Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Blind Spots: The Effects of Information and Stakes on Fairness Bias and Dispersion

  • Published:
Social Justice Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Mounting empirical research provides evidence of fairness bias and its economic and social effects, where fairness bias refers here to a deviation of claims from unbiased justice due to a personal stake. A far less appreciated issue is dispersion of fairness views and claims, which is also important for its effects on disagreements, empirical analysis, and philosophical theories. This study undertakes a systematic analysis of the effects on fairness bias and dispersion of two variables: stakes and information. Most philosophical and social science analyses related to justice and bias associate heightened bias with increased information and, conversely, impartiality with the elimination of certain information. Less attention has been paid to the opposing impact of information, which is to supply the facts needed to achieve justice more reliably. An important open question is whether, on balance, increased information helps agents to achieve fairer outcomes or whether biased use of such information contributes to less fair outcomes. This study focuses on a set of previously reported experiments that share certain features and subjects them to a new analysis. The results of this analysis suggest that, although information is often used in a self-serving way, increased information can, under certain conditions, contribute to fairness claims becoming less biased and less dispersed, both for stakeholders as well as impartial spectators.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Adams, J. S. (1965). Inequality in Social Exchange. In Berkowitz, L. (ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, Vol. 2, Academic Press, New York, pp. 267–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., and Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: An experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica 70(2): 737–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babcock, L., and Loewenstein, G. (1997). Explaining bargaining impasse: The role of self-serving biases. J. Econ. Perspect. 11(1): 109–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babcock, L., Loewenstein, G., Issacharoff, S., and Camerer, C. (1995). Biased judgments of fairness in bargaining. Am. Econ. Rev. 85(5): 1337–1343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Babcock, L., Wang, X., and Loewenstein, G. (1996). Choosing the wrong pond: Social comparisons in negotiations that reflect a self-serving bias. Q. J. Econ. 111(1): 1–19.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., Katok, E., and Zwick, R. (1996). Dictator game giving: Rules of fairness versus acts of kindness. Int. J. Game Theory 27: 269–299.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C., and Loewenstein, G. (1993). Information, fairness, and efficiency in bargaining. In Mellers, B. A., and Baron, J. (eds.), Psychological Perspectives on Justice, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 155–179.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cason, T. N., and Mui, V. (1997). A laboratory study of group polarization in the team dictator game. Econ. J. 107(444): 1465–1483.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cross, K. P. (1977). Not can, but will college teaching be improved? N. Direct. Higher Educ. 17(Spring): 1–15.

  • Dana, J., Weber, R. A., and Kuang, J. X. (2004). Exploiting moral wriggle room: Behavior inconsistent with a preference for fair outcomes, manuscript.

  • Dunning, D., Meyerowitz, J. A., and Holzberg, A. D. (1989). Ambiguity and self-evaluation: The role of idiosyncratic trait definitions in self-serving assessments of ability. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 57(6): 1082–1090.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellingsen, T., and Johannesson, M. (2002). Does Impartial Deliberation Breed Fair Behavior? An Experimental Test, University of Stockholm: Economics, December.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., and Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Q. J. Econ. 114(3): 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Festinger, L. (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance, Stanford University Press, Stanford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forsythe, R., Horowitz, J. L., Savin, N. E., and Sefton, M. (1994). Fairness in simple bargaining experiments. Games Econ. Behav. 6(May): 347–369.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., and Moore, B. (2001). Some doubts about measuring self-interest using dictator experiments: The costs of anonymity. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 46(3): 271–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gächter, S., and Riedl, A. (2005). Moral property rights with infeasible claims. Manage. Sci. 51(2): 249–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaertner, W., Jungeilges, J., and Neck, R. (2001). Cross-cultural equity evaluations: A questionnaire–experimental approach. Eur. Econ. Rev. 45: 953–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gorman, R. F., and Kehr, J. B. (1992). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Comment. Am. Econ. Rev. 82(1): 355–358.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Huck, S., and Ockenfels, P. (1996). Two-level ultimatum bargaining with incomplete information: An experimental study. Econ. J. 106(436): 593–604.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., Schmittberger, R., and Schwarze, B. (1982). An experimental analysis of ultimatum bargaining. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 3(4): 367–388.

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., and van Damme, E. (1998). Information, strategic behavior, and fairness in ultimatum bargaining: An experimental study. J. Math. Psychol. 42: 227–247.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Hafer, C. L. (2000). Do innocent victims threaten the belief in a just world? Evidence from a modified stroop task. Attitudes Soc. Cogn. 79(2): 165–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haidt, J. (2003). The emotional dog does learn new tricks: A reply to Pizarro and Bloom. Psychol. Rev. 110(1): 197–198.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handgraaf, M. J. J., Van Dijk, E., and De Cremer, D. (2003). Social utility in ultimatum bargaining. Soc. Justice Res. 16(3): 263–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heider, F. (1958). The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations, Wiley, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bolwes, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., and McElreath, R. (2001). In search of homo economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Am. Econ. Rev. 91(2): 73–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., Shachat, K., and Smith, V. (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games Econ. Behav. 7(3): 436–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., McCabe, K., and Smith, V. (1996). Social distance and other-regarding behavior in dictator games. Am. Econ. Rev. 86(3): 653–660.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homans, G. C. (1958). Social behavior as exchange. Am. J. Sociol. 63: 597–606.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hook, J. (1978). The development of equity and logico-mathematical thinking. Child Dev. 49: 1035–1044.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hook, J., and Cook, T. D. (1979). Equity theory and the cognitive ability of children. Psychol. Bull. 86(3): 429–445.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jost, J. T., Blount, S., Pfeffer, J., and Hunyady, G. (2003). Fair market ideology: Its cognitive–motivational underpinnings. Res. Org. Behav. 25: 53–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., and Thaler, R. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. Am. Econ. Rev. 76: 728–741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kay, A. C., and Jost, J. T. (2003). Complementary justice: Effects of “Poor but Happy” and “Poor but Honest” stereotype exemplars on system justification and implicit activation of the justice motive. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 85(5): 823–837.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Komorita, S. S., and Chertkoff, J. M. (1973). A bargaining theory of coalition formation. Psychol. Rev. 80(3): 149–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konow, J. (2000). Fair shares: Accountability and cognitive dissonance in allocation decisions. Am. Econ. Rev. 90(4): 1072–1092.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konow, J. (2003). Which is the fairest one of all?: A positive analysis of justice theories. J. Econ. Literature 41(4): 1186–1237.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konow, J. (2005). Mixed feelings: Theories and evidence of warm glow and altruism, manuscript, Loyola Marymount University.

  • Leventhal, G. S., and Michaels, J. W. (1971). Locus of cause and equity motivation as determinants of reward allocation. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 17(1): 229–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, G., Issacharoff, S., Camerer, C., and Babcock, L. (1993). Self-serving assessments of fairness and pretrial bargaining. J. Legal Stud. 22(1): 135–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Messick, D. M. (1993). Equality as a decision heuristic. In Mellers, B. A., and Baron, J. (eds.), Psychological Perspectives on Justice: Theory and Applications, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp. 11–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Messick, D. M., and Bazerman, M. H. (1996). Ethical leadership and the psychology of decision making. Sloan Manage. Rev. 37: 9–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Messick, D. M., and Sentis, K. P. (1983). Fairness, preference, and fairness biases. In Messick, D. M., and Cook, K. (eds.), Equity Theory: Psychological and Sociological Perspectives, Praeger, New York, pp. 61–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oberholzer-Gee, F., Bohnet, I., and Frey, B. (1997). Fairness and competence in democratic decisions. Public Choice 91(1): 89–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paulhus, D. L., Harms, P. D., Bruce, M. N., and Lysy, D. C. (2003). The over-claiming technique: Measuring self-enhancement independent of ability. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 84(4): 890–904.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Peters, S. L., van den Bos, K., and Bobocel, D. R. (2004). The moral superiority effect: Self versus other differences in satisfaction with being overpaid. Soc. Justice Res. 17(3): 257–273.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pillutla, M. M., and Murnighan, J. K. (1995). Being fair or appearing fair: Strategic behavior in ultimatum bargaining. Acad. Manage. J. 38(5): 1408–1426.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pillutla, M. M., and Murnighan, J. K. (2003). Fairness in bargaining. Soc. Justice Res. 16(3): 241–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). A Theory of Justice, Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., and Malouf, M. W. K. (1979). Game-theoretic models and the role of information in bargaining. Psychol. Rev. 86(6): 574–594.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., Malouf, M. W. K., and Murnighan, J. K. (1981). Sociological versus strategic factors in bargaining. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 2: 153–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., and Murnighan, J. K. (1982). The role of information in bargaining: An experimental study. Econometrica 50(5): 1123–1142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E., Prasnikar, V., Okuno-Fujiwara, M., and Zamir, S. (1991). Bargaining and market behavior in Jerusalem, Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An experimental study. Am. Econ. Rev. 81(5): 1068–1095.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotter, J. B. (1966). Generalized expectancies for internal versus external control of reinforcement. Psychol. Monogr. 80(1): 609.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schokkaert, E., and Capeau, B. (1991). Interindividual differences in opinions about distributive justice. Kyklos 44(3): 325–345.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selten, R. (1965). Spieltheoretische Behandlung Eines Oligopol Models mit Nachfragetragheit. Z. Gesamte Staatswissenschaft 121: 301–324.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1759) [1809]. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, R. Chapman, Glasgow, Scotland.

  • Spiegel, M., Currie, J., Sonnenschein, H., and Sen, A. (1994). Understanding when agents are fairmen or gamesmen. Games Econ. Behav. 7(1): 104–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Straub, P. G., and Murnighan, J. K. (1995). An experimental investigation of ultimatum games: Information, fairness, expectations, and lowest acceptable offers. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 27: 345–364.

    Google Scholar 

  • Svenson, O. (1981). Are we all less risky and more skillful than our fellow drivers? Acta Psychol. 47: 143–148.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, S. E., and Brown, J. D. (1988). Illusion and well-being: A social psychological perspective on mental health. Psychol. Bull. 103(2): 193–210.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Tenbrunsel, A. E., and Messick, D. M. (2004). Ethical fading: The role of self-deception in unethical behavior. Soc. Justice Res. 17(2): 223–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Walster, E., Walster, G. W., and Berscheid, E. (1973). New directions in equity research. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 25(2): 151–176.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiner, B., and Kukla, A. (1970). An attributional analysis of achievement motivation. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 15(1): 1–20.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to James Konow.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Konow, J. Blind Spots: The Effects of Information and Stakes on Fairness Bias and Dispersion. Soc Just Res 18, 349–390 (2005). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11211-005-8566-6

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11211-005-8566-6

Key Words

Navigation