Skip to main content
Log in

State fiscal constraint and local overrides: a regression discontinuity design estimation of the fiscal effects

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Despite abundant evidence regarding the influence of US state-imposed tax and expenditure limitations on local governments, the causes and consequences of local overrides remain largely unexplored. This article comprehensively examines the fiscal effects of local overrides of Massachusetts’s state-enforced property tax limit. Existing evidence has shown that pressure from powerful local interest groups, such as public schoolteachers and public employees, is crucial for determining agenda-setting and the successes or failures of measures overriding the statewide property tax limit. In that sense, fiscal constraints are able to curb bureaucrats’ budget-maximizing behaviors. Empirically, a regression discontinuity design estimation shows that local property tax limit overrides increase local property taxes and total revenues, decentralize the state–local fiscal relationship, and improve local budgetary balance. However, overrides do not affect local government spending.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Two ways of proposing overrides are possible. “Government officials can either propose a single override associated with a large override amount or split the override into multiple smaller ones, each of which is linked to a specific policy goal” (Wei and Butler 2020, p. 6). The latter is called the “menu” approach by Bradbury (1991).

  2. The property tax limit in municipality i and in year t can be computed as follows:

    $${\text{Levy~limit}}_{{{i},{t}}} = \left( {1 + 2.5{\% }} \right) \times {\text{Levy~limit}}_{{{i},{t} - 1}} + {\text{Values~of~new~growth}}_{{{i},{t}}} \times {\text{Tax~rate}}_{{{i},{t} - 1}} + {\text{Override~amounts}}_{{{i},{t}}}.$$
  3. The local appropriating body is “defined in towns as the board of selectmen, not town meeting. In towns without selectmen, a vote of the town council is required to present a referendum question to the electorate. In cities, a vote of the city council, with the mayor's approval where required by law, is needed.” (Refer to http://cltg.org/prop2_requirements-procedures.pdf for details).

  4. Proposition 2½ also allows voters to exclude a debt or capital outlay expenditure from the property tax levy limit. Unlike the property tax limit override, debt or capital outlay expenditure exclusions are temporary one-time solutions; they are not included in the base for calculating the property tax limit in future years.

  5. Multiple override attempts on the same ballot are recorded as separate overrides. Override attempts and successes are recorded by the year of the vote. Successful overrides begin in the following fiscal year.

  6. The data are accessible at https://www.mass.gov/municipal-databank-data-analytics-including-cherry-sheets.

  7. Although the figures in “Appendix 1” show evidence of jumps at the cutoff for mean and median household incomes the jumps are merely marginal in a statistical sense because the confidence interval on each side almost overlaps at the cutoff. To further alleviate concern about the potential endogeneity caused by household income, the sensitivity analysis in the empirical section checks the robustness of the findings by entering the pretreatment covariates, including mean and median household income, in the regressions. The results and conclusions remain the same.

  8. The results remain similar when choosing different polynomials for the override vote share (e.g.,\(g\) = 1, 3, or 4) in the RDD model. The sensitivity analyses in the empirical results section briefly discuss those results.

References

  • Adsera, A., Boix, C., & Payne, M. (2003). Are you being served? Political accountability and quality of government. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 19(2), 445–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alt, J. E., & Lassen, D. D. (2008). Political and judicial checks on corruption: Evidence from American state governments. Economics & Politics, 20(1), 33–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alt, J. E., & Lowry, R. C. (1994). Divided government, fiscal institutions, and budget deficits: Evidence from the states. American Political Science Review, 88(4), 811–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, N. B. (2006). Property tax limitations: An interpretative review. National Tax Journal, 59(3), 685–694.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bae, S., Moon, S. G., & Jung, C. (2012). Economic effects of state-level tax and expenditure limitations. Public Administration Review, 72(5), 649–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1973). The control of politicians: an economic model. Public Choice, 14(1), 19–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowler, S., & Donovan, T. (2004). Evolution in state governance structures: Unintended consequences of state tax and expenditure limitations. Political Research Quarterly, 57(2), 189–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowman, A. O. M. (2017). The state-local government (s) conundrum: Power and design. Journal of Politics, 79(4), 1119–1129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, K. L. (1991). Can local governments give citizens what they want? Referendum outcomes in Massachusetts. New England Economic Review, 3–22.

  • Brennan, G., & Buchanan, J. M. (1980). The power to tax: Analytic foundations of a fiscal constitution. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1971). Principles of urban fiscal strategy. Public Choice, 11(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cattaneo, M. D., Idrobo, N., and Titiunik, R. (2017). A Practical Introduction to Regression Discontinuity Designs. Working Manuscript accessible at http://www-personal.umich.edu/~titiunik/books/CattaneoIdroboTitiunik2017-Cambridge.pdf.

  • Cellini, S. R., Ferreira, F., & Rothstein, J. (2010). The value of school facility investments: Evidence from a dynamic regression discontinuity design. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(1), 215–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, E. C. (2008). Electoral incentives and budgetary spending: rethinking the role of political institutions. Journal of Politics, 70(4), 1086–1097.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (2004). The median voter model. In The encyclopedia of public choice (pp. 707–712). Springer, Boston, MA.

  • Courant, P. N., Gramlich, E. M., & Rubinfeld, D. L. (1980). Why voters support tax limitation amendments: The Michigan case. National Tax Journal, 33(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cutler, D. M., Elmendorf, D. W., & Zeckhauser, R. (1999). Restraining the Leviathan: property tax limitation in Massachusetts. Journal of Public Economics, 71(3), 313–334.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (2005). Who governs?: Democracy and power in an American city. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Denzau, A., Mackay, R., & Weaver, C. (1979). Spending limitations, agenda control and voters’ expectations. National Tax Journal, 32(2), 189–200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of political action in a democracy. Journal of Political Economy, 65(2), 135–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dronyk-Trosper, T. (2017). Getting what we vote for: A regression discontinuity test of ballot initiative outcomes. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 64, 46–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye, R. F., & McGuire, T. J. (1997). The effect of property tax limitation measures on local government fiscal behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 66(3), 469–487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eggers, A. C., Fowler, A., Hainmueller, J., Hall, A. B., & Snyder, J. M., Jr. (2015). On the validity of the regression discontinuity design for estimating electoral effects: New evidence from over 40,000 close races. American Journal of Political Science, 59(1), 259–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira, F., & Gyourko, J. (2009). Do political parties matter? Evidence from US cities. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124(1), 399–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folke, O., & Snyder, J. M. (2012). Gubernatorial midterm slumps. American Journal of Political Science, 56(4), 931–948.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, E. R., & Hopkins, D. J. (2011). When mayors matter: estimating the impact of mayoral partisanship on city policy. American Journal of Political Science, 55(2), 326–339.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber, J. (2010). Public finance and public policy. Worth Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn, J., Todd, P., & Van der Klaauw, W. (2001). Identification and estimation of treatment effects with a regression-discontinuity design. Econometrica, 69(1), 201–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hajnal, Z. L., & Trounstine, J. (2010). Who or what governs?: The effects of economics, politics, institutions, and needs on local spending. American Politics Research, 38(6), 1130–1163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, J. M. (1998). Individuals, institutions, and public preferences over public finance. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 513–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hong, K., & Zimmer, R. (2016). Does investing in school capital infrastructure improve student achievement? Economics of Education Review, 53, 143–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G. W., & Lemieux, T. (2008). Regression discontinuity designs: A guide to practice. Journal of Econometrics, 142(2), 615–635.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • James, C. O. X., & Lowery, D. (1990). The impact of the tax revolt era state fiscal caps. Social Science Quarterly, 71(3), 492.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joyce, P. G., & Mullins, D. R. (1991). The changing fiscal structure of the state and local public sector: The impact of tax and expenditure limitations. Public Administration Review, 51(3), 240–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klarner, C. E., Phillips, J. H., & Muckler, M. (2012). Overcoming fiscal gridlock: Institutions and budget bargaining. Journal of Politics, 74(4), 992–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kloha, P., Weissert, C. S., & Kleine, R. (2005). Developing and testing a composite model to predict local fiscal distress. Public Administration Review, 65(3), 313–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kousser, T., McCubbins, M. D., & Moule, E. (2008). For whom the TEL tolls: Can state tax and expenditure limits effectively reduce spending? State Politics & Policy Quarterly, 8(4), 331–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ladd, H. F., & Wilson, J. B. (1982). Why voters support tax limitations: evidence from Massachusetts’ Proposition 2–1/2. National Tax Journal, 35(2), 121–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ladd, H. F., & Wilson, J. B. (1983). Who supports tax limitations: Evidence from Massachusetts’ Proposition 2½. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 2(2), 256–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D. S. (2008). Randomized experiments from non-random selection in US House elections. Journal of Econometrics, 142(2), 675–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D. S., & Lemieux, T. (2010). Regression discontinuity designs in economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(2), 281–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D. S., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. J. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? Evidence from the US House. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 807–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, L. W., & Vanberg, G. (2013). Multiparty government, fiscal institutions, and public spending. Journal of Politics, 75(4), 953–967.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martorell, P., Stange, K., & McFarlin, I., Jr. (2016). Investing in schools: capital spending, facility conditions, and student achievement. Journal of Public Economics, 140, 13–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCrary, J. (2008). Manipulation of the running variable in the regression discontinuity design: A density test. Journal of Econometrics, 142(2), 698–714.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins, D. R., & Joyce, P. G. (1996). Tax and expenditure limitations and state and local fiscal structure: An empirical assessment. Public Budgeting & Finance, 16(1), 75–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins, D. R., & Wallin, B. A. (2004). Tax and expenditure limitations: Introduction and overview. Public Budgeting & Finance, 24(4), 2–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nguyen-Hoang, P. (2013). Tax limit repeal and school spending. National tax journal, 66(1), 117–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1968). The peculiar economics of bureaucracy. American Economic Review, 58(2), 293–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W. A. (1975). Bureaucrats and politicians. Journal of Law and Economics, 18(3), 617–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. M. (1994). State responses to fiscal crises: The effects of budgetary institutions and politics. Journal of Political Economy, 102(4), 799–821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poulson, B. W., & Kaplan, J. (1994). A rent-seeking model of TELs. Public Choice, 79(1–2), 117–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T., & Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice, 33(4), 27–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, S. (2010). Institutions and fiscal sustainability. National Tax Journal, 63(4), 807–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin, D. B. (1974). Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized and nonrandomized studies. Journal of Educational Psychology, 66(5), 688–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N. (2007). The mean voter theorem: necessary and sufficient conditions for convergent equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies, 74(3), 965–980.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadbegian, R. J. (1999). The effect of tax and expenditure limitations on the revenue structure of local government, 1962–87. National Tax Journal, 52(2), 221–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sharp, E. B. (2012). Does Local Government Matter?: How Urban Policies Shape Civic Engagement. University of Minnesota Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of Political Economy, 64(5), 416–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Hagen, J. (1991). A note on the empirical effectiveness of formal fiscal restraints. Journal of Public Economics, 44(2), 199–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallin, B. A. (2004). The tax revolt in Massachusetts: Revolution and reason. Public Budgeting & Finance, 24(4), 34–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wallin, B., & Zabel, J. (2011). Property tax limitations and local fiscal conditions: The impact of Proposition 2½ in Massachusetts. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 41(4), 382–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, X., Dennis, L., & Tu, Y. S. (2007). Measuring financial condition: A study of US states. Public Budgeting & Finance, 27(2), 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wei, W. (2020). Municipal structure matters: Evidence from government fiscal performance. Public Administration Review, online first, https://doi.org/10.1111/puar.13183

  • Wei, W., & Butler, J. S. (2020). State Fiscal Constraints and Local Responses: Evidence from the Property Tax Limit Overrides in Massachusetts. Public Administration Review, online first, https://doi.org/10.1111/puar.13186

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author thanks Dr. William F. Shughart II and the anonymous referees for their helpful comments and suggestions to revise the article and thanks Andrew Sullivan for his suggestions to edit the article’s language. This research is supported by the New Teacher Initiation Research Fund of Renmin University of China (project No.: 20XNF005).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wenchi Wei.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

See Fig. 4

Fig. 4
figure 4

Linear fits of pretreatment covariates. Note: Graphs show the linear fits of the socioeconomic, demographic, fiscal, and political pretreatment covariates on both sides of the cutoff. Data are collected from the Municipal Databank of Division of Local Services of the Massachusetts Department of Revenue

Appendix 2

See Fig. 5

Fig. 5
figure 5

Quadratic polynomial fits of pretreatment covariates. Note: Graphs show the quadratic polynomial fits of the socioeconomic, demographic, fiscal, and political pretreatment covariates on both sides of the cutoff. Data are collected from the Municipal Databank of Division of Local Services of the Massachusetts Department of Revenue

Appendix 3

See Table 5.

Table 5 Placebo test setting the fake cutoff at one-third of the vote share

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wei, W. State fiscal constraint and local overrides: a regression discontinuity design estimation of the fiscal effects. Public Choice 189, 347–373 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-021-00889-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-021-00889-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation