Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Incentives in optimally sized teams for projects with uncertain returns

  • Published:
Review of Accounting Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes a principal-agent model with three risk-averse players to investigate incentive provision and optimal team size in a setting with uncertain productivity and team synergies. A principal hires a team of workers and a manager to supervise the team. Workers provide productive effort, whereas the manager exerts effort to reduce measurement noise and productivity risk. We find that moral hazard is a limiting factor for team size and that the risk from uncertain productivity leads to smaller optimal teams, which stands in contrast to previous literature. Furthermore, we show that the manager’s and workers’ compensation increases with team size and that the pay differential between them is higher for larger teams. Our analysis demonstrates that the interdependency between team size and incentive provision makes it essential to coordinate the choice of these design variables.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Chandrasekaran and Linderman (2015) observe a negative correlation between team size and project complexity, which can be interpreted as a proxy for the uncertain productivity of a project. Dailey (1978) and van de Ven et al. (1976) show a negative correlation between task uncertainty and team size.

  2. For an overview with a particular focus on accounting applications, see Lambert (2001).

  3. Liang et al. (2008) cannot derive a first-best solution. Due to their model construction, the optimal team size in a first-best setting would tend toward infinity.

  4. Vectors are in boldface, and T denotes the transpose of a column vector.

  5. Liang et al. (2008) capture the trade-off for larger teams as a positive linear effect on output and an increase in performance measure risk as a negative component.

  6. Of course, similar examples can be found in other industries. In the IT industry, the success of software development is uncertain. In banking, the ongoing process of digital transformation has an uncertain outcome.

  7. For simplicity, we abstract from the assumption of Liang et al. (2008) that measurement noise increases with team size. However, incorporating such an assumption would not change the results qualitatively.

  8. The variance σx can be approximated by a binomial distribution for large N, that is, σx = Nq ⋅ (1 − q), where N is the number of customers and q is the probability with which customers will buy the firm’s product. Reducing σx through a market research effort s would imply increasing the probability q of each potential customer buying the product and reducing the number of potential customers N as preferences are more clearly identified and some customer groups drop out.

  9. Henceforth, we omit the index i in the parameters for the workers.

  10. Installation of a monitoring system, analysis of market prospects, and development of a project are independent tasks such that none of them requires another task to be finished first. We therefore assume that the workers’ and manager’s efforts are exerted simultaneously.

  11. To reduce the complexity of the model, we disregard the time value of money.

  12. We present a variation of the model with a risk-neutral principal in Section 5.

  13. The results presented in the following also hold for different risk-aversion coefficients for the manager and the workers. We have used the simplified assumption of identical risk-aversion to make our model comparable to Liang et al. (2008).

  14. Liang et al. (2008) assume a risk-neutral principal. Consequently, they do not establish a first-best solution to their model because team size would be optimally set to infinity if efforts were observable.

  15. In the model of Liang et al. (2008), the manager only exerts effort m, and the manager’s effort cost is C(m) = km. We assume k = 1 and add the second effort (market research). The tasks are independent, so we neglect potential spillovers in the effort cost functions.

  16. See Appendix A for a presentation of the principal’s optimization program.

  17. All proofs can be found in Appendix A.

  18. Setting λ = 0 results in the standard solution of a risk-neutral principal with \(\beta _{x}^{*}=0\), where the entire accounting income risk is borne by the principal and the manager is paid solely a fixed salary. See also Section 5.

  19. In the first-best solution (see the proof of Lemma 1 in Appendix A), the workers’ and manager’s effort choices are interdependent, because they are connected in the principal’s certainty equivalent. In the second-best scenario, this is no longer the case, since the effort choices are determined based on the individual certainty equivalents of the workers and the manager. The manager anticipates the workers’ optimal effort choice, since their productive efforts determine the level of risk exposure from the uncertain productivity. The market research effort s is then chosen strategically, considering the workers’ optimal productive effort choice.

  20. Note that indeed \(\beta _{y}^{\dagger }=\frac {\sqrt {n}\sqrt {r+n \lambda }}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}\cdot b^{\dagger }\).

  21. We will elaborate on this issue in Proposition 4.

  22. This result comports with the result in Proposition 4 of Liang et al. (2008).

  23. Another difference in their model is the assumption of a risk-neutral principal. However, the positive impact of risk on team size also holds for a risk-averse principal. See Appendix A for a proof of this statement.

  24. The results are robust to different parameter values and relations among them as well as for different functional forms for the synergy effect and the organizational costs.

  25. See Proposition 5 in Liang et al. (2008).

  26. Note that the manager’s total compensation in the second-best setting needs to be paid for also performing effort m, which was not necessary in the first-best setting. Therefore the change in the manager’s total compensation is only very small from first to second best.

  27. The results are also robust to variations in the relations of the underlying parameter values.

  28. For the ease of notation, we omit the optimality index ‡ in the following derivation of the proof.

  29. In the work of Liang et al. (2008), \(\beta ^{*}=\sqrt {\frac {n}{2}}\cdot b^{*}\), which corresponds to our result if we assume a risk-neutral principal, that is, λ = 0.

  30. The notation is the same as for Fu et al. (2016), with λ as the principal’s risk aversion.

  31. The numbering of equations refers to Fu et al. (2016)

References

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baiman, S., Larcker, D. F., Rajan, M. V. (1995). Organizational design for business units. Journal of Accounting Research, 33(2), 205–229.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, G., Gibbs, M., Holmstrom, B. (1993). Hierarchies and compensation: A case study. European Economic Review, 37(2-3), 366–378.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldenius, T., Melumad, N. D., Ziv, A. (2002). Monitoring in multiagent organizations. Contemporary Accounting Research, 19(4), 483–511.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P., & Besanko, D. (2001). Strategy, organization and incentives: Global corporate banking at Citibank. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(1), 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharyya, S., & Lafontaine, F. (1995). Double-sided moral hazard and the nature of share contracts. RAND Journal of Economics, 26(4), 761–781.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bose, A., Pal, D., Sappington, D.E. M. (2011). On the performance of linear contracts. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 20(1), 159–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breunig, K. J., Aas, T. H., Hydle, K.M. (2014). Incentives and performance measures for open innovation practices. Measuring Business Excellence, 18(1), 45–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brooks, F. P. (1975). The mythical man-month: Essays on software engineering. Reading: Addison Wesley Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cawsey, T. F., Deszca, G., Ingols, C. (2015). Organizational change: An action-oriented toolkit. Los Angeles: SAGE Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandrasekaran, A., & Linderman, K. (2015). Managing knowledge creation in high-tech R&D projects: A multimethod study. Decision Sciences, 46(2), 267–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dailey, R. C. (1978). The role of team and task characteristics in R&D team collaborative problem solving and productivity. Management Science, 24(15), 1579–1588.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutta, S., & Fan, Q. (2012). Incentives for innovation and centralized versus delegated capital budgeting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 53(3), 592–611.

    Google Scholar 

  • Faccio, M., Marchica, M. -T., Mura, R. (2011). Large shareholder diversification and corporate risk-taking. Review of Financial Studies, 24(11), 3601–3641.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fu, R., Subramanian, A., Venkateswaran, A. (2016). Project characteristics, incentives, and team production. Management Science, 62(3), 785–801.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garden, A. -M. (1990). Career orientations of software developers in a sample of high tech companies. R&D Management, 20(4), 337–352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garnier, J. -P. (2008). Rebuilding the R&D engine in big pharma. Harvard Business Review, 86(5), 68–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbs, M. (1995). Incentive compensation in a corporate hierarchy. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 19(2-3), 247–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grant, R. M. (2005). Organizational restructuring within the Royal Dutch/Shell Group. In Grant, R. M. (Ed.) Cases to accompany contemporary strategy analysis (pp. 117–142). Malden: Blackwell.

  • Green, C., Heywood, J. S., Theodropoulos, N. (2017). Employer size and supervisor earnings: Evidence from Britain. GLO Discussion Paper 136.

  • Hall, R. E., & Woodward, S. E. (2010). The burden of the nondiversifiable risk of entrepreneurship. American Economic Review, 100(3), 1163–1194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, B. H., Nickerson, J. A., Owan, H. (2003). Team incentives and worker heterogeneity: An empirical analysis of the impact of teams on productivity and participation. Journal of Political Economy, 111(3), 465–497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (2002). Organization design. Management Science, 48(7), 852–865.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hemmer, T. (1998). Performance measurement system, incentives, and the optimal allocation of responsibilities. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 25(3), 321–347.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertel, G. (2011). Synergetic effects in working teams. Journal of Managerial Psychology, 26(3), 176–184.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 324–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B., & Milgrom, P. (1987). Aggregation and linearity in the provision of intertemporal incentives. Econometrica, 55(2), 303–328.

    Google Scholar 

  • Indjejikian, R., & Nanda, D. (1999). Dynamic incentives and responsibility accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 27(2), 177–201.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kandel, E., & Lazear, E. P. (1992). Peer pressure and partnerships. Journal of Political Economy, 100(4), 801–817.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, S., & Henderson, R. (2005). Inertia and incentives: Bridging organizational economics and organizational theory. Organization Science, 16(5), 509–521.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kothari, S. P., Laguerre, T. E., Leone, A. J. (2002). Capitalization versus expensing. Review of Accounting Studies, 7(4), 355–382.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lambert, R. A. (2001). Contracting theory and accounting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 32(1), 3–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lerner, J., & Wulf, J. (2007). Innovation and incentives: Evidence from corporate R&D. Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(4), 634–644.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, T. R., & Sappington, D. E. M. (1995). Optimal capital structure in agency relationships. RAND Journal of Economics, 26(3), 343–361.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liang, P. J., Rajan, M., Ray, K. (2008). Optimal team size and monitoring in organizations. Accounting Review, 83(3), 789–822.

    Google Scholar 

  • Manso, G. (2011). Motivating innovation. Journal of Finance, 66(5), 1823–1860.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marschak, J., & Radner, R. (1972). Economic theory of teams. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mellow, W. (1982). Employer size and wages. Review of Economics and Statistics, 64(3), 495–501.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melumad, N. D., Mookherjee, D., Reichelstein, S. (1992). A theory of responsibility centers. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 15(4), 445–484.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melumad, N. D., Mookherjee, D., Reichelstein, S. (1995). Hierarchical decentralization of incentive contracts. RAND Journal of Economics, 26(4), 654–672.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. R., & Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, organization, and management. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee, D., & Reichelstein, S. (2001). Incentives and coordination in hierarchies. Advances in Theoretical Economics, 1(1), 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, J. S. (2012). Why individuals in larger teams perform worse. Organizational Behavior & Human Decision Processes, 117(1), 111–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, H. M., Ouimet, P. P., Simintzi, E. (2017). Within-firm pay inequality. Review of Financial Studies, 30(10), 3605–3635.

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman, A. F. (2007). Risk-bearing and entrepreneurship. Journal of Economic Theory, 137(1), 11–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodríguez, D., Sicilia, M. A., García, E., Harrison, R. (2012). Empirical findings on team size and productivity in software development. Journal of Systems and Software, 85(3), 562–570.

    Google Scholar 

  • Staats, B. R., Milkman, K. L., Fox, C. R. (2012). The team scaling fallacy: Underestimating the declining efficiency of larger teams. Organizational Behavior & Human Decision Processes, 118(2), 132–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tosi, H. L., Werner, S., Katz, J. P., Gomez-Mejia, L. R. (2000). How much does performance matter? A meta-analysis of CEO pay studies. Journal of Management, 26(2), 301–339.

    Google Scholar 

  • van de Ven, A. H., Delbecq, A. L., Koenig, R. J. (1976). Determinants of coordination modes within organizations. American Sociological Review, 41(2), 322–338.

  • Xue, Y. (2007). Make or buy new technology: The role of CEO compensation contract in a firm’s route to innovation. Review of Accounting Studies, 12(4), 659–690.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziv, A. (1993). Performance measures and optimal organization. Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 9(7), 30–50.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ziv, A. (2000). Information technology and optimal firm structure. Journal of Accounting Research, 38(2), 297–328.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank the editor, two anonymous reviewers, Martin Wu, Samuel Pereira, and participants of the Management Accounting Section Midyear Meeting 2017, the Workshop on Accounting and Economics 2016, the Annual Congress of the European Accounting Association 2016, and the Colloquium on Personnel Economics 2016 for helpful comments. Anna Rohlfing-Bastian acknowledges financial support by the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft (DFG, German Research Foundation)–Project-ID 403041268–TRR 266.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anna Rohlfing-Bastian.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A

The principal’s optimization problem is

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \max_{b,\beta_{x},\beta_{y},n} \phantom{...} & & CEP(\cdot)\\ \text{s.t.} \phantom{...} & & CEW(\cdot)\geq0, \qquad\qquad\quad \ \ \qquad\qquad\qquad(IRW)\\ && CEM(\cdot)\geq0, \qquad \qquad\quad\ \ \qquad\qquad\qquad(IRM)\\ && e\in\operatornamewithlimits{argmax}_{e'\in\mathbb{R}}\phantom{..}CEW(\cdot), \qquad \qquad\qquad\qquad(ICW)\\ && s\in\operatornamewithlimits{argmax}_{s'\in\mathbb{R}}\phantom{..}CEM(\cdot), \qquad \qquad\qquad\qquad(ICM_{1})\\ && m\in\operatornamewithlimits{argmax}_{m'\in\mathbb{R}}\phantom{..}CEM(\cdot). \qquad \qquad\qquad\qquad(ICM_{2}) \end{array} $$

Proof Proof of Lemma 1.

If efforts are observable, the optimal effort choices for the workers and the manager are determined by differentiating the principal’s certainty equivalent, given in Eq. 3 with respect to e, s, and m. Solving the respective first-order conditions yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} e&=&\frac{p s G(n)}{s+n G(n)^{2}({\beta_{x}^{2}} r+(1-\beta_{x})^{2}\lambda)\cdot {\sigma_{p}^{2}}}, \\ s&=& n e G(n)\sqrt{{\beta_{x}^{2}} r+(1-\beta_{x})^{2}\lambda}\cdot\sigma_{p}\text{, and} \\ m^{*}&=&\sqrt{\lambda(\beta_{y}+n b)^{2}+r({\beta_{y}^{2}}+n {b}^{2})}\cdot\sigma_{y}. \end{array} $$

Solving the system of equations given by e and s yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} e^{*}&=&G(n)\cdot\left( p-\sqrt{{\beta_{x}^{2}} r+(1-\beta_{x})^{2}{\lambda}}\cdot \sigma_{p}\right)\text{ and }\\ s^{*}&=&n G(n)^{2}\cdot\sqrt{{\beta_{x}^{2}} r+(1-\beta_{x})^{2}{\lambda}}\cdot \sigma_{p} \left( p-\sqrt{{\beta_{x}^{2}} r+(1-\beta_{x})^{2}{\lambda}}\cdot \sigma_{p}\right). \end{array} $$

Inserting the optimal effort choices as well as the binding individual rationality constraints (IRW) and (IRM) into the principal’s certainty equivalent in Eq. 3 yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} CEP &=& \frac{1}{2}n G(n)^{2}\left( p-\sqrt{\lambda-2\lambda \beta_{x}+(r+\lambda){\beta_{x}^{2}}}\cdot \sigma_{p} \right)^{2} \\ &&-\sqrt{\lambda(\beta_{y} + n b)^{2} + r ({\beta_{y}^{2}}+n b^{2})} \cdot \sigma_{y} -C(n). \end{array} $$

Differentiating this equation with respect to b, βx, and βy and solving the respective first-order conditions yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} b&=&-\frac{\lambda \beta_{y}}{r+n\lambda},\\ \beta_{x}^{*}&=&\frac{\lambda}{r+\lambda}, \text{ and}\\ \beta_{y}&=&-\frac{n \lambda b}{r+\lambda}. \end{array} $$

Solving the systems of equations given by b and βy leads to optimal incentive rates of \(b^{*}=\beta _{y}^{*}=0\) and the respective incentive rate \(\beta _{x}^{*}\) given in the lemma. Inserting the optimal incentive rates into the principal’s payoff yields

$$ {CEP}^{*}= \frac{1}{2} n G(n)^{2} \left( p-\sqrt{\frac{r \cdot \lambda}{r + \lambda}}\cdot \sigma_{p}\right)^{2} - C(n). $$

Proof Proof of Lemma 2.

Differentiating Eq. 1 with respect to e and Eq. 2 with respect to s and m yields the optimal effort choices

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} e^{\dagger}&=&G(n)b,\\ s^{\dagger}&=&n G(n)^{2}\sqrt{r} \beta_{x} b \sigma_{p}, \text{ and}\\ m^{\dagger}&=&\sqrt{r} \beta_{y} \sigma_{y}. \end{array} $$

Inserting the optimal effort choices into the principal’s certainty equivalent Eq. 3 and considering the binding individual rationality constraints (IRW) and (IRM) yields

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} CEP &=& n b G(n)^{2} \bigg(p - \frac{1}{2\sqrt{r}\beta_{x}}(\lambda (1 - \beta_{x})^{2} + 2 r {\beta_{x}^{2}})\cdot \sigma_{p} \bigg) -\frac{1}{2}n G(n)^{2} b^{2} \\ &-& \frac{1}{2\sqrt{r}\beta_{y}}\cdot \sigma_{y} \bigg(n (n \lambda + r) b^{2} + 2 n \lambda b \beta_{y} + (2 r + \lambda) {\beta_{y}^{2}}\bigg) -C(n). \end{array} $$

Differentiating this expression with respect to b, βx, and βy and solving the respective first-order conditions gives the optimal incentive rates

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} b&=&\frac{\beta_{y}}{(r+n\lambda)\sigma_{y} + \sqrt{r}\beta_{y} G(n)^{2}}\!\left( \!G(n)^{2}\!\left( p\sqrt{r} - (r \beta_{x}+\frac{\lambda(1-\beta_{x})^{2}}{2\beta_{x}})\sigma_{p}\right)-\lambda\sigma_{y}\right), \\ \beta_{x}^{\dagger}&=&\frac{\sqrt{\lambda}}{\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}\text{, and} \\ \beta_{y}&=&\frac{\sqrt{n}\sqrt{n \lambda+r}}{\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}b. \end{array} $$

Solving the respective system of equations given by b and βy yields the optimal second-best incentive rates stated in the lemma (expressions Eqs. 56 and 7). Inserting the optimal incentive rates into the principal’s utility gives

$$ {CEP}^{\dagger}=\frac{1}{2} n G(n)^{2}\left[p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n)\right]^{2}- C(n). $$

Proof Proof of Proposition 1.

We first obtain the conditions for the optimal team size in the first- and second-best settings. Differentiating the principal’s utilities derived in connection with Lemmas 1 and 2 with respect to n yields the following necessary conditions for the optimal team size:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} (p-\psi^{*})^{2} G(n^{*})\bigg(\frac{1}{2}G(n^{*}) +n^{*} G'(n^{*}) \bigg) - C'(n^{*})&\!=&\!0,\\ G(n^{\dagger}) \left( \frac{1}{2}G(n^{\dagger})+n^{\dagger} G'(n^{\dagger})\right)(p - \psi^{\dagger}\!-\theta^{\dagger}(n^{\dagger}))^{2}&&\\ + \!\left( \!\frac{1}{2}\sigma_{y}\frac{\sqrt{r}}{\sqrt{n^{\dagger}}}\frac{\sqrt{2r + \lambda}}{\sqrt{r + n^{\dagger} \lambda}}+2n^{\dagger} G'(n^{\dagger})G(n^{\dagger})\theta^{\dagger}(n^{\dagger})\!\right)(p - \psi^{\dagger} - \theta^{\dagger}(n^{\dagger})) - C'(n^{\dagger})&\!=&\!0, \end{array} $$

with \(\psi ^{*}=\sqrt {\frac {r\cdot \lambda }{r + \lambda }}\cdot \sigma _{p}\) and ψ as well as 𝜃 as defined in Lemma 2. The sufficient condition is obtained by formulating the second derivative, which is exemplarily done for the first-best case but works the same for the second-best case:

$$ \frac{\partial^{2} {CEP}^{*}}{\partial n^{2}} = \underbrace{\left( p - {\psi^{*}}\right)^{2}}_{\text{I}}\cdot \underbrace{\!\bigg(\!G(n^{*}) G'(n^{*}) + n^{*} G'(n^{*})^{2} + n^{*} G(n^{*}) G^{\prime\prime}(n^{*}) \!\bigg)}_{\text{II}} - \underbrace{C^{\prime\prime}(n^{*})}_{\text{III}}\!<\!0. $$

Part I of the term is positive, and part II can either be positive or negative, depending on the functional form of G(n). Part III is negative, as assumed from the functional form of the organizational costs. For an extremely large team size (\(n \to \infty \)), the product III will approach zero, but the organizational costs will approach \(-\infty \), so that the existence of a maximizing optimum is ensured as long as the risk-adjusted productivity and the marginal synergy effect are sufficiently large for n = 1. We can now compare the two conditions for the optimal team size in the first- and second-best case. This allows us to make an inference on the relation between the first- and second-best team sizes:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \frac{\partial {CEP}^{*}}{\partial n}&=& -C'(n) + \underbrace{(p-\psi^{*})^{2} G(n)\bigg(n G'(n) + \frac{1}{2}G(n) \bigg)}_{\text{I}}, \\ \frac{\partial {CEP}^{\dagger}}{\partial n}&=& -C'(n) + \underbrace{(p - {\psi^{\dagger}})^{2} G(n) \bigg(n G'(n) + \frac{1}{2} G(n) \bigg)}_{\text{I'}} \\ && - \underbrace{{\theta^{\dagger}(n)}^{2} G(n) \bigg(n G'(n) + \frac{1}{2}G(n) \bigg) }_{\text{II}}\\ & &- \underbrace{(p-{\psi^{\dagger}}-{\theta^{\dagger}(n)}) {G(n)^{2}} {\theta^{\dagger}(n)} \left( \frac{2r + \lambda + 4 n \lambda + \frac{\sqrt{n} \lambda \sqrt{2r + \lambda} }{\sqrt{r + n \lambda}} }{4 r + 2 \lambda +4 n \lambda} \right)}_{\text{III}}. \end{array} $$

The optimal team size is determined by the intersection of the marginal cost function with the marginal benefit function. The marginal cost function C(n) is increasing at an increasing rate and identical in the first- and second-best cases. The marginal benefits are increasing at a decreasing rate. The marginal benefits in the first-best case are given by part I and by parts I’, II, and III in the second-best case. Apart from the parameter ψ, parts I and I’ are identical. We next need to show that ψ > ψ. We prove the inequality by contradiction, that is, we start with ψ < ψ and show that this leads to a conflict with a basic assumption on the underlying model parameters. Replacing the simplification symbols ψ and ψ with the respective terms yields the initial inequality:

$$\frac{\sqrt{\lambda}}{\sqrt{r}} \bigg(\sqrt{2 r + \lambda} - \sqrt{\lambda}\bigg) < \frac{\sqrt{r\cdot \lambda}}{\sqrt{r + \lambda}}.$$

We then simplify and rearrange the terms to eliminate the fractions:

$$\sqrt{r + \lambda} \sqrt{2 r + \lambda} - \sqrt{\lambda} \sqrt{r + \lambda} < r.$$

We then square the inequality and simplify the terms:

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} 2 r^{2} + 3 r \lambda + \lambda^{2} & <& r^{2} + 2 r \sqrt{\lambda r + \lambda^{2}} + \lambda r + \lambda^{2}, \\ r + 2 \lambda & < &2 \sqrt{\lambda r + \lambda^{2}}, \\ r^{2} + 4 r \lambda + 4 \lambda^{2} & <& 4 \lambda r + 4 \lambda^{2},\\ r^{2} & < &0. \end{array} $$

Risk aversion is assumed to be positive, and the squared value needs to be positive in any way. We therefore obtain a contradiction and have proven that ψ > ψ. With this result, it follows that I > I’; that is, this part of the marginal benefits is smaller in the second- than in the first-best case. Moreover, parts II and III are positive and enter the equation in the second-best case with a negative sign, such that the marginal benefits are further reduced in the second-best case. We can thus conclude that the marginal benefit function in the second-best case is below the marginal benefit function in the first-best case. Given the functional specifications, the intersection of the second-best marginal benefit function with the marginal cost function, \(\displaystyle \frac {\partial {CEP}^{\dagger }}{\partial n}=0\mid _{n=n^{\dagger }}\), needs to occur for smaller n than the intersection of the first-best marginal benefit function with the marginal cost function, \(\displaystyle \frac {\partial {CEP}^{*}}{\partial n}=0\mid _{n=n^{*}}\); that is, n < n. □

Proof Proof of Proposition 2.

The comparative statics of the optimal team size n with respect to any exogenous parameter are derived by implicit differentiation. We denote the exogenous parameters p, σp, and σy by h. From the optimality condition in the proof of Proposition 1, we define

$$ \frac{\partial {CEP}^{\dagger}}{\partial n}=F(n,h)\stackrel{!}{=} 0. $$

From the rule for implicit differentiation, we obtain

$$ \frac{\partial F}{\partial h} + \frac{\partial F}{\partial n^{\dagger}} \cdot \frac{\partial n^{\dagger}}{\partial h} = 0. $$

Rearranging the terms leads to

$$ \frac{\partial n^{\dagger}}{\partial h} = -\frac{\frac{\partial F}{\partial h}}{\frac{\partial F}{\partial n^{\dagger}}}=-\frac{F_{h}}{F_{n^{\dagger}}}. $$

We now need to define the partial derivative of the optimality condition F with respect to the optimal team size, which is equal to the second derivative of the principal’s certainty equivalent with respect to n:

$$ \frac{\partial F}{\partial n}= \frac{\partial^{2} {CEP}^{\dagger}}{\partial n^{2}}<0. $$

This expression has already been defined as being negative (sufficient condition for a concave structure of the principal’s expected utility such that the optimal team size maximizes the principal’s utility). The direction of the effect of a change in any of the exogenous parameters, h, is therefore the same as the direction of the effect of a change in any of the exogenous parameters on the function F:

$$ sgn\left( \frac{\partial n^{\dagger}}{\partial h}\right) = -\frac{\overbrace{F_{h}}^{\text{\large{?}}}}{\underbrace{F_{n^{\dagger}}}_{\text{\LARGE{-}}}}=sgn(F_{h})=sgn\left( \frac{\partial F}{\partial h}\right). $$

The sign is determined by formulating the partial derivatives and using the assumptions for the relation of the risk aversions and the function G(n):

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} sgn\!\left( \!\frac{\partial n^{\dagger}}{\partial \sigma_{p}}\!\right)\! &=&\! sgn\!\left( \frac{\partial F}{\partial \sigma_{p}}\right)\\ &=& \! sgn\!\left( \! - \frac{\sqrt{\lambda}}{\sqrt{r}}(\sqrt{2r \! +\! \lambda}\! -\! \sqrt{\lambda})\bigg(\! (G(n)^{2}\! +\! 2nG'(n) G(n)) (p\! -\! \psi^{\dagger}\! -\! \theta^{\dagger}(n)) \right. \\ && \left. + \frac{1}{2} \sigma_{y} \frac{\sqrt{r}}{\sqrt{n}} \frac{\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}{\sqrt{r+n \lambda}} +2n G'(n)G(n) \theta^{\dagger}(n) \bigg) \right) \\ &=&\! -1, \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} sgn\!\left( \!\frac{\partial n^{\dagger}}{\partial \sigma_{y}}\!\right)\! &=&\! sgn\! \left( \frac{\partial F}{\partial \sigma_{y}}\right)\\ &=&\! sgn\! \left( \! -\frac{\theta^{\dagger}\!({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt})}{\sigma_{y}}\! \bigg(\! 2 n G'\!({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt}){\kern-.5pt} G{\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt}) \theta^{\dagger}\!({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt}) \! +\! \frac{1}{2} \frac{G(n)^{2} r}{\sqrt{n} \lambda \! +\! \sqrt{2r\! +\!\lambda} \sqrt{r\! +\! n \lambda}} \frac{\sqrt{2r\! +\!\lambda}}{\sqrt{r\! +\! n \lambda}} \theta^{\dagger}\!({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt}) \right. \\ && \left. +G(n)^{2} (p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n)) \right. \\ && \left. \left( \! \frac{2 \sqrt{n} \lambda \! +\! \sqrt{2r\! +\! \lambda} \sqrt{r\! +\! n\lambda} }{2 (\sqrt{n} \lambda \! +\! \sqrt{2r\! +\! \lambda} \sqrt{r\! +\! n\lambda}) } \! +\! \frac{\sqrt{2r+\lambda} n \lambda }{2 \sqrt{r\! +\! n \lambda} (\sqrt{n} \lambda \! +\! \sqrt{2r\! +\!\lambda} \sqrt{r\! +\! n\lambda}) }\! \right) \bigg) \right) \\ &=&\! -1, \end{array} $$
$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} sgn\!\left( \!\frac{\partial n^{\dagger}}{\partial p}\!\right)\! &=&\! sgn\!\left( \frac{\partial F}{\partial p}\right)\\ &=&\! sgn\bigg((G(n)^{2}+2nG'(n)G(n))(p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n))\\ &&\left. + \bigg(\frac{1}{2} \sigma_{y} \frac{\sqrt{r}}{\sqrt{n}} \frac{\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}{\sqrt{r+n \lambda}} +2nG'(n)G(n)\theta^{\dagger}(n) \bigg) \right) \\ &=&\! +1. \end{array} $$

To determine the impact of a change in the synergy effect G(n) on the optimal team size n, we add an infinitesimally small μ to the function G(n), that is, G(n)Δ = G(n) + μ, and re-derive the optimality condition in the proof of Proposition 1. Next, we compare this condition with the original optimality condition in the proof of Proposition 1. Since the marginal costs C(n) remain the same, the difference between the marginal benefits determines the direction of the impact (the argumentation is analogous to the proof of Proposition 1):

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&sgn\left( \frac{\partial {CEP}^{\dagger}_{G(n)_{\Delta}}}{\partial n} - \displaystyle\frac{\partial {CEP}^{\dagger}_{G(n)}}{\partial n} \right)\\ &=& sgn\left( \underbrace{\bigg(\frac{1}{2}G(n)_{\Delta}+nG'(n)\bigg)G(n)_{\Delta}\bigg(p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n) \displaystyle\frac{G(n)^{2}}{G(n)_{\Delta}^{2}} \bigg)^{2}}_{\text{I}} \right. \\ &-& \underbrace{\bigg(\frac{1}{2}G(n)+nG'(n)\bigg)G(n)\bigg(p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n)\bigg)^{2}}_{\text{I'}} \\ &+& \bigg(p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n) \displaystyle\frac{G(n)^{2}}{G(n)_{\Delta}^{2}}\bigg)\\ &\cdot&\underbrace{\bigg(\frac{1}{2} \sigma_{y} \displaystyle\frac{\sqrt{r}}{\sqrt{n}}\frac{\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}{\sqrt{r+n \lambda}}+2nG'(n)G(n)_{\Delta}\theta^{\dagger}(n) \displaystyle\frac{G(n)^{2}}{G(n)_{\Delta}^{2}}\bigg)}_{\text{II}} \\ &-& \left. \underbrace{\bigg(p-\psi^{\dagger}-\theta^{\dagger}(n)\bigg)\bigg(\frac{1}{2} \sigma_{y} \frac{\sqrt{r}}{\sqrt{n}}\frac{\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}{\sqrt{r+n \lambda}}+2nG'(n)G(n)\theta^{\dagger}(n)\bigg)}_{\text{II'}} \right) \\ &=& +1. \end{array} $$

The only difference between parts I and I’ as well as between parts II and II’ lies in the use of the function G(n)Δ instead of G(n). By assumption, G(n)Δ > G(n). Furthermore, the factor \(\frac {G(n)^{2}}{G(n)_{\Delta }^{2}}\) appears in parts I and II with \(\frac {G(n)^{2}}{G(n)_{\Delta }^{2}} \leq 1\), such that parts I and II exceed their counterparts I’ and II’. The positive impact also holds for an infinitesimally small change in a multiplicatively linked factor; that is, G(n)Δ = G(n) ⋅ γ. □

Proof Proof of Proposition 3.

The variable compensations depend on b and y for the workers as well as \(\beta _{y}^{\dagger }\), y, \(\beta _{x}^{\dagger }\), and x for the manager. Performance measure y and accounting income x unambiguously increase with team size; that is, \(\frac {\partial y}{\partial n}>0\) and \(\frac {\partial x}{\partial n}>0\). The manager’s bonus rate \(\beta _{x}^{\dagger }\) is independent of the team size n; that is, \(\frac {\partial \beta _{x}^{\dagger }}{\partial n}=0\). The first derivative of the worker’s bonus rate is

$$\frac{\partial b^{\dagger}}{\partial n}=\frac{\sigma_{y} \!\left( 4 n G^{\prime}(n) \left( n \lambda \sqrt{2 r + \lambda}+\!\sqrt{n} \lambda \sqrt{n \lambda + r}+r \sqrt{2 r + \lambda}\right) + r G(n) \sqrt{2 r + \lambda}\right)}{2 n^{3/2} \sqrt{r} G(n)^{3} \sqrt{n \lambda+r}}\!>\!0.$$

Given the assumptions for the underlying parameters, this expression is larger than zero. The manager’s short-term bonus rate is given by \(\beta _{y}^{\dagger }=\frac {\sqrt {n} \sqrt {n \lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}\cdot b^{\dagger }\). Since we have already demonstrated that \(\frac {\partial b^{\dagger }}{\partial n}>0\), we focus on the term \(\frac {\sqrt {n} \sqrt {n \lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}\). Given the underlying assumptions for the parameter values, this expression increases in n. We thus conclude that the manager’s and the workers’ compensations both increase in n. Next, we demonstrate that this increase is more pronounced for managers than for workers. We show that this is already the case if we compare only the short-term bonuses, and we can then conclude that it will hold for the total bonus as well. We need to show that \(\frac {\partial b^{\dagger }}{\partial n}<\frac {\partial \beta _{y}^{\dagger }}{\partial n}\). We define b = b(n), \(\frac {\partial b}{\partial n}=b^{\prime }(n)\), \(\frac {\sqrt {n} \sqrt {n \lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}=\beta (n)\), and \(\frac {\partial \frac {\sqrt {n} \sqrt {n \lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}}{\partial n}=\beta ^{\prime }(n)\). Applying basic differentiation rules leads to

$$b^{\prime}(n)<\beta^{\prime}(n)\cdot b(n)+\beta(n)\cdot b^{\prime}(n) \text{ and}$$
$$b^{\prime}(n)(1-\beta(n))<\beta^{\prime}(n)\cdot b(n).$$

It can be shown that β(n) > 1 for n > 2, such that (1 − β(n)) < 0 for n > 2. Consequently, the left-hand side of the expression \(b^{\prime }(n)(1-\beta (n))\) is negative for n > 2, while the right-hand side, \(\beta ^{\prime }(n)\cdot b(n)\), is positive. Therefore we conclude that the manager’s short-term bonus increases faster than the workers’ bonus for teams with more than two members. □

Proof Proof of Proposition 4.

It has already been shown in the proof of Proposition 2 that the optimal team size n varies with changes in exogenous parameters.Footnote 28 We now demonstrate that the optimal bonus rates b and βy for an endogenously chosen n vary with changes in exogenous parameters. Since \(\beta _{y}=\frac {\sqrt {n}\sqrt {n\lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2r+\lambda }}\cdot b=\beta (n)\cdot b\), with β(n) > 1 for n > 2 (see Proof of Proposition 3), it is sufficient to derive the comparative statics for b. For any exogenous parameter p,σp, and σy denoted by h, we have

$$\frac{db}{dh}=\frac{\partial b}{\partial h}+\frac{\partial b}{\partial n}\cdot\frac{dn}{dh}.$$

We derive the following proof exemplarily for a change in productivity p. The proof for the other exogenous parameter is analogous. We have already shown in the proof of Proposition 2 that \(\frac {\partial n}{\partial p}>0\). Moreover, \(\frac {\partial b}{\partial p}=1>0\), which confirms the first part in Proposition 4. Next, we have to show that there exist cases in which

$$\frac{db}{dh}>\frac{dn}{dh};$$

that is,

$$\frac{\partial b}{\partial p}+\frac{\partial b}{\partial n}\cdot \frac{dn}{dp}>\frac{dn}{dp}.$$

Rearranging yields

$$\frac{\partial b}{\partial p}+\frac{dn}{dp}\left( \frac{\partial b}{\partial n}-1\right)>0.$$

Since \(\frac {\partial b}{\partial p}\) and \(\frac {dn}{dp}\) point in the same direction, the above condition is fulfilled, for example, if \(\frac {\partial b}{\partial n}\geq 1\), confirming the second part in Proposition 4. □

Proof Proof of Corollary 1.

We have already shown in the proof of Proposition 3 that \(\frac {\partial b}{\partial n}>0\). We now have to show that \(\frac {\partial n}{\partial b}>0\) holds as well. We take the procedure described in the proof of Proposition 2 and use implicit differentiation, where F is given by \(\displaystyle \frac {\partial CEP^{\dagger }}{\partial n}\) before optimizing with respect to the bonus rate b:

$$\frac{\partial F}{\partial b}\! =\!\frac{-\sigma_{y}\!\left( \!\frac{(r+2n\lambda)\sqrt{2r+\lambda}}{\sqrt{n}\sqrt{r+n\lambda}}+2\lambda\!\right) + 2\!\left( \!\sqrt{r}{\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}p\! -\! b{\kern-.5pt})\! +\! \sigma_{p}{\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}\lambda\! -\! \sqrt{\lambda}\sqrt{2r\! +\! \lambda})\!\right)\! G{\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt}){\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}G{\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt})\! +\! 2nG^{\prime} {\kern-.5pt}({\kern-.5pt}n{\kern-.5pt}){\kern-.5pt})}{2\sqrt{r}}$$

At the optimal b, this expression is larger than zero, confirming that team size increases with incentives. □

Proof Proof of Corollary 2.

While this result is already illustrated in Table 1, the analytical proof of the corollary follows directly from the fact that \(\beta _{y}^{\dagger }=\frac {\sqrt {n} \sqrt {n \lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}\cdot b^{\dagger }\), where \(\frac {\sqrt {n} \sqrt {n \lambda +r}}{\sqrt {2 r+\lambda }}>1\) for n > 2.Footnote 29 The manager’s short-term incentives are thus affected by a change in exogenous parameters via two channels: a direct effect, which is visible in b, and an indirect effect, through the optimal team size, n. Both factors are directionally equally affected by changes in exogenous parameters. □

Appendix B

Proof Proof of the result ofFu et al. (2016) for a risk-averse principal.

To derive the impact of risk on team size for a risk-averse principal, we use the same solution procedure as in the original version but with a change in the principal’s utility:Footnote 30

$$ \phi = \rho(N) A N^{x} b^{\tau-1} - B N^{x} b^{\tau} - \frac{1}{2} \gamma N S^{2} b^{2} - \frac{1}{2} \lambda (\rho(N) - N b)^{2} S^{2}. $$

The result for the comparative statics is determined by the following inequality:

$$ sgn\left( \frac{\partial N}{\partial S^{2}} \right)=sgn\left( \frac{\partial^{2} \phi}{\partial N \partial b} \frac{\partial^{2} \phi}{\partial b \partial S^{2}} - \frac{\partial^{2} \phi}{\partial N \partial S^{2}}\frac{\partial^{2} \phi}{\partial b^{2}} \right) > 0. $$

Inserting first \(\frac {\partial ^{2} \phi }{\partial b \partial S^{2}}\) and \(\frac {\partial ^{2} \phi }{\partial N \partial S^{2}}\), we obtain the equivalent to the original condition (A10)Footnote 31. After inserting, rearranging, and simplifying the equivalents of (A14) and (A16), (A18), and (A21), the condition is reduced to the equivalent of (A22):

$$ \begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} &&\!\!\!\! B N^{x} b^{\tau} (x -\frac{1}{2} \tau ) -\frac{\lambda}{\gamma} (\rho(N) -b N) B N^{x} b^{\tau-1} (x -\frac{1}{2} \tau ) \\ &&\!\!\!\! + \frac{1}{2}\frac{\lambda}{\gamma} A \rho(N) N^{x} (\tau -1) b^{\tau - 2} (\rho(N) -b N) (1 -\frac{2 \rho^{\prime}(N)}{b} ) \\ &&\!\!\!\! +\frac{1}{2}\frac{\lambda}{\gamma} N {S^{2}}\! \left( \! b^{2} N \! \!\left( {\kern-.3pt}N \lambda\! +\! \gamma\! \right) \! +\! \lambda \rho({\kern-.3pt}N{\kern-.3pt}) \! \left( \rho{\kern-.3pt}({\kern-.3pt}N{\kern-.3pt}) \! -\! 2 b {\kern-.3pt} N{\kern-.3pt} \right) \! -\! 2 \rho^{\prime}\!(N) \! \left( N \lambda \! +\! \gamma \right) \! \left( \rho(N) \! - \! b N \right)\! \right) \! >\! 0. \end{array} $$

For this inequality to hold, a few straightforward conditions need to hold. Moreover, a condition remains that can be simplified by inserting A and B:

$$ \alpha > \alpha_{min}=\left( \frac{1}{2} \frac{\rho(N)}{b} \left( 1 - 2 \frac{\rho^{\prime}(N)}{b} + \frac{b}{\rho(N)}\right) + \frac{1}{\delta} \right)^{-1 }. $$

Since αmin increases in b, the condition holds for any b < bmax if it holds for bmax. Using the limit on \(b=b_{max}=\frac {\rho (N)}{N}\), we can rearrange this condition to be

$$ \alpha > \left( \frac{1}{2} N \left( 1 - 2 \frac{\rho^{\prime}(N)}{\rho(N)} N + \frac{1}{N} \right) + \frac{1}{\delta} \right)^{-1}. $$

Since \(1 - 2 \frac {\rho ^{\prime }(N)}{\rho (N)} N + \frac {1}{N} > 1\), the condition holds for reasonable values for N and α. Using the numerical example in the paper, that is, δ= 2.1, Nmin= 5, and the lower bound \(1 - 2 \frac {\rho ^{\prime }(N)}{\rho (N)} N + \frac {1}{N}\text {=}1\), the inequality reduces to α > 0.336, which holds for the value in the paper; that is, α= 0.5. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Dürr, O., Nisch, M. & Rohlfing-Bastian, A. Incentives in optimally sized teams for projects with uncertain returns. Rev Account Stud 25, 313–341 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-019-09529-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-019-09529-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation