Skip to main content
Log in

Scarcity and consumers’ credit choices

  • Published:
Theory and Decision Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study the effect of scarcity on decision making by low income Swedes. We exploit the random assignment of welfare payments to study their borrowing decisions within the pawn and mainstream credit market. We document that higher educated borrowers borrow less frequently and choose lower loan to value ratios when their budget constraints are exogenously tighter. In contrast, low-educated borrowers do not respond to temporary elevated levels of scarcity. This lack of response translates into a significantly higher probability to default and an 11.6% increase in borrowing cost. We show that a difference in access to liquidity and/or buffer stocks cannot explain our results. Instead a framework, where the awareness of self-control problems is positively correlated with education can explain that high-educated consumers choose a lower LTV as a commitment device to increase their likelihood to repay. Analogously, low-educated with less awareness of their future self-control problems, do not tie themselves to the mast and thus ignore the consequences of their credit decisions when focusing on solving acute liquidity problems. Our findings highlight that increased levels of scarcity risk reinforcing the conditions of poverty through overborrowing.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. From the album: ’I Am Just a Rebel’.

  2. See for example Morse (2011), Bhutta et al., (2015), Agarwal & Bos (2014).

  3. The most relevant behavioral biases studied in this context include, but are not limited to: (i) inconsistent time preferences (Laibson et al., 2003; Meier & Sprenger, 2010), (ii) Biased price perceptions (Gabaix & Laibson, 2006; Bertrand & Morse, 2011), (iii) tendency towards optimism (Brunnermeier & Parker, 2005), (iv) reliance on crude heuristics (Stango & Zinman, 2014). See Bos et al. (2015) and Schilbach et al. (2016) for an overview of this topic.

  4. Other recent papers come to a similar conclusion with alternative mechanisms, for example: Gabaix and Laibson (2017) present a model, where agents who are unable to think carefully about an intertemporal tradeoff, for example due to a high cognitive load, will exhibit more discounting, even though agents are patient. Bernheim et al. (2015) show theoretically that low levels of assets undermine the individuals’ capacity for self-control by diminishing the effectiveness of self-imposed punishments.

  5. Borrowers reveal this preference to repay and ultimately retrieve their collateral when they decide to pawn their gold, instead of selling it at the gold-to-cash vendor. The lion’s share of pawn loans (more than 80%) in the full sample are secured by gold (see Bos et al. (2012)), and we limit our sample to pawn loans collateralized by gold, to calculate the loan to value ratio. A pawn loan contract is typically 3–4 months long and thus the pawn broker is exposed to the risk that the price of gold will fall during this time. Furthermore, the pawnbroker has to bear the cost of administering the loan and storing the gold. The gold-to-cash service can, in theory, resell the gold immediately with a lower administrative burden.

  6. An individual’s probability of taking a pawn loan increases, on average, by 2% per day since payday.

  7. Stephens (2003, 2006), Shapiro (2005), Mastrobuoni and Weinberg (2009), Huffman and Barenstein (2005).

  8. As education correlates with income, wealth and preferences, we discuss alternative interpretations below.

  9. Note that Allcott et al. (2020) find that three quartiles of the studied payday loan population are sophisticated borrowers. If the lion share of our studied customers would be sophisticated, we would expect a large share of borrowers using a commitment device (i.e., a lower loan to value). This is not what we find. We believe that the main difference between their paper and ours lies in the sample selection. Our identification strategy of exogenous exposure to scarcity only works for the unemployed pawnborrowers receiving welfare benefits every month, that is, the poor people. This selection might explain the smaller share of sophisticated borrowers in our sample compared to Allcott et al. (2020) that sample randomly from a pool of all payday borrowers. In addition, we consider education level as a proxy for sophistication, while Allcott et al. (2020) define the sophistication level as a forecast error (the difference between perceived and actual probability of borrowing in the next 8 weeks). The best proxy for sophistication is ultimately an empirical question on which the literature is still debating.

  10. We observe, among other things, the borrowers’ mainstream credit applications, balances and limits of their credit cards and installment loans, and arrears.

  11. Online Appendix A.1 presents further details.

  12. We use a 7-day cutoff for three reasons. Firstly, expenditure needs may differ depending on the day of the week, so we ensure that all weekdays are in the post-period. This is especially relevant as the pawnbroker is typically not open on Sunday, which constrains participation for either the early or late born when their payday is moved. Secondly, the trends until 7 days before payday are parallel, after which divergence occurs (see Fig. A1). Finally, we follow Carvalho et al. (2016), who also define the last week before payday as the scarce period. We demonstrate robustness to this choice of cutoff in Online Appendix A, Table A6.

  13. See Bos et al. (2012) for a comparison of the Swedish and US pawn industries and their customers.

  14. In addition, trust does not play a role, as the asset is physically handed over to the pawnbroker, avoiding costly liquidation or bankruptcy procedures.

  15. We calculate the LTV ratio using the gold price at the time of the loan origination and the grams of gold we observe in the dataset.

  16. The probabilities of default are estimated by the credit bureau, with a model based on data from the entire Swedish adult population. The model specifications are proprietary.

  17. As we use borrower fixed effects in our regression, adding all social transfer recipients that do not take pawn loans to our estimation sample does not affect the quantitative results.

  18. An extensive theoretical literature has emerged studying the consequences of hyperbolic discounting for consumption choices. See, amongst others, Laibson (1997), Harris and Laibson (2001), Fehr (2002), DellaVigna and Malmendier (2004)

  19. Skiba and Tobacman (2008) find that a model with hyperbolic discounting and different degrees of sophistication matches the data on payday borrowing, rollover and default. The distinction between sophisticates and naifs is from the seminal article of O’Donoghue and Rabin (1999).

  20. Our main result is robust to defining 3 groups of education (primary, secondary and post-secondary).

  21. See for example Heidhues and Kőszegi (2010), Skiba and Tobacman (2008), Kuchler and Pagel (2018)

  22. Tables A1 and A2 show coefficients for all included variables.

  23. The pre-period mean reported in column 4 is taken over all borrowers, as opposed to the non-scarce mean for low-educated borrowers, given in columns 1–3.

  24. A different way of studying the intensity of treatment would be to consider two (or more) consecutive long payday cycles. However, this pattern hardly occurs in our panel: Only 3 (1) months out of 48 were long for the early- (late-) born after the previous month being long as well.

  25. We also limit our sample to pawn shops, where at least 5% of all loans in the full sample had a maturity of 2 months, which we define to be the shops offering the menu of contracts. The results are very similar to using different cut-offs.

  26. The average loan size is around 4,000 SEK. The fees and interest costs per kronor borrowed amount to 0.25 SEK for the 77% of loans that end up being repaid, giving costs of \(4,000\times 0.25\times 0.77=770\) SEK. For the 23% of loans that end up in default, and given the average LTV of 76%, the costs amount to \(4,000\times 0.23/0.76=1211\) SEK. During periods of increased scarcity, we estimate a 10.7% increased probability to borrow (Sect. 3.2) as well as a 4% points higher likelihood of defaulting. The repayment costs and default costs due to scarcity amount to \(0.107\times 4000\times 0.25\times 0.73=78\) SEK and \(0.107\times 4000\times 0.27/0.76=152\) SEK, respectively. Hence, scarcity increases pawn credit costs by \(100\times (78+152)/(770+1211)=11.6\%\).

  27. The results using continuous variables for income and age in the regression are representative for an extensive specification search, using for instance dummies for income deciles or retirees. These results are not reported for brevity.

  28. Again, we have used a battery of other specifications for these variables (continuous, dummies etc.) which all gave similar results.

  29. Using the full payday cycle, or the last 4 weeks, instead of the last 3 weeks, does not affect the results of our main regression (see Panel b of Table A6). The Wald test for parallel trends using the full payday cycle instead of the last 3 weeks does not reject the null hypothesis of parallel trends in the non-scarce period, for neither the probability to take a pawn loan (p = 0.48) nor the LTV ratio (p = 0.30).

  30. We thank the referee for this suggestion.

References

  • Agarwal, S., & Bos, M. (2014). ‘Rationality in the consumer credit market: Choosing between alternative and mainstream credit. Working paper 1978574, SSRN.

  • Agnew, J., Balduzzi, P., & Sunden, A. (2003). Portfolio choice and trading in a large 401 (k) plan. American Economic Review, 93(1), 193–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allcott, H., Kim, J., Taubinsky, D., & Zinman, J. (2020). Are high-interest loans predatory? theory and evidence from payday lending. Tech. rep., Technical report, Working paper.

  • Ashraf, N., Karlan, D., & Tin, W. (2006). Tying Odysseus to the mast: evidence from a commitment savings product in the Philippines. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 635–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baugh, B. K., & Wang, J. (2018). When is it hard to make ends meet?’ Unpublished.

  • Benjamin, D., Brown, S., & Shapiro, J. (2013). Who is “Behavioral’’? Cognitive ability and anomalous preferences. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(6), 1231–1255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernheim, B. D., Ray, D., & Yeltekin, Ş. (2015). Poverty and self-control. Econometrica, 83(5), 1877–1911.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., & Morse, A. (2011). Information disclosure, cognitive biases, and payday borrowing. Journal of Finance, 66(6), 1865–1893.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Mullainathan, S., & Shafir, E. (2004). A behavioral-economics view of poverty. American Economic Review, 94(2), 419–423.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beshears, J., Choi, J. J., Harris, C., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Sakong, J. (2020). Which early withdrawal penalty attracts the most deposits to a commitment savings account? Journal of Public Economics, 183, 104144.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhutta, N., Skiba, P. M., & Tobacman, J. (2015). Payday loan choices and consequences. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 47(2–3), 223–260.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bilias, Y., Georgarakos, D., & Haliassos, M. (2010). Portfolio inertia and stock market fluctuations. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(4), 715–742.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, S. E., Devereux, P. J., Lundborg, P., & Majlesi, K. (2018). Learning to take risks? The effect of education on risk-taking in financial markets. Review of Finance, 22(3), 951–975.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bos, M., Carter, S., & Skiba, P. (2012). The Pawn Industry and Its Customers: The United States and Europe. Vanderbilt Law and Economics Research Paper, pp. 12–26.

  • Bos, M., Carter, S., & Skiba, P. (2015). Balancing act: New evidence and a discussion of the theory on the rationality and behavioral anomalies of choice in credit markets. In T. C. Teitelbaum & K. Zeiler (Eds.), Research handbook in behavioral law and economics. Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, M., Grigsby, J., Van Der Klaauw, W., Wen, J., & Zafar, B. (2016). Financial education and the debt behavior of the young. The Review of Financial Studies, 29(9), 2490–2522.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M., & Parker, J. (2005). Optimal expectations. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1092–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., & Sodini, P. (2007). Down or out: Assessing the welfare costs of household investment mistakes. Journal of Political Economy, 115(5), 707–747.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calvet, L. E., Campbell, J. Y., & Sodini, P. (2009). Measuring the financial sophistication of households. American Economic Review, 99(2), 393–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, J. Y. (2006). Household finance. The Journal of Finance, 61(4), 1553–1604.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho, L., Meier, S., & Wang, S. (2016). Poverty and economic decision making: Evidence from changes in financial resources at payday. American Economic Review, 106(2), 260–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dalton, P. S., Ghosal, S., & Mani, A. (2016). Poverty and aspirations failure. The Economic Journal, 126(590), 165–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S., & Malmendier, U. (2004). Contract design and self-control: Theory and evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 353–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhar, R., & Zhu, N. (2006). Up close and personal: Investor sophistication and the disposition effect. Management Science, 52(5), 726–740.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E. (2002). Behavioural science: The economics of impatience. Nature, 415(6869), 269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gabaix, X., & Laibson, D.. (2017). Myopia and discounting.’ NBER Working Paper 23254.

  • Gabaix, X., & Laibson, D. (2006). Shrouded attributes, consumer myopia, and information suppression in competitive markets. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 505–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goetzmann, W. N., & Kumar, A. (2008). Equity portfolio diversification. Review of Finance, 12(3), 433–463.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, C., & Laibson, D. (2001). Dynamic choices of hyperbolic consumers. Econometrica, 69(4), 935–957.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hastings, J. S., Madrian, B. C., & Skimmyhorn, W. L. (2013). Financial literacy, financial education, and economic outcomes. Annual Review of Economics, 5(1), 347–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haushofer, J., & Fehr, E. (2019). Negative income shocks increase discount rates. University of Zurich Working Paper.

  • Heidhues, P., & Kőszegi, B. (2010). Exploiting Naïvete about self-control in the credit market. American Economic Review, 100(5), 2279–2303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huffman, D., & Barenstein, M. (2005). A Monthly struggle for self-control? Hyperbolic discounting, mental accounting, and the fall in consumption expenditures between paydays. IZA Discussion Paper 430.

  • Karlan, D., McConnell, M., Mullainathan, S., & Zinman, J. (2016). Getting to the top of mind: How reminders increase saving. Management Science, 62(12), 3393–3411.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kőszegi, B. (2014). Behavioral contract theory. Journal of Economic Literature, 52(4), 1075–1118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuchler, T., & Pagel, M. (2018). Sticking to your plan: empirical evidence on the role of present bias for credit card debt paydown. NBER Working paper 24881.

  • Kuchler, T., & Pagel, M. (2021). Sticking to your plan: The role of present bias for credit card paydown. Journal of Financial Economics, 139, 359–388.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D. (1997). Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(2), 443–478.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, D., Repetto, A., & Tobacman, J. (2003). A debt puzzle. In P. Aghion, J. Frydman, & M. Woodford (Eds.), Knowledge, information, and expectations in modern economics: honor of Edmund S Phelps (pp. 228–266). Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leary, J., & Wang, J. (2016). Liquidity constraints and budgeting mistakes: Evidence from social security recipients. Unpublished.

  • Mani, A., Mullainathan, S., Shafir, E., & Zhao, J. (2013). Poverty impedes cognitive function. Science, 341(6149), 976–980.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mastrobuoni, G., & Weinberg, M. (2009). Heterogeneity in intra-monthly consumption patterns, self-control, and savings at retirement. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 1(2), 163–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, S., & Sprenger, C. D. (2010). Present-biased preferences and credit card borrowing. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2(1), 193–210.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melzer, B. (2011). The real costs of credit access: Evidence from the payday lending market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(1), 517–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morse, A. (2011). Payday lenders: Heroes or villains? Journal of Financial Economics, 102(1), 28–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Donoghue, T., & Rabin, M. (1999). Doing It now or later. American Economic Review, 89(1), 103–124.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, C. A., & Van Wesep, E. D. (2013). The timing of pay. Journal of Financial Economics, 109(2), 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps, E., & Pollak, R. (1968). On second-best national saving and game-equilibrium growth. Review of Economic Studies, 35(2), 185–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ru, H., & Schoar, A. (2016). Do credit card companies screen for behavioral biases? NBER Working Paper 22360.

  • Schilbach, F., Schofield, H., & Mullainathan, S. (2016). The psychological lives of the poor. American Economic Review, 106(5), 435–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shah, A., Mullainathan, S., & Shafir, E. (2012). Some consequences of having too little. Science, 338(6107), 682–685.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, J. (2005). Is there a daily discount rate? Evidence from the food stamp nutrition cycle. Journal of Public Economics, 89(2–3), 303–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sims, C. (2003). Implications of rational inattention. Journal of Monetary Economics, 50(3), 665–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skiba, P. M., & Tobacman, J. (2008). Payday loans, uncertainty and discounting: Explaining patterns of borrowing, repayment, and default (August 21, 2008). Vanderbilt Law and Economics Research Paper No. 08-33, Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1319751 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1319751.

  • Stango, V., & Zinman, J. (2014). Limited and varying consumer attention evidence from shocks to the salience of bank overdraft fees. Review of Financial Studies, 27(4), 990–1030.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephens, M. (2003). “3rd of the month’’: Do social security recipients smooth consumption between checks? American Economic Review, 93(1), 406–422.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephens, M. (2006). Paycheque receipt and the timing of consumption. Economic Journal, 116(513), 680–701.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka, T., Camerer, C., & Nguyen, Q. (2010). Risk and time preferences: Linking experimental and household survey data from vietnam. American Economic Review, 100(1), 557–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urban, C., Maximilian S., Michael Collins, J., & Brown, A. (2020). The effects of high school personal financial education policies on financial behavior. Economics of Education Review. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econedurev.2018.03.006.

  • Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2002). Towards an explanation of household portfolio choice heterogeneity: Nonfinancial income and participation cost structures. National Bureau of Economic Research: Tech. rep.

  • Zinman, J. (2010). Restricting consumer credit access: Household survey evidence on effects around the oregon rate cap. Journal of Banking and Finance, 34(3), 546–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chloé Le Coq.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank Renee Adams, Bob Hunt, Leandro Carvalho, Cristina Cella, Ronel Elul, Daria Finocchiaro, Andrew Hertzberg, Alexander Ljungqvist, Leonard Nakamura, Farzad Saidi, Erik von Schedvin, Giancarlo Spagnolo and Per Strömberg, Ferdinand Vieider (editor), two anonymous referees and numerous seminar and conference participants for helpful comments. Jesper Böjeryd provided excellent research assistance. All errors are our own. Funding from VINNOVA is gratefully acknowledged.

Supplementary Information

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (PDF 529 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bos, M., Le Coq, C. & van Santen, P. Scarcity and consumers’ credit choices. Theory Decis 92, 105–139 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-021-09815-2

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-021-09815-2

Keywords

Navigation