Skip to main content
Log in

Overconfidence and Corporate Tax Policy

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using a sample of firms experiencing exogenous CEO departures, we investigate whether firms with overconfident CEOs avoid more tax. We find robust evidence of a positive relation between proxies for corporate tax avoidance and CEO overconfidence. Because our empirical tests use a panel of firm-years with exogenous CEO departures and include controls for stationary firm effects as well as observable firm characteristics, we can better isolate the role of an idiosyncratic personality trait (i.e., overconfidence) on corporate tax outcomes, thus adding to the literatures on overconfidence, managerial effects, and tax avoidance.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Rego and Wilson (2012) and Gallemore et al. (2014).

  2. Malmendier and Tate (2005) test the validity of their measure by comparing the returns from unexercised in-the-money stock options to hypothetical option exercises coupled with an investment in the S&P 500 index. They find that investment in the index produces higher returns more often than the unexercised option strategy. Specifically, investing the proceeds from exercised in the money options in the S&P 500 index would beat the strategy of holding exercisable in-the-money options 54.14% of the time.

  3. In sensitivity tests, we relax this assumption and find similar results (see Section 4.2).

  4. The tax avoidance measures in our study are consistent with prior literature and include the cash effective tax rate, estimated tax shelter probability (Wilson 2009; Rego and Wilson 2012), and residual book-tax differences not attributable to accruals management (Desai and Dharmpala 2006).

  5. See for example Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008); Hirshleifer et al. (2012); Schrand and Zechman (2012); Ahmed and Duellman (2013); and Ben-David et al. (2013).

  6. For example, if firm A experiences an endogenous turnover event in 1996 and an exogenous turnover event in 2001, then we delete observations for firm A prior to 1997.

  7. To reduce the impact of outliers, we winsorize all continuous variables at the 1st and 99th percentiles.

  8. The limited coverage of Execucomp, relative to Compustat, has a pronounced effect in reducing our sample from the 824 firms identified by Fee et al. (2013) to the 135 firms that are usable for our study.

  9. We obtain similar results for CASH ETR after subtracting special items (SPI) from pretax book income, dropping firms with negative pretax income, or both. We omit the year after turnover from our CASH ETR analysis to avoid commingling cash tax payments across CEO regimes. Turnover years are excluded from all analyses.

  10. In estimating TAX SHELTER SCORE, BTD is pretax book income (#PI) less estimated taxable income scaled by total assets (#AT), where estimated taxable income is (current federal tax expense, #TXFED, plus current foreign tax expense, #TXFO)/0.35, less the change in tax loss carryforwards, #TLCF. Leverage is total debt (#DLTT+#DLC) scaled by total assets (#AT). ROA is pretax book income (#PI) scaled by total assets (#AT). ForeignIncome is foreign pretax income (#PIFO) scaled by total assets (#AT); and 0 if #PIFO is missing. Finally, R&D is research and development expenses (#XRD) scaled by total assets (#AT); and 0 if #XRD is missing.

  11. See for example Malmendier and Tate (2005, 2008); Campbell et al. (2011); Hirshleifer et al. (2012); Schrand and Zechman (2012); Ahmed and Duellman (2013); Hribar and Yang (2016).

  12. Research suggests that our overconfidence measure is distinguishable from risk seeking (Malmendier and Tate 2005; Ben-David et al. 2013). Executives’ risk seeking would predict overinvestment in high-risk, high-return assets, but it would not predict overinvestment in one’s own firm. This is because the better-than-average effect combined with miscalibration would lead overconfident executives to underestimate the risk-return profile of their own firm to a greater extent than external investment opportunities. Hence, if overconfident managers were risk seekers, they would be more likely to overinvest in external assets, rather than in their own firm.

  13. Our results are robust to variations on our overconfidence measure as well as wholly different measures of overconfidence. See Sections 4.2 and 4.3.

  14. As Dyreng et al. (2010) point out, the use of firm fixed effects constrains our tests to only consider variation within the firm. Thus, if a firm always experiences lower tax rates than another firm because it operates in lower-taxed jurisdictions, this effect will be captured in its fixed effect.

  15. As evident in correlations reported in Table 4, consistent with prior research, LEVERAGE is negatively and significantly correlated with OVERCONFIDENCE, and R&D is positively and significantly correlated with OVERCONFIDENCE (Hirshleifer et al. 2012). However, none of the correlation coefficients is high enough to raise concerns regarding multicollinearity.

  16. Excluding loss firms, the mean CASH ETR is approximately 30%.

  17. Both time trends in tax avoidance and the somewhat coarse nature of our overconfidence measure could at least partially explain the increase in corporate tax avoidance we document when another overconfident CEO replaces an overconfident CEO.

  18. In an untabulated analysis, we examine the association between CEO overconfidence and the three-year standard deviation of cash ETR (Guenther et al. 2017). The results from these tests suggest that overconfident CEOs do not suffer from more volatile cash payments. We interpret these results with caution, because many of the turnovers in our sample do not have a long enough period afterward to draw meaningful conclusions, regarding whether tax avoidance initiated by an overconfident CEO will result in more volatile cash ETRs in the long run.

  19. In an untabulated analysis, we find a low (i.e. -0.06) correlation coefficient between raw CEO narcissism (NarcScore per Olsen and Stekelberg 2016) and CEO overconfidence. Since we lack narcissism data for over 25% of the sample, we code missing observations to 0 and include the MISSING_NARCISSISM variable to pick up the average effect of narcissism when it is missing.

  20. For example, consider executive Z who works for two different firms, FIRM1 and FIRM2. We code OVERCONFIDENCE as 1 for firms employing executive Z if she demonstrates overconfidence at any point in the sample. The key reason for this is that it allows OVERCONFIDENCE to only vary with executive Z coming in or out of the firm. If we coded OVERCONFIDENCE only after executive Z demonstrates overconfidence, we could have cases where OVERCONFIDENCE varies within executive Z’s tenure in the firm (i.e., no variation in OVERCONFIDENCE due to turnover). Consider the case where the executive exhibits overconfidence in the third year of her tenure with FIRM1. Waiting until the third year to code her as overconfident would create variation in OVERCONFIDENCE within FIRM1, despite no change in CEO (i.e., in the absence of an exogenous shock).

  21. Factor_5 captures the common variation in OVERCONFIDENCE, Net Purchase, OC_Firm5, Over-Invest_1, and Over-Invest_2.

  22. There are at least two reasons why forecast error is likely a noisier proxy for executive overconfidence than the options-based proxies. First, all executives, regardless of their confidence, face a substantial probability of missing a forecast. In contrast, there is not a strong reason to believe that less-confident executives would have a strong inclination to leave in-the-money options unexercised. Hence the forecast-based measure might be less discriminating than the options-based measure. Second, overconfident executives might be willing to engage in more aggressive accounting, operating decision, or both (Schrand and Zechman 2012) to avoid missing forecasts, which would manifest in a lower likelihood of missing a forecast. This propensity to take aggressive actions might counter the propensity to make more optimistic forecasts, also making the forecast-based measure less discriminating.

  23. While our paper relates to the work of Dyreng et al. (2010), we have different research questions, research designs, samples, and overconfidence proxies.

  24. Armstrong et al. (2012) and Rego and Wilson (2012) suggest that tax directors are more directly related to the tax function than CFOs. Nevertheless, Rego and Wilson (2012) assert that the role of the CFO in financial reporting and in overseeing the maximization of after-tax cash flows suggests they could be important in setting corporate tax policy. Chyz and Gaertner (2017) present evidence that both CEOs and CFOs appear to be held accountable for tax outcomes. Although at least partially driven by a lack of endogenous turnover data for CFOs, their findings are considerably weaker for CFOs.

  25. OC_CEO is equivalent to OVERCONFIDENCE from our primary analyses. We merely change the variable name to make it easier for readers to interpret CEO and CFO effects separately. OC_CFO is measured consistent with the approached used to measure OC_CEO.

References

  • Aboody, D., Hughes, J., Liu, J., & Su, W. (2008). Are executive stock option exercises driven by private information? Review of Accounting Studies, 13, 551–570.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahmed, A. S., & Duellman, S. (2013). Managerial overconfidence and accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting Research, 51, 1–30.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, C. S., Blouin, J. L., & Larcker, D. F. (2012). The incentives for tax planning. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, 391–411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bamber, L., Jiang, J., & Wang, I. (2010). What’s my style? The influence of top managers on voluntary corporate financial disclosure. The Accounting Review, 85, 1131–1162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with style: The effect of managers on firm policies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 1169–1208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David, I., Graham, J. R., & Harvey, C. R. (2013). Managerial miscalibration. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128, 1547–1584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. (2011). The spread of aggressive tax reporting: A detailed examination of the corporate-owned life insurance shelter. The Accounting Review, 86, 23–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, T. C., Gallmeyer, M., Johnson, S., Rutherford, J., & Stanley, B. (2011). CEO optimism and forced turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 101, 695–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen, S., Chen, X., Cheng, Q., & Shevlin, T. (2010). Are family firms more tax aggressive than non-family firms? Journal of Financial Economics, 95, 41–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chyz, J. A. (2013). Personally tax aggressive executives and corporate tax sheltering. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 56, 311–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chyz, J. A., & Gaertner, F. B. (2017). Can paying “too much” or “too little” tax contribute to forced CEO turnover? The Accounting Review, 93, 103–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chyz, J. A., Leung, W. S. C., Li, O. Z., & Rui, O. M. (2013). Labor unions and tax aggressiveness. Journal of Financial Economics, 108, 675–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Core, J., & Guay, W. (2002). Estimating the value of employee stock option portfolios and their sensitivities to price and volatility. Journal of Accounting Research, 40, 613–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechow, P., Sloan, R., & Sweeney, A. (1995). Detecting earnings management. The Accounting Review, 70, 193–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M. A., & Dharmapala, D. (2006). Corporate tax avoidance and high-powered incentives. Journal of Financial Economics, 79, 145–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Desai, M. A., & Dharmapala, D. (2009). Earnings management, corporate tax shelters, and book-tax alignment. National Tax Journal, 62, 169–186.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyreng, S., Hanlon, M., & Maydew, E. (2010). The effects of executives on corporate tax avoidance. The Accounting Review, 85, 1163–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dyreng, S., Hanlon, M., Maydew, E., & Thornock, J. (2017). Changes in corporate effective tax rates over the past twenty-five years. Journal of Financial Economics, 124, 441–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fee, C. E., Hadlock, C. J., & Pierce, J. R. (2013). Managers with and without style: Evidence using exogenous variation. Review of Financial Studies, 26, 567–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallemore, J., Maydew, E. L., & Thornock, J. (2014). The reputational costs of tax avoidance. Contemporary Accounting Research, 31, 1103–1133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graham, J., & Tucker, A. (2006). Tax shelters and corporate debt policy. Journal of Financial Economics, 81, 563–594.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guenther, D., Matsunaga, S., & Williams, B. (2017). Is tax avoidance related to firm risk? The Accounting Review, 92, 115–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, S., & Newberry, K. (1997). Determinants of the variability in corporate effective tax rates: Evidence from longitudinal data. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 16, 1–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B., & Murphy, K. (2002). Stock options for undivested executives. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 33, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hambrick, D. (2007). Upper echelons theory: An update. Academy of Management Review, 32, 334–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hambrick, D., & Mason, P. (1984). Upper echelons: The organization as a reflection of its top managers. The Academy of Management Review, 9, 193–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanlon, M., & Slemrod, J. (2009). What does tax aggressiveness signal? Evidence from stock price reactions to news about tax shelter involvement. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 126–141.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, D., Low, A., & Teoh, S. H. (2012). Are Overconfident CEOs Better Innovators? Journal of Finance, 67, 1457–1498.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hribar, P., & Yang, H. (2016). CEO Overconfidence and Management Forecasting. Contemporary Accounting Research, 33, 204–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, T., Wang, Z., & Demirkan, S. (2018). Overconfidence and tax avoidance: The role of CEO and CFO interaction. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 37, 241–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khan, M., & Watts, R. L. (2009). Estimation and empirical properties of a firm-year measure of accounting conservatism. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 48, 132–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, I., & Skinner, D. (2012). Measuring securities litigation risk. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, 290–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koester, A., Shevlin, T., & Wangerin, D. (2016). The role of managerial ability in corporate tax avoidance. Management Science forthcoming.

  • Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. Journal of Finance, 60, 2661–2700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2008). Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market’s reaction. Journal of Financial Economics, 89, 20–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malmendier, U., Tate, G., & Yan, J. O. N. (2011). Overconfidence and early-life experiences: The effect of managerial traits on corporate financial policies. Journal of Finance, 66, 1687–1733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olsen, K. J., & Stekelberg, J. (2016). CEO narcissism and corporate tax sheltering. Journal of American Taxation Association, 38, 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plesko, G. (2004). Corporate tax avoidance and the properties of corporate earnings. National Tax Journal, 57, 729–737.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rego, S. O., & Wilson, R. (2012). Equity risk incentives and corporate tax aggressiveness. Journal of Accounting Research, 50, 775–810.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson, J. R., Sikes, S. A., & Weaver, C. D. (2010). Performance measurement of corporate tax departments. The Accounting Review, 85, 1035–1064.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schrand, C. M., & Zechman, S. L. C. (2012). Executive overconfidence and the slippery slope to financial misreporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53, 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, R. (2009). An examination of corporate tax shelter participants. The Accounting Review, 84, 969–999.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yin, F. (2003). How much tax do large public corporations pay? Estimating the effective tax rates of the S&P 500. Virginia Law Review, 89, 1793–1845.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Edward Fee, Charles Hadlock, and Joshua Pierce for allowing us to use their exogenous CEO departure data. We are thankful for helpful comments from two anonymous reviewers, Brad Blaylock, Scott Dyreng, Paul Fischer (editor), Sandy Klasa, April Klein, Alok Kumar, Clive Lennox, Ed Maydew, Brian Mayhew, Lil Mills, Mark Peecher, Leslie Robinson, Terry Shevlin, Richard Taffler, members of the University of Connecticut Tax Reading Group, members of the University of Texas Tax Reading Group, workshop participants at the University of Kentucky, and attendees at the 2014 NTA Annual Meeting, 2014 Accounting Conference at Temple University, and 2014 Behavioral Finance Working Group Conference (University of London). A prior version of this paper benefited from useful comments from Dan Givoly, Michelle Hanlon, Rick Laux, and Karl Muller. We are thankful for the financial support from the University of Tennessee (Chyz); University of Wisconsin-Madison (Gaertner); American University (Kausar); Luciano Prida Sr. Term Professorship, Fisher School of Accounting, and Warrington College of Business (Watson).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Luke Watson.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Variable definitions

Appendix: Variable definitions

Variable

Description

Construction

CASH ETR

Cash effective tax rate

TXPD/PI

TAX SHELTER SCORE

Estimated tax shelter probability

Following Wilson (2009), \( \frac{1}{1+{e}^{-\left(\alpha +\beta X\right)}} \), where

α + βX = −4.30 + 6.63*BTD – 1.72*Leverage

+ 2.26*ROA + 1.62*ForeignIncome + 1.56*R&D

BTD_DD

Residual book-tax differences

Following Desai and Dharmapala (2006), the residual from:

BTDi,t = β1TAi,t + μi + εi,t

OVERCONFIDENCE

Executive overconfidence

(OPT_UNEX_EXER_EST_VAL / OPT_UNEX_EXER_NUM) / (PRCC_F – (OPT_UNEX_EXER_EST_VAL / OPT_UNEX_EXER_NUM))

CASH FLOW

Cash return on assets

(OANCF+TXPD)/AT

LEVERAGE

Leverage

(DLC + DLTT)/AT

NOL

Net operating loss carryforward indicator

Indicator variable equal to 1 if TLCF >0, and 0 otherwise

ΔNOL

Change in net operating loss carryforwards

(TLCFt - TLCFt-1) / ATt

FOREIGN INCOME

Foreign return on assets

PIFO/AT

PP&E

Property, plant, and equipment

PPENT/AT

INTANGIBLES

Intangible assets

INTAN/AT

EQUITY INCOME

Equity income in earnings

ESUB/AT

SIZE

Firm size

Natural log of AT

MARKET-TO-BOOK RATIO

Market-to-book ratio

(PRCC_F*CSHO)/CEQ

R&D

Research and development expense

XRD/AT

DISC_ACC

Performance-adjusted discretionary accruals

Following Dechow et al. (1995), the residual from:

TAit = α0 + α1 /ASSETSit-1 + α2ΔSALESit

+ α3PPEit + α4ROAit + εit

COMP_OPTION

Ratio of stock option grant value to total compensation

OPTION_AWARDS_BLK_VALUE/TDC1

DELTA

Sensitivity of executive wealth to stock price changes

Delta per Core and Guay (2002)

VEGA

Sensitivity of executive wealth to changes in stock price volatility

Vega per Core and Guay (2002)

VESTED

Percentage of options vested

OPT_UNEX_EXER_NUM/CSHO

TENURE

Executive tenure

Number of years CEO has been in CEO position in a given firm

Additional Control Variables Used in Robustness Checks:

ABILITY

Managerial ability

MASCORE per Koester et al. (2016)

NARCISSISM

CEO narcissism

NarcScore per Olsen and Stekelberg (2016)

MISSING_NARCISSISM

Missing CEO narcissism indicator

Indicator variable equal to 1 when NARCISSISM is missing, and 0 otherwise

STOCK_OWN

Percentage of stock owned by CEO

SHROWN_EXCL_OPTS/CSHO

HELD_PCT

Institutional ownership

Outstanding shares held by 13f institutions from Thomson Financial / CSHO

INVEST

Capital expenditures

CAPX/AT

LITSCORE

Litigation risk

Litigation risk per Kim and Skinner (2012) using industry, size, growth, and return volatility

CSCORE

Accounting conservatism

C_Score per Khan and Watts (2009)

ANNRET

Stock returns

Contemporaneous compounded annual stock returns from CRSP

P_TAX_AGG

CEO’s personal tax aggressiveness

SUSPECT_EXEC per Chyz (2013)

EXER_HOLD

Exercise-and-hold indicator

Executives that have ever engaged in an “exercise-and-hold” stock option transaction per Chyz (2013)

Alternative measures of Overconfidence:

Net Purchase

Overconfidence based on CEO stock purchase activity

Purchase per Ahmed and Duellman (2013)

OC_Firm5

Overconfidence based on five firm-level factors

OC_FIRM5 per Schrand and Zechman (2012)

Over-Invest_1

Overconfidence based on overinvestment

XSINVEST_INDADJ per Schrand and Zechman (2012)

Over-Invest_2

Overconfidence based on overinvestment

ACQUIRE_INDADJ per Schrand and Zechman (2012)

Factor_5

Overconfidence based on factor analysis of five factors

Single factor created from factor analysis capturing the common variation in OVERCONFIDENCE, Net Purchase, OC_Firm5, Over-Invest_1, and Over-Invest_2

Overconfidence_2

Alternate measure of overconfidence

Same as OVERCONFIDENCE except that Overconfidence_2 is set to 1 only for years after the first observance of overconfident behavior

Press

Press-based measure of overconfidence

A measure based on news articles in Factiva that report a CEO as being confident or less confident. Press takes on a value of 1 if the number of confident references exceed non-confident references; zero otherwise

Miss

Overconfidence based on forecast error

OVERCONFIDENCE IN FORECASTS per Dyreng et al. (2010)

  1. All variables are measured annually at t

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chyz, J.A., Gaertner, F.B., Kausar, A. et al. Overconfidence and Corporate Tax Policy. Rev Account Stud 24, 1114–1145 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-019-09494-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-019-09494-z

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation