Skip to main content
Log in

Choosing international organizations: When do states and the World Bank collaborate on environmental projects?

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While international cooperation research emphasizes institutional design, states mostly interact with existing organizations. How do states choose organizations for cooperation? We develop a theory of agency choice for development projects, emphasizing the importance of domestic institutions, the scope of cooperation, and the resources of the implementing agency. If states are to cooperate with funding agencies that have abundant resources, such as the World Bank, they must accept more stringent conditions on project implementation. We argue states accept the stringent conditions that resourceful organizations demand if the public goods from project implementation are highly valuable. Empirically, this is the case for democratic states, large projects, and projects that produce national instead of global public goods. We test this theory using data on 2,882 Global Environment Facility (GEF) projects, 1991–2011. The GEF offers an ideal case because various implementing agencies are responsible for the actual projects. States implement projects in collaboration with the World Bank, which has the most expertise and resources among the GEF’s implementing agencies, if their regime type is democracy, the project size is large, and the benefits are primarily national. Qualitative evidence sheds light on causal mechanisms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Originally, all GEF projects were implemented by one or a combination of three executing agencies: the UNDP, the United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP), and the WB. As of 2012, there are ten such agencies, including a number of additional UN agencies and regional development banks.

  2. Based on a coding of 50 random GEF projects, we ascertain in the Online Appendix available on the journal’s webpage that GEF agencies contribute on average about 19 % of project funds, confirming that financial resources are one of the most important contributions that funding agencies bring to the table. Funding from other sources, such as private capital (12 %), NGOs (2 %), or other concessionary, non-recipient funding (5 %), is more limited.

  3. See http://www.thegef.org/gef/project_detail?projID=2903. Accessed on May 3, 2013.

  4. This database is available online at http://www.gefonline.org.

  5. Occasionally, an additional agency is assigned to assist implementation. The GEF’s description of comparative advantages suggests that policy intervention is important in selecting a primary agency; focal area expertise, where it exists, is listed second.

  6. Available online at http://www.aiddata.org/content/index/Research/research-datasets.

  7. In terms of AidData Environment, our indicator is set to 1 if a project is coded either “environmental strictly defined — green” or “environmental broadly defined — green.” Our indicator is set to 0 if a project is coded “environmental strictly defined — brown,” “environmental broadly defined — brown,” “neutral,” “dirty strictly defined,” or “dirty broadly defined.”

  8. In checking the robustness of our results, we also estimate random effects probit regressions. Our findings are robust to this specification; we present complete results in the Online Appendix.

  9. As Fig. 1 shows, while partnering with the UNDP has been consistently less costly than cooperating with the WB, the difference shrank somewhat following the GEF’s adoption of the RAF.

  10. We estimate both standard OLS and weighted regressions modeling each country’s variance as the inverse of the number of GEF projects. Both robustness tests validate the hypotheses.

  11. Multiplicative interaction effects are not necessarily needed in non-linear models to account for non-linear effects. As suggested by Berry et al. (2010) we implemented likelihood ratio tests to check if the inclusion of interaction effects is warranted. Further details can be found in the Online Appendix.

  12. The interview questionnaire and additional details on the interview process can be found in the Online Appendix.

  13. For 1,000 draws from a multivariate normal based on model (1), we find a mean effect of -9 percentage points (-3 and -14 percentage points as lower and upper confidence bounds, respectively) for a change from local to global public goods. The mean effect for increases in total project costs by one standard deviation above the mean is 17 percentage points, with 12 and 23 percentage points as the lower and upper end of the 95 % confidence interval. The substantive effects for a change from an autocratic to a democratic regime type are weakest in absolute value, with an average increase of only 4 percentage points and a confidence interval ranging from 1 to 8 percentage points.

References

  • Ai, C., & Norton, E.C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbut, M. (2012). Telephone interview with the CEO of the Global Environment Facility. September 2012.

  • Barrett, S. (2003). Environment and statecraft: the strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bayer, P., Marcoux, C., Urpelainen, J. (2013). Leveraging private capital for climate mitigation: evidence from the Clean Development Mechanism. Ecological Economics, 96, 14–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry, W.D., DeMeritt, J.H.R., Esarey, J. (2010). Testing for interaction in binary logit and probit models: is a product term essential?American Journal of Political Science, 54(1), 248–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brambor, T., Clark, W.R., Golder, M. (2006). Understanding interaction models: improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R.M., Morrow, J.D. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busch, M.L. (2007). Overlapping institutions, forum shopping, and dispute settlement in international trade. International Organization, 61(4), 735–761.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carter, D.B., & Signorino, C.S. (2010). Back to the future: modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., Vreeland, J. R. (2010). Democracy and dictatorship revisited. Public Choice, 143(1-2), 67–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clémençon, R. (2006). What future for the Global Environment Facility? Journal of Environment and Development, 15(1), 50–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R.A. (1967). Pluralist democracy in the United States: conflict and consent. Chicago: Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A. (2009). IMF conditionality: theory and evidence. Public Choice, 141(1–2), 233–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dreher, A., Sturm, J.-E., Vreeland, J.R. (2009). Development aid and international politics: does membership on the UN Security Council influence World Bank decisions? Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fleck, R.K., & Kilby, C. (2006). World Bank independence: a model and statistical analysis of US influence. Review of Development Economics, 10(2), 224–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • GEF (2007). Comparative advantages of the GEF agencies. http://www.thegef.org/gef/node/427. Accessed 30 Sept 2012.

  • Grossman, G.M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helfer, L.R. (2004). Regime shifting: the TRIPs agreement and new dynamics of international intellectual property lawmaking. Yale Journal of International Law, 29, 1–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, R.L., Parks, B.C., Roberts, J.T., Tierney, M.J. (2008). Greening aid? understanding the environmental impact of development assistance. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann, S.C. (2011). Why institutional overlap matters: CSDP in the European security architecture. Journal of Common Market Studies, 49(1), 101–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, C., & Michaelowa, K. (2013). Shopping for development: multilateral lending, shareholder composition and borrower preferences. World Development, 44, 142–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, T., & Urpelainen, J. (2012). A strategic theory of regime integration and separation. International Organization, 66(4), 645–677.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jupille, J., Mattli, W., Snidal, D. (2013). Institutional choice in global commerce. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jupille, J., & Snidal, D. (2006). The choice of international institutions: cooperation alternatives and strategies. Working Paper, University of Colorado at Boulder and University of Chicago.

  • Kaja, A., & Werker, E. (2010). Corporate governance at the World Bank and the dilemma of global governance. World Bank Economic Review, 24(2), 171–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, R.O., & Victor, D.G. (2011). The regime complex for climate change. Perspectives on Politics, 9(1), 7–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kilby, C. (2009). The political economy of conditionality: an empirical analysis of World Bank loan disbursements. Journal of Development Economics, 89(1), 51–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, G., Tomz, M., Wittenberg, J. (2000). Making the most of statistical analyses: improving interpretation and presentation. American Journal of Political Science, 44(2), 341–355.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyne, M.M., Nielson, D.L., Tierney, M.J. (2009). Controlling coalitions: social lending at the multilateral development banks. Review of International Organizations, 4(4), 407–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J.W., Boli, J., Thomas, G.M., Ramirez, F.O. (1997). World society and the nation-state. American Journal of Sociology, 103(1), 144–181.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H.V. (2006). Why multilateralism? foreign aid and domestic principal-agent problems. In D.G. Hawkins, D.A. Lake, D.L. Nielson, M.J. Tierney (Eds.), Delegation and agency in international organizations. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nielson, D.L., & Tierney, M.J. (2003). Delegation to international organizations: agency theory and World Bank Environmental Reform. International Organization, 57(2), 241–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations: economic growth, stagflation, and social rigidities. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pevehouse, J., Nordstrom, T., Warnke, K. (2004). The Correlates of War 2 international governmental organizations data version 2.0. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 21(2), 101–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1995). Why is there multilateral lending? NBER Working Paper 5160.

  • Sharma, S.D. (1996). Building effective international environmental regimes: the case of the Global Environment Facility. Journal of Environment and Development, 5(1), 73–86.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G.J. (1972). Economic competition and political competition. Public Choice, 13(1), 91–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R.W. (2008). The scope of IMF conditionality. International Organization, 62(4), 589–620.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone, R.W. (2011). Controlling institutions: international organizations and the global economy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sykes, A.O. (2008). Transnational forum shopping as a trade and investment issue. Journal of Legal Studies, 37(2), 339–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tendler, J. (1975). Inside foreign aid. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Truman, D. (1951). The governmental process: political interests and public opinion. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vreeland, J.R. (2003). The IMF and economic development. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Winters, M.S. (2010). Choosing to target: what types of countries get different types of World Bank projects. World Politics, 62(3), 422–458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D.A. (1995). The myth of democratic failure: why political institutions are efficient. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2006). Policy conditions in World Bank investment lending. Operations Policy and Country Services. http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB/2006/08/03/000090341_20060803094631/Rendered/PDF/36924.pdf. Accessed 30 Sept 2012.

Download references

Acknowledgments

An earlier version of this paper was presented at the 6th Political Economy of International Organizations Conference, held at the Universities of Mannheim and Heidelberg, February 7–9, 2013. We thank all conference participants for their comments and are particularly indebted to Katharina Michaelowa, Ulrich Wagner, Axel Dreher, and three anonymous reviewers for their helpful feedback.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johannes Urpelainen.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 286 KB)

(ZIP 232 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Bayer, P., Marcoux, C. & Urpelainen, J. Choosing international organizations: When do states and the World Bank collaborate on environmental projects?. Rev Int Organ 9, 413–440 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-013-9184-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-013-9184-y

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation