Skip to main content
Log in

Intra-party politics and interest groups: missing links in explaining government effectiveness

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The article sheds light on two missing links in the existing literature on government’s policy preferences and policy choices, namely the roles played by party factions and trade unions as political actors able to affect government’s decision-making power. The content analysis of a wide typology of documents (i.e., investiture speeches, parliamentary debates, motions discussed during parties’ and trade unions’ congresses) allows to locate cabinets, parties, party factions and trade unions on a common pro-state/pro-market scale. Using these new data sources, we perform a multivariate time-series analysis to estimate the relative impact of those political actors on social expenditure in Italy throughout its modern history (1946–2015). The results support the idea that intra-party dynamics and trade unions’ preferences do matter. Indeed, government’s ability to retrench the welfare state vanishes when the Prime Minister’s party is highly polarized internally and when trade unions are more cohesive.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Recent work has pointed out that electoral costs are not distributed equally among coalescing parties (Hjermitslev 2018). Thus, we can hypothesize that party leaders are not bounded by internal factionalism to the same extent: those with stronger valence qualities and/or electoral support are likely to be less constrained by factions (see also Ceron 2012). Unfortunately, we cannot test this conditional effect with the data at hands. That opens avenues for further developments.

  2. In the Online Appendix, we also test whether trade unions’ policy positions affect a government’s ability to cut social expenditure. Table A9 adds a new variable, Trade Unions’ Position, which is equal to the mean of the CGIL’s and the CISL’s positions on the economic policy scale. The estimated coefficients on Trade Unions’ Position do not reach conventional levels of statistical significance. However, our two hypotheses are confirmed even when including the additional control.

  3. To test the robustness of our findings with respect to the dominant role played by the Democrazia Cristiana—Christian Democracy (DC) during the First Italian Republic, we run our model specification for intra-party factionalism on two separate subsamples: the first one restricted to the budgetary laws adopted by DC PMs; the other restricted to the ones adopted by PMs who were leaders of other parties. The results hold the same in both the subsamples, thus confirming that they are not biased by the DC’s dominant role. The estimates are available upon request.

  4. See the Online Appendix—Table A2 for the list of the categories included in the economic policy scale.

  5. The convergent validity of the policy scores from our dataset on investiture speeches also appears to be satisfactory. Please see the Online Appendix—Sect. 3.2 for the complete validation exercise.

  6. Figure A1 in the Online Appendix displays the positions of factions in the PM’s party over time. Point estimates demonstrate that left-wing factions adopt positions on the economic policy scale that are more pro-state (− 0.786; standard error 0.109) and statistically different from those supported by the other factions (− 0.305; standard error 0.060).

  7. We replicate the analysis by imputing the IPD of the major party supporting those three independent PMs. The results hold. Estimates are available upon request.

  8. We omitted the smaller Unione Italiana dei Lavoratori (Italian Union of Workers—UIL), founded in 1949 by republican and social democratic union members, which represents only approximately 10% of the unionized workforce, and lies (ideologically) between CGIL and CISL.

  9. Figure A2 in the Online Appendix displays the evolution of CGIL’s and CISL’s positions over time. The estimates suggest that the CGIL is slightly to the left of the CISL, although the difference is not statistically significant.

  10. To annualize the index of IGD, we follow the same procedure used for PMs’ speeches.

  11. Additional models are proposed and discussed in the Online Appendix—Sect. 2. They test the robustness of our findings to different specifications of the dependent variable, add socioeconomic and institutional control variables and change the temporal lag between the day on which a government takes office and the budgetary choices for which that government can be considered to be responsible. All our findings hold.

  12. We also assess whether high values of IPD prevent left-wing governments from increasing social expenditure (or reducing its retrenchment) by recoding governments’ positions so that higher numbers point to the pro-state pole of the economic scale. In line with H1, the results suggest that a PM willing to increase social expenditure is unable to do so when IPD reaches 0.1. Thus, no matter what the PM’s preferences may be, high levels of IPD generate a status-quo bias, as they imply more veto players. The estimates are available upon request.

  13. We compared the explanatory power of our new measure of trade unions’ ideological cohesion (TUD) to the one of more conventional measures, such as trade union density (OECD) and number/hours of strikes (ISTAT). If TUD is substituted with trade union density, or number/hours of strikes, its effects are not statistically significant, meaning that those variables do not capture the same phenomenon (estimates available upon request). On the other hand, when the more conventional measures are added to our model specifications, TUD retains its sign and statistical significance. The estimates reported in the Online Appendix—Table A4.

References

  • Alesina, A., & Drazen, A. (1991). Why are stabilizations delayed. American Economic Review, 81(5), 1170–1188.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allan, J. P., & Scruggs, L. (2004). Political partisanship and welfare state reform in advanced industrial societies. American Journal of Political Science, 48(3), 496–512.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allern, E. H., & Bale, T. (Eds.). (2017). Left-of-centre parties and trade unions in the twenty-first century. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armingeon, K., & Bonoli, G. (2006). The politics of post-industrial welfare states: Adapting post-war social policies to new social risks. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Avdagic, S. (2010). When are concerted reforms feasible? Explaining the emergence of social pacts in Western Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 43(5), 628–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baccaro, L., & Lim, S. (2007). Social pacts as coalitions of the weak and moderate: Ireland, Italy and South Korea in comparative perspective. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 13(1), 27–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baccaro, L., & Simoni, M. (2008). Policy concertation in Europe: Understanding government choice. Comparative Political Studies, 41(10), 1323–1348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bäck, H., & Debus, M. (2016). Political parties, parliaments and legislative speechmaking. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bäck, H., Müller, W. C., & Nyblade, B. (2017). Multiparty government and economic policy-making. Coalition agreements, prime ministerial power and spending in Western European Cabinets. Public Choice, 170(1–2), 33–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balassone, F., & Giordano, R. (2001). Budget deficits and coalition governments. Public Choice, 106(3–4), 327–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K., & Herzog, A. (2017). Text analysis: Estimating policy preferences from written and spoken words. In J. Bachner, K. Wagner Hill, & B. Ginsberg (Eds.), Analytics, policy and governance (pp. 137–159). Yale: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernauer, J., & Bräuninger, T. (2009). Intra-party preference heterogeneity and faction membership in the 15th German Bundestag: A computational text analysis of parliamentary speeches. German Politics, 18(3), 385–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bevan, S., & Greene, Z. (2015). Looking for the party? Partisan effects on issue attention in UK acts of parliament. European Political Science Review, 8(1), 49–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjedov, T., Lapointe, S., & Madiès, T. (2014). The impact of within-party and between-party ideological dispersion on fiscal outcomes: Evidence from Swiss cantonal parliaments. Public Choice, 161(1–2), 209–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blais, A., Blake, D., & Dion, S. (1993). Do parties make a difference? Parties and the size of government in liberal democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 37(1), 40–62.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boucek, F. (2012). Factional politics. How dominant parties implode or stabilize. London: Palgrave MacMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braüninger, T. (2005). A partisan model of government expenditure. Public Choice, 125(3), 409–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry, S., Giordano, C., & Zollino, F. (2011). A sectoral analysis of Italy’s development: 1861–2010. In Presented at the conference ‘Italy and the world economy, 1861–2011’, Rome, Banca d’Italia, 12–15 October 2011, economic history working papers no. 20.

  • Budge, I., Klingemann, H., Volkens, A., Bara, J., & Tanenbaum, E. (2001). Mapping policy preferences, estimates for parties, governments and electors 1945–1998. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Castater, E. G., & Han, K. J. (2016). Deal or no deal: Why do social pact proposals fail? West European Politics, 39(6), 1251–1275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceron, A. (2012). Bounded oligarchy: How and when factions constrain leaders in party position-taking. Electoral Studies, 31(4), 689–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceron, A. (2014). Gamson rule not for all. Patterns of portfolio allocation among Italian party factions. European Journal of Political Research, 53(1), 180–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceron, A. (2019). Leaders, factions and the game of intra-party politics. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ceron, A., & Negri, F. (2017). Trade unions and political parties in Italy (1946–2014): Ideological positions and critical junctures. South European Society and Politics, 22(4), 491–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceron, A., & Negri, F. (2018). March divided, fight united? Trade union cohesion and government appeal for concertation. West European Politics, 41(1), 218–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clayton, R., & Pontusson, J. (1998). Welfare-state retrenchment revisited: Entitlement cuts, public sector restructuring, and inegalitarian trends in advanced capitalist societies. World Politics, 51(1), 67–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, E., Tirelli, P., & Visser, J. (2014). Reinterpreting social pacts: Theory and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics, 42(2), 358–374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Compston, H. W. (2003). Beyond corporatism: A configurational theory of policy concertation. European Journal of Political Research, 42(6), 787–809.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culpepper, P. D. (2002). Powering, puzzling, and “pacting”. Journal of European Public Policy, 9(5), 774–790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culpepper, P. D., & Regan, A. (2014). Why don’t governments need trade unions anymore? The death of social pacts in Ireland and Italy. Socio-Economic Review, 12(4), 723–745.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cusack, T. R. (1997). Partisan politics and public finance: Changes in public spending in the industrialized democracies, 1955–1989. Public Choice, 91(3–4), 375–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, C. H. (2014). Parties and institutions: Empirical evidence on veto players and the growth of government. Public Choice, 159(3–4), 415–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Haan, J., Sturm, J. E., & Beekhuis, G. (1999). The weak government thesis: Some new evidence. Public Choice, 101(3–4), 163–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debus, M., & Bräuninger, T. (2009). Intra-party factions and coalition bargaining. In D. Giannetti & K. Benoit (Eds.), Intra-party politics and coalition government (pp. 121–145). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dolezal, M., Ennser-Jedenastik, L., Müller, W. C., et al. (2012). The life cycle of party manifestos: The Austrian case. West European Politics, 35(4), 869–895.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Döring, H., & Schwander, H. (2015). Revisiting the left cabinet share: How to measure the partisan profile of governments in welfare state research. Journal of European Social Policy, 25(2), 175–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elgie, R., & McMenamin, I. (2008). Political fragmentation, fiscal deficits and political institutionalisation. Public Choice, 136(3–4), 255–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti, D., & Benoit, K. (2009). Intra-party politics and coalition government. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giannetti, D., & Laver, M. (2009). Party cohesion, party discipline, party factions in Italy. In D. Giannetti & K. Benoit (Eds.), Intra-party politics and coalition government (pp. 146–168). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene, Z., & Haber, M. (2016). Leadership competition and disagreement at party national congresses. British Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 611–632.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamann, K., Johnston, A., Katsanidou, A., Kelly, J., & Pollock, P. (2015). Sharing the rewards, dividing the costs? The electoral consequences of social pacts and legislative reform in Western Europe. West European Politics, 38(1), 206–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamann, K., Johnston, A., & Kelly, J. (2013). Unions against governments: Explaining general strikes in Western Europe, 1980–2006. Comparative Political Studies, 46(9), 1030–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamann, K., & Kelly, J. (2007). Party politics and the reemergence of social pacts in Western Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 40(8), 971–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassel, A. (2009). Policies and politics in social pacts in Europe. European Journal of Industrial Relations, 15(1), 17–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Häusermann, S., Picot, G., & Geering, D. (2013). Review article: Rethinking party politics and the welfare state. Recent advances in the literature. British Journal of Political Science, 43(1), 221–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review, 71(4), 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hjermitslev, I. B. (2018). The electoral cost of coalition participation: Can anyone escape? Party Politics. https://doi.org/10.1177/1354068818794216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Höhmann, D. (2017). The effect of legislature size on public spending: Evidence from a regression discontinuity design. Public Choice, 173(3), 345–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbeau, L. M., Pétry, F., & Lamari, M. (2001). Left–right party ideology and government policies: A meta-analysis. European Journal of Political Research, 40(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R. O., & Nye, J. S. (1989). Power and interdependence. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Klüver, H., & Pickup, M. (2019). Are they listening? Public opinion, interest groups and government responsiveness. West European Politics, 42(1), 91–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • König, T. (2006). The scope for policy change after the 2005 election: Veto players and intra-party decision-making. German Politics, 15(4), 520–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kontopoulos, Y., & Perotti, R. (1999). Government fragmentation and fiscal policy outcomes: Evidence from OECD countries. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Fiscal institutions and fiscal performance (pp. 81–102). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korpi, W., & Palme, J. (2003). New politics and class politics in the context of austerity and globalization: Welfare state regress in 18 countries, 1975–95. American Political Science Review, 97(3), 425–446.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marlow, M. L., & Orzechowski, W. (1996). Public sector unions and public spending. Public Choice, 89(1–2), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martocchia Diodati, N., Marino, B., & Carlotti, B. (2018). Prime ministers unchained? Explaining prime minister policy autonomy in coalition governments. European Political Science Review. https://doi.org/10.1017/s1755773918000085.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattina, L., & Carrieri, M. (2017). Left-of-centre parties and trade unions in Italy: From party dominance to a dialogue of the deaf. In E. H. Allern & T. Bale (Eds.), Left-of-centre parties and trade unions in the twenty-first century (pp. 170–186). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • McDonald, M. D., & Budge, I. (2005). Elections, parties, democracy. Conferring the median mandate. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mershon, C. (1996). The costs of coalition: Coalition theories and Italian governments. American Political Science Review, 90(3), 534–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mershon, C. (2001). Contending models of portfolio allocation and office payoffs to party factions: Italy 1963–1979. American Journal of Political Science, 45(2), 277–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Molina, O., & Rhodes, M. (2002). Corporatism: The past, present, and future of a concept. Annual Review of Political Science, 5, 305–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W. C., & Strom, K. (2000). Coalition government in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Natali, D., & Pochet, P. (2009). The evolution of social pacts in the EMU era: What type of institutionalization? European Journal of Industrial Relations, 15(2), 147–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Negri F. (2016). Breaking down the chain of responsiveness. Doctoral Thesis. https://doi.org/10.13130/negri-fedra_phd2016-03-11. Accessed March 11, 2016.

  • Negri, F. (2017). Who affects government declarations and why: Contrasting the left–right scale with the welfare dimension. Government and Opposition. https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2017.29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nijhuis, D. O. (2009). Revisiting the role of labor: Worker solidarity, employer opposition, and the development of old-age pensions in the Netherlands and United Kingdom. World Politics, 61(2), 296–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oliver, R. J. (2011). Powerful remnants? The politics of egalitarian bargaining institutions in Italy and Sweden. Socio-Economic Review, 9(3), 533–566.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padovano, F., & Venturi, L. (2001). Wars of attrition in Italian government coalitions and fiscal performance: 1948–1994. Public Choice, 109(1–2), 15–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persico, N., Pueblita, J. C. R., & Silverman, D. (2011). Factions and political competition. Journal of Political Economy, 119(2), 242–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (1994). Dismantling the welfare state? Reagan, Thatcher and the politics of retrenchment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Powell, G. B. (2009). The ideological congruence controversy: The impact of alternative measures, data, and time periods on the effects of election rules. Comparative Political Studies, 42(12), 1475–1497.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Proksch, S., & Slapin, J. B. (2012). Institutional foundations of legislative speeches. American Journal of Political Science, 53(3), 520–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ragioneria Generale dello Stato. (2011). La spesa dello Stato dall’Unità d’Italia. Anni 1862–2009. http://www.rgs.mef.gov.it/_Documenti/VERSIONE-I/Pubblicazioni/Studi-e-do/La-spesa-dello-stato/La_spesa_dello_Stato_dall_unit_d_Italia.pdf. Accessed July 01, 2018.

  • Rose, R. (1984). Do parties make a difference? (2nd ed.). Chatham, NJ: Chatham House.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Roubini, N., & Sachs, J. D. (1989). Government spending and budget deficits in the industrial economies. NBER working paper number 2919.

  • Russo, F., & Verzichelli, L. (2016). Government ideology and party priorities: The determinants of public spending changes in Italy. Italian Political Science Review, 46(3), 269–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solé-Ollé, A. (2006). The effects of party competition on budget outcomes: Empirical evidence from local governments in Spain. Public Choice, 126(1–2), 145–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor-Gooby, P. (2002). The silver age of the welfare state: Perspectives on resilience. Journal of Social Policy, 31(4), 597–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press/Russell Sage.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Volkerink, B., & de Haan, J. (2001). Fragmented government effects on fiscal policy: New evidence. Public Choice, 109(3–4), 221–242.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warwick, P. V. (1992). Ideological diversity and government survival in Western European parliamentary democracies. Comparative Political Studies, 25(3), 332–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warwick, P. V. (2011). Voters, parties, and declared government policy. Comparative Political Studies, 44(12), 1675–1699.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. The Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zucchini, F. (2011). Government alternation and legislative agenda setting. European Journal of Political Research, 50(6), 749–774.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zuckerman, A. (1979). The politics of factions: Christian democratic rule in Italy. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to Fabio Franchino and Robert Franzese for their helpful comments and suggestions. An early version of this paper has been presented at the II International Conference on Public Policy (2015) in Milan, at the VI General Conference of the European Political Science Association (2016) in Brussels and at the General Conference of the Italian Political Science Association (2016) in Milan. We thank the discussants and the participants for their comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrea Ceron.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (DOCX 429 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ceron, A., Curini, L. & Negri, F. Intra-party politics and interest groups: missing links in explaining government effectiveness. Public Choice 180, 407–427 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00644-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00644-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation