the European Parliament with veto power over Commission proposals. Note that there are two types of Commission proposals for either secondary or tertiary legislation. Secondary legislation requires the approval of the Council under both procedures, while tertiary legislation demands a legal basis in secondary legislation and is adopted by the Commission alone (König et al., 2012: 24–25).

  2. See the literature on committee gatekeeping (Shepsle 1979; Denzau and Mackay 1983; McCubbins et al. 1987; Shepsle and Weingast 1987; Snyder 1992; Dion and Huber 1996; Epstein 1997; Cox 2001; Crombez et al. 2006; Calvo and Sagarzazu 2011) and (majority) party gatekeeping (Cox and McCubbins 1993, 2005; Aldrich, 1995; Cox and Poole, 2002; Lawrence et al., 2006; Gailmard and Jenkins, 2007).

  3. From January 1973 to December 1980, 70.69 %; from January 1981 to December 1985, 71.43 %; from January 1986 to December 1994, 71.05 %; from January 1995 to April 2004, 71.26 %; from May 2004 to October 2004, 70.97 %; from November 2004 to December 2006, 72.27 %; and since January 2007, 73.91 % (Moberg, 2002; Hosli and Machover, 2004; Holzinger et al., 2005: 107–111).

  4. In the U.S. federal system, the legitimacy of gatekeeping has been extensively discussed in the pre-Civil War decades. John C. Calhoun, one of the proponents of (Southern) states’ rights, developed the concept of concurrent majority and argued that “it is this negative power… be it called by what term it may—veto, interposition, nullification, check, or balance of power—which, in fact, forms the constitution” (Lence, 1992: 28, 371).

  5. See http://eurlex.europa.eu/LexUriServ/LexUriServ.do?uri=OJ:C:2012:287:0023:0023:EN:PDF.

  6. Brigitte Zypries not only voted in favor of the Data Retention Directive, but also insisted on more extensive data surveillance in the 2005 Council deliberations, which she attempted to implement immediately, but without success due to the intervention of the German Federal Constitutional Court (see http://www.bverfg.de/entscheidungen/rs20100302_1bvr025608.html).

  7. The core corresponds to the concept of a “centrality area” in a one-dimensional policy space, which Roozendaal et al. (2012: 453–454) use to determine the indispensable part of each (connected) winning coalition in the Council.

  8. The unanimity core is determined by the most left-wing and the most right-wing minister in the Council, whereas the QMV core is calculated as the intersection of all (connected) winning coalitions in the Council that reach the QMV threshold (see footnote 3).

  9. See the EUR-Lex service, available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/en/index.htm (last download: 3 January 2013). EUR-Lex sector 3 contains bibliographical notices and full texts of EU legislative acts, while EUR-Lex sector 7 provides information on national implementation measures of EU directives (König et al. 2006).

  10. Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Denmark, Ireland, the United Kingdom, Greece, Portugal, Spain, Austria, Finland, and Sweden.

  11. Note that we disregard directives with no notifications at all.

  12. We consider directives with deadlines prior to 30 June 2012. This introduces the possibility of a six-month notification delay.

  13. For minority governments, the parliamentary support party (Laver, 2006: 128; Franchino and Høyland, 2009: 612).

  14. Following Franchino and Høyland (2009: 612), we use party positions from expert surveys (Ray 1999; Benoit and Laver 2006; Steenbergen and Marks 2007) and calculate the mean value across the national implementation measures for each directive. To cope with missing data for Luxembourg, we use the data of the Comparative Manifestos Project (CMP; Budge et al., 2001; Klingemann et al., 2006), aggregated on the left-right dimension using a method proposed by Gabel and Huber (2000). For the coding of parliaments and cabinets, we collect information provided by Müller and Strøm (2000),Woldendorp et al. (2000), and the political data yearbooks published in the European Journal of Political Research.

  15. Parliamentary involvement is coded if at least one national implementation measure for a directive has been adopted legislatively (see Franchino and Høyland, 2009: 610).

  16. Following formula (1) or (2), we calculate the Council core using the positions of the parties of the ministers (with responsibility for the subjects under discussion) in all EU Member States at the adoption date t 0 (from the EU-9 to the EU-27). Although this procedure estimates the expected outcome of a directive based on all Member States participating in the adoption, our analysis considers only the implementation (in)activities of the EU-9 (before 1981), the EU-10 (from 1981 to 1985), the EU-12 (from 1986 to 1994), and the EU-15 Member States (since 1995), i.e., parliamentary systems in Western Europe.

  17. In the standard selection model of Heckman (1979), the second-stage estimation involves a continuous variable.

  18. In contrast to the probit model with sample selection, the second-stage estimation in the Heckman (1979) selection model makes it possible to include the inverse of Mill’s ratio for multi-level modeling.

References

  • Aldrich, J. H. (1995). Why parties? The origin and transformation of political parties in America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Angelova, M., Dannwolf, T., & König, T. (2012). How robust are compliance findings? A research synthesis. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(8), 1269–1291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beichelt, T. (2012). Recovering space lost? The German Bundestag’s new potential in European politics. German Politics, 21(2), 143–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K., & Laver, M. (2006). Party policy in modern democracies. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergman, T. (1997). National parliaments and EU affairs committees: notes on empirical variation and competing explanations. Journal of European Public Policy, 4(3), 373–387.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergman, T. (2000). The European Union as the next step of delegation and accountability. European Journal of Political Research, 37(3), 415–429.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D., & Newing, R. A. (1951). Committee decisions with complementary valuation. London: Hodge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boockmann, B. (2001). The ratification of ILO conventions: a hazard rate analysis. Economics and Politics, 13(3), 281–309.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brouard, S., Costa, O., & König, T. (Eds.) (2012). The Europeanization of domestic legislatures: the empirical implications of the Delors’ Myth in nine countries. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Budge, I., Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., & Tanenbaum, E. (2001). Mapping policy preferences: estimates for parties, electors, and governments 1945–1998. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, E., & Sagarzazu, I. (2011). Legislator success in committee: gatekeeping authority and the loss of majority control. American Journal of Political Science, 55(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clinton, J. D., Bertelli, A., Grose, C. R., Lewis, D. E., & Nixon, D. C. (2012). Separated powers in the United States: the ideology of agencies, presidents, and Congress. American Journal of Political Science, 56(2), 341–354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W. (2001). Agenda setting in the U.S. house: a majority-party monopoly? Legislative Studies Quarterly, 26(2), 185–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1993). Legislative leviathan. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (2005). Setting the agenda: responsible party government in the U.S .house of representatives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, G. W., & Poole, K. T. (2002). On measuring partisanship in roll-call voting: the U.S. house of representatives, 1877–1999. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 477–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez, C. (1996). Legislative procedures in the European Community. British Journal of Political Science, 26(2), 199–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez, C., Groseclose, T., & Krehbiel, K. (2006). Gatekeeping. The Journal of Politics, 68(2), 322–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crombez, C., & Hix, S. (2012). Legislative activity and gridlock in the European Union (FEB research report MSI 1226). Leuven: KU Leuven.

  • Dalal, D. K., & Zickar, M. J. (2012). Some common myths about centering predictor variables in moderated multiple regression and polynomial regression. Organizational Research Methods, 15(3), 339–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A. T., & Mackay, R. J. (1983). Gatekeeping and monopoly power of committees: an analysis of sincere and sophisticated behavior. American Journal of Political Science, 27(4), 740–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dion, D., & Huber, J. D. (1996). Procedural choice and the house committee on rules. The Journal of Politics, 58(1), 25–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Döring, H. (1995). Time as a scarce resource: government control of the agenda. In H. Döring (Ed.), Parliaments and majority rule in Western Europe (pp. 223–246). New York: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, G. W., Rocke, D. M., & Barsoom, P. N. (1996). Is the good news about compliance good news about cooperation? International Organization, 50(3), 379–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D. (1997). An informational rationale for committee gatekeeping power. Public Choice, 91(3/4), 271–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D., & O’Halloran, S. (1999). Delegating powers: a transaction cost politics approach to policy making under separate powers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, D., & Dannwolf, T. (2013). Domestic scrutiny of European Union politics: between whistle blowing and opposition control. European Journal of Political Research, 52(6), 715–746.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finke, D., König, T., Proksch, S.-O., & Tsebelis, G. (2012). Reforming the European Union: realizing the impossible. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Follesdal, A., & Hix, S. (2006). Why there is a democratic deficit in the EU: a response to Majone and Moravcsik. Journal of Common Market Studies, 44(3), 533–562.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Franchino, F. (2007). The powers of the union. Delegation in the EU. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Franchino, F., & Høyland, B. (2009). Legislative involvement in parliamentary systems: opportunities, conflict, and institutional constraints. American Political Science Review, 103(4), 607–621.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabel, M., & Hix, S. (2002). Defining the EU political space: an empirical study of the European elections manifestos, 1979–1999. Comparative Political Studies, 35(8), 934–964.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabel, M., & Huber, J. D. (2000). Putting parties in their place: inferring party left-right ideological positions from party manifestos data. American Journal of Political Science, 44(1), 94–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gailmard, S., & Jenkins, J. A. (2007). Negative agenda control in the senate and house: fingerprints of majority party power. The Journal of Politics, 69(3), 689–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Golub, J. (1999). In the shadow of the vote? Decision making in the European Community. International Organization, 53(4), 733–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, T. H., & Miller, G. J. (1987). The core of the constitution. American Political Science Review, 81(4), 1155–1174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (1979). Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica, 47(1), 153–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heller, W. B. (2001). Making policy stick: why the government gets what it wants in multiparty parliaments. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 780–798.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holzinger, K., Schimmelfennig, F., Rittberger, B., Knill, C., Peters, D., & Wagner, W. (2005). Die Europäische Union: Analysekonzepte und Theorien. Paderborn: Schöningh.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hosli, M. O., & Machover, M. (2004). The nice treaty and voting rules in the council: a reply to Moberg (2002). Journal of Common Market Studies, 42(3), 497–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. D. (1996). The vote of confidence in parliamentary democracies. American Political Science Review, 90(2), 269–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, J. D., & Shipan, C. R. (2002). Deliberate discretion? The institutional foundations of bureaucratic autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Klingemann, H.-D., Volkens, A., Bara, J., Budge, I., & McDonald, M. D. (2006). Mapping policy preferences II: estimates for parties, electors, and governments in Central and Eastern Europe, European Union and OECD 1990–2003. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kohler-Koch, B. & Rittberger, B. (Eds.) (2007). Debating the democratic legitimacy of the European Union. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • König, T. (2007). Discontinuity: another source of the EU’s democratic deficit? European Union Politics, 8(3), 411–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König, T., Dannwolf, T., & Luetgert, B. (2012). EU legislative activities and domestic politics. In S. Brouard, O. Costa, & T. König (Eds.), The Europeanization of domestic legislatures: the empirical implications of the Delors’ Myth in nine countries (pp. 21–37). New York: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • König, T., & Luetgert, B. (2009). Troubles with transposition? Explaining trends in member-state notification and the delayed transposition of EU directives. British Journal of Political Science, 39(1), 163–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König, T., Luetgert, B., & Dannwolf, T. (2006). Quantifying European legislative research. European Union Politics, 7(4), 553–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König, T., & Mäder, L. (2008). Cabinets and the transposition of EC directives. Paper presented at the 4th ECPR Pan-European conference on EU politics, Riga, Latvia, 25–27 September 2008.

  • König, T., & Mäder, L. (2013a). Non-conformable, partial and conformable transposition: a competing risk analysis of the transposition process of directives in the EU15. European Union Politics, 14(1), 46–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König, T., & Mäder, L. (2013b). The strategic nature of compliance: an empirical evaluation of law implementation in the central monitoring system of the European Union. American Journal of Political Science. First published online on 6 June 2013.

  • Kreppel, A., & Tsebelis, G. (1999). Coalition formation in the European parliament. Comparative Political Studies, 32(8), 933–966.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. (2006). Legislatures and parliaments in comparative context. In B. R. Weingast & D. Wittman (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of political economy (pp. 121–140). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. & Shepsle, K. A. (Eds.) (1994). Cabinet ministers and parliamentary government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., & Shepsle, K. A. (1996). Making and breaking governments: cabinets and legislatures in parliamentary democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, E. D., Maltzman, F., & Smith, S. S. (2006). Who wins? Party effects in legislative voting. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 31(1), 33–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lence, R. M. (Ed.) (1992). Union and liberty: the political philosophy of John C. Calhoun. Indianapolis: Liberty Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy: government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luetgert, B., & Dannwolf, T. (2009). Mixing methods: a nested analysis of EU member state transposition patterns. European Union Politics, 10(3), 307–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Majone, G. (1998). Europe’s ‘democratic deficit’: the question of standards. European Law Journal, 4(1), 5–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. W., & Vanberg, G. (2004). Policing the bargain: coalition government and parliamentary scrutiny. American Journal of Political Science, 48(1), 13–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. W., & Vanberg, G. (2005). Coalition policymaking and legislative review. American Political Science Review, 99(1), 93–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. W., & Vanberg, G. (2011). Parliaments and coalitions: the role of legislative institutions in multiparty governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mastenbroek, E. (2003). Surviving the deadline: the transposition of EU directives in the Netherlands. European Union Politics, 4(4), 371–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maurer, A., & Wessels, W. (2001). National parliaments on their ways to Europe: losers or latecomers? Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins, M. D., Noll, R. G., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). Administrative procedures as instruments of political control. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 3(2), 243–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moberg, A. (2002). The nice treaty and voting rules in the council. Journal of Common Market Studies, 40(2), 259–282.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (1993). Preferences and power in the European Community: a liberal intergovernmentalist approach. Journal of Common Market Studies, 31(4), 473–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (1998). The choice for Europe: social purpose and state power from Messina to Maastricht. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (2002). In defense of the ‘democratic deficit’: reassessing legitimacy in the European Union. Journal of Common Market Studies, 40(4), 603–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (2006). What can we learn from the collapse of the European constitutional project? Politische Vierteljahresschrift, 47(2), 219–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moravcsik, A. (2008). The myth of Europe’s ’democratic deficit’. Intereconomics: Review of European Economic Policy, 43(6), 331–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. (2005). Constitutional political economy in the European Union. Public Choice, 124(1–2), 57–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W. C. & Strøm, K. (Eds.) (2000). Coalition governments in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poguntke, T. (2008). Party government in the EU: on the road to presidentialization? (EUI Working Paper SPS No. 2008/10). Fiesole: European University Institute.

  • Poguntke, T., & Webb, P. (2005). The presidentialization of politics in democratic societies: a framework for analysis. In T. Poguntke & P. Webb (Eds.), The presidentialization of politics: a comparative study of modern democracies (pp. 1–25). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ray, L. (1999). Measuring party orientations towards European integration: results from an expert survey. European Journal of Political Research, 36(2), 283–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roozendaal, P. v., Hosli, M. O., & Heetman, C. (2012). Coalition formation on major policy dimensions: the Council of the European Union 1998 to 2004. Public Choice, 153(3–4), 447–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science, 23(1), 27–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A., & Weingast, B. R. (1984). Uncovered sets and sophisticated voting outcomes with implications for agenda institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 49–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K., & Weingast, B. R. (1987). The institutional foundations of committee power. American Political Science Review, 81(1), 85–104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slapin, J. B. (2011). Veto power: institutional design in the European Union. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, J. M. (1992). Committee power, structural-induced equilibria, and roll call votes. American Journal of Political Science, 36(1), 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steenbergen, M. R., & Marks, G. (2007). Evaluating expert judgments. European Journal of Political Research, 46(3), 347–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steunenberg, B., & Rhinard, M. (2010). The transposition of European law in EU member states: between process and politics. European Political Science Review, 2(3), 495–520.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tallberg, J. (2002). Paths to compliance: enforcement, management, and the European Union. International Organization, 56(3), 609–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson, R. (2010). Opposition through the back door in the transposition of EU directives. European Union Politics, 11(4), 577–596.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson, R., Stokman, F. N., Achen, C. H., & König, T. (Eds.) (2006). The European Union decides. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toshkov, D. (2010). Taking stock: a review of quantitative studies of transposition and implementation of EU law (Working paper No. 01/2010). Vienna: Institute for European Integration Research.

  • Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision making in political systems: veto players in presidentialism, parliamentarism, multicameralism and multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25(3), 289–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: how political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G., & Garrett, G. (2000). Legislative politics in the European Union. European Union Politics, 1(1), 9–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van de Ven, W. P. M. M., & van Praag, B. M. S. (1981). The demand for deductibles in private health insurance: a probit model with sample selection. Journal of Econometrics, 17(2), 229–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vaubel, R. (2013). International organizations. In M. Reksulak, L. Razzolini, & W. F. I. Shughart (Eds.), The Elgar campanion to public choice (pp. 451–468). Cheltenham: Elgar.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Webb, P., Poguntke, T., & Kolodny, R. (2012). The presidentialization of party leadership? Evaluating party leadership and party government in the democratic world. In L. Helms (Ed.), Comparative political leadership (pp. 77–98). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiler, J. H. H., Haltern, U. R., & Mayer, F. C. (1995). European democracy and its critique. West European Politics, 18(3), 4–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winzen, T. (2012). National parliamentary control of European Union affairs: a cross-national and longitudinal comparison. West European Politics, 35(3), 657–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woldendorp, J., Keman, H., & Budge, I. (2000). Party government in 48 democracies (1945–1998): composition, duration, personnel. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Earlier drafts of this article were presented at the 69th Annual National Conference of the Midwest Political Science Association in Chicago (31 March–3 April 2011), at the University of Essex in Colchester (13 March 2012), at the 2nd Annual General Conference of the European Political Science Association in Berlin (21–23 June 2012), and at the 6th Pan-European Conference on EU Politics at the University of Tampere in Finland (13–15 September 2012). We thank the participants for fruitful discussions. Furthermore, we gratefully acknowledge the valuable comments of three anonymous reviewers and the editor.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas König.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

König, T., Luig, B. Ministerial gatekeeping and parliamentary involvement in the implementation process of EU directives. Public Choice 160, 501–519 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0110-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0110-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation