Skip to main content
Log in

The economic logic behind the ultimate resource

  • Published:
The Review of Austrian Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using economic reasoning, Julian Simon offered crucial insights into a range of pressing issues including the environment, immigration, and economic development. The main lesson from Simon’s scholarship is that the ultimate resource does not reside in the ground (natural resources), or even in the accumulated wisdom and knowledge in books and scientific journals (human capital), but in the imagination of people. Through their purposeful actions, people turn their thoughts and aspiration into a new reality that enables immense improvements in the human condition. In making this argument, Simon articulated the core ideas of Ludwig von Mises, F.A. Hayek, and Israel Kirzner regarding the discovery and use of knowledge in society, and the role of entrepreneurship as the prime mover of progress. This paper makes this intellectual connection clear.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As Thomas Sowell (1980: 383) notes, “Freedom is not simply the right of intellectuals to circulate their merchandise. It is, above all, the right of ordinary people to find elbow room for themselves and a refuge from the rampaging presumptions of their ‘betters’.”

  2. On differences between Acemoglu and Robinson and McCloskey on institutions and development, see McCloskey (2016, 2021). McCloskey takes issue with the “institutions and stir” approach to development which, in her view, neglects the importance of underlying ethics and ideas.

  3. This episode represented an important methodological insight to Simon. “The ruling paradigm in the University of Chicago’s Economics Department and School of Business,” he states in his autobiography A Life Against the Grain (2002: 177), “considered business people to be rational self-maximizers. It was clear to me that this was nonsense, based on my own experience in the advertising business. This idea came to a sharp point years later in an interchange with Milton Friedman about airline oversales. If I had indeed assumed that airline industry executives were rational self-maximizers, I could never have put forth the scheme that I did.”

  4. Simon’s views the controversial issues of birth control and abortion can be found in A Life Against the Grain (2002: 345-346) and can be summed up as a meta-choice about choosing. It is the individual and circumstances that guide the course of action, not a fixed rule that can never be violated.

  5. Simon did not seek the approval of the elite, in fact, he challenged the elite. Regarding Paul Samuelson’s judgment on the economic system, he states: “this just shows how great talent can swear to nonsense when the nonsense is framed in the ‘difficult art’ (Samuelson’s phrase) of mathematical economics” (1996: 79, fn). Simon preferred more common-sense reasoning grounded in empirical observation conducted in a variety of styles. In A Life Against the Grain (2002: 331) he sides with Kenneth Boulding that the reason to become an economists is not to seek approval from one’s scientific peers, as Samuelson had argued, but because “there was an intellectual task ahead, of desperate importance for the welfare and even the survival of mankind.”

  6. For an example of the allocation paradigm at work in the context of the economics of resource use, see Arrow et al. (2004).

  7. For an appraisal of Ehrlich’s subsequent counter bet, see Desrochers et al. (2021a, b).

  8. For recent empirical evidence on the causal impact of immigration on innovation and dynamism in the United States, see Burchardi et al. (2020).

  9. This is not to deny the intellectual discipline provided by allocation, maximization, equilibrium, and constraints. The issue is whether these factors are places in the analytical foreground or background (see Wagner 2010). The mainline tradition places these factors in the background while placing in the foreground the processes that enable people to move toward these outcomes.

  10. David Warsh (2006) provides an introduction to Romer’s work and its emergence out of the allocation, maximization, equilibrium, and the constraints given by nature conversation, but he misses the stream of mainline economics from Adam Smith to F. A. Hayek that was conducting this very conversation as well. His treatment also neglects how the economics of ideas could be productively married with the economic history work of Deirdre McCloskey (2007, 2011, 2017) and Joel Mokyr (2012) to explain the “Great Enrichment” and the “Enlightened Economy.”

  11. As Simon (2002) notes, “Concerning the label ‘conservative’: Along with Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman, I disavow the label ‘conservative’ … I am not in favor of any public attempts to conserve existing values or culture or ways life. Generally, I am against ‘controlling’ individuals and boundaries (such as borders). I do not worry about the loss of control by governments” (340-1).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2013). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2019). The narrow corridor: States, societies, and the fate of liberty. Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aligica, P. D., Boettke, P. J., & Tarko, V. (1999). Public governance and the classical-Liberal perspective: Political economy foundations. Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L., Daily, G., Ehrlich, P., Heal, G., Levin, S., Mäler, K.-G., Schneider, S., Starrett, D., & Walker, B. (2004). Are we Consumign too much? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 147–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (2012). Living economics: Yesterday, today, tomorrow. Independent Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J. (2018). Economics and public administration. Southern Economic Journal, 84(4), 938–959.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2003). Entrepreneurship and development. Advances in Austrian Economics, 6, 67–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Coyne, C. J. (2009). Context matters: Institutions and entrepreneurship. Foundations and Trends in Entrepreneurship, 5(3), 135–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., & Candela, R. (2017). The liberty of Progress. Social Philosophy and Policy, 34(2), 136–163.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boettke, P. J., Haeffele-Balch, S., & Storr, V. H. (2016). Mainline lectures: Six Nobel lectures in the tradition of Adam Smith. Mercatus Center at George Mason University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. (1964). What should economists do? Southern Economic Journal, 30(3), 213–222.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burchardi, K. B., T. Chaney, T.A. Hassan, L. Tarquinio, and S.J. Terry. 2020. “Immigration, Innovation, and Growth,” NBER Working Paper 27075. Available online: https://www.nber.org/papers/w27075

  • Desrochers, P., Geloso, V., & Szurmak, J. (2021a). Care to wager again? An appraisal of Paul Ehrlich’s Counterbet offer to Julian Simon, part 1: Outcomes. Social Science Quarterly, 102(2), 786–807.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desrochers, P., Geloso, V., & Szurmak, J. (2021b). Care to wager again? An appraisal of Paul Ehrlich’s Counterbet offer to Julian Simon, part 2: Critical analysis. Social Science Quarterly, 102(2), 808–829.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1960). The constitution of liberty. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. M. (2007). The bourgeois virtues: Ethics for an age of commerce. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. M. (2011). Bourgeois dignity: Why economics Can’t explain the modern world. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. M. (2016). Max U versus Humanomics: A critique of neo-institutionalism. Journal of Instituional Economics, 12(1), 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. M. (2017). Bourgeois equality: How ideas, not capital or institutions, enriched the world. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. M. (2021). Bettering Humanomics: A new, and old, approach to economic science. University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2012). The enlightened economy: An economy history of Britain 1700-1850. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (2018). “The Possibility of Progress,” Nobel Prize in Economics documents 2018-4, Nobel Prize Committee.

  • Ridley, M. (2020). How innovation works: And why it flourishes in freedom. Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, J. C. (1999). Seeing like a state: How certain schemes to improve the human condition have failed. Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1977). The economics of population growth. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1981). Environmental disruption or environmental improvement? Social Science Quarterly, 62(1), 30–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1986). Theory of population and economic growth. Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J.L. (1989a). The economic consequences of immigration. Basil Blackwell, Inc.

  • Simon, J. L. (1989b). Lebensraum: Paradoxically, population growth may eventually end wars. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 33(1), 164–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1989c). Robinson Crusoe was not mainly a Resoure allocator. Social Science Quarterly, 70(2), 471–478.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1990). Population matters: People, resources, environment, and immigration. Transactions Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1992). Population and development in poor countries. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (1996). The ultimate resource 2. Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, J. L. (2002). A life against the grain. Transactions Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776 [2000]). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. The Modern Library.

  • Sowell, T. (1980). Knowledge and decisions. Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R. (2010). Mind, society and human action. Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Warsh, D. (2006). Knowledge and the wealth of nations. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Yahya Alshamy, Peter Jacobsen, Deirdre McCloskey, and Louis Rouanet for useful comments and helpful suggestions on early versions of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Peter J. Boettke.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Boettke, P.J., Coyne, C.J. The economic logic behind the ultimate resource. Rev Austrian Econ 35, 303–314 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-022-00571-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11138-022-00571-2

Keywords

JEL codes

Navigation