Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Enduring trade disputes: Disguised protectionism and duration and recurrence of international trade disputes

  • Published:
The Review of International Organizations Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Why do some WTO trade disputes endure and recur while others do not? States have difficulty resolving trade conflicts when they involve certain types of trade-restrictive domestic regulations. While such regulations vary in their extent of legitimacy—fulfilling non-trade domestic regulatory objectives and availability of less trade-restrictive options—complainant states cannot always distinguish legitimate barriers from illegitimate ones. In such scenarios of disguised protectionism, which I argue is most prevalent with policies involving WTO’s Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) Agreement, disputants confront difficulties concluding their disputes. Disputes last longer and are more likely to recur. I test the argument against a data set of WTO disputes structured in an innovative manner—one that links together related and recurring disputes into single conflicts. Both an event history analysis of conflict duration and a count analysis of conflict recurrence using this data strongly support this argument.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Leitner and Lester (2015) and the preceding annual pieces for descriptive summaries of trade disputes at the WTO.

  2. “China–U.S. Trade Dispute Has Broad Implications,” The New York Times, September 15, 2009.

  3. I thank Leslie Johns for suggesting this framework for casting the two types. The formulation is also similar to Carrubba (2005), in which two countries have different costs to compliance.

  4. The existence of alternative policies that are multilaterally more acceptable as a component of legitimacy is similar to Pelc (2010).

  5. Alternatively, the complainants’ discount factor can be specified so that they choose to settle now rather than engage in a drawn-out bargaining against the sincere type.

  6. A contrasting approach would be to have different time horizons and discount values for the bargainers (e.g., Cramton 1984).

  7. The parameter that captures the uncertainty in Grossman and Perry (1986b) is a probability distribution F(r) bounded by r l , a low reservation value assessment of the respondent type by the complainant and r h , a high reservation value. The information precision is decreasing in the distance between the bounds.

  8. “Understanding the WTO Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures.” World Trade Organization (WTO). https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/sps_e/spsund_e.htm. Accessed May 12, 2015.

  9. Accordingly, this is different from Bown and Reynolds (2015), who identify common disputes based on repeating patterns of complainant-disputed policy.

  10. The results of these robustness checks are available on the journal’s website.

  11. http://www.wto.org/english/tratope/dispue/dispustatuse.htm. Accessed September 11, 2014.

  12. The results of these robustness checks are available on the journal’s website.

  13. For the EU, the rounded average Polity score among the evolving membership does not fall below 10.

  14. An alternative approach would track changes in respondents’ policy, which can mark the start of a conflict a la Bown and Reynolds (2015).

  15. TRIMs has the lowest maximum number of provisions cited—4—and the fewest cases of positive counts.

References

  • Allee, T. (2004). Legal incentives and domestic rewards: The selection of trade disputes for GATT/WTO dispute resolution.

  • Allee, T. (2005). The political and economic value of GATT/WTO dispute initiation. In In 2005 annual meeting of the american political science association. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allee, T. L., & Huth, P. K. (2006). Legitimizing dispute settlement: international legal rulings as dometic political cover. American Political Science Review, 100(2), 219–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barton, J., et al. (2006). The evolution of the trade regime: Politics, law and economics of the GATT and WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beaulieu, E., & Gaisford, J. (2002). Labour and environmental standards: the ‘lemons problem’ in international trade policy. World Economy, 25(1), 59–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechtel, M. M., & Sattler, T. (2015). What is litigation in the world trade organization worth? International Organization.

  • Bernauer, T. (2003). Genes, trade, and regulation: The seeds of conflict in food biotechnology. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bown, C. P. (2004). On the economic success of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3), 811–823.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bown, C. P., & Reynolds, K. M. (2014). Trade flows and trade disputes. Washington, DC: World Bank Development Research Group. Policy Research Working Paper.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bown, C. P., & Reynolds, K. M. (2015). Trade agreements and enforcement: Evidence from WTO dispute settlement. Washington, DC: World Bank Group—Development Research Group—Trade; International Integration Team. Policy Research Working Paper.

  • Bureau, J. C., Marette, S., & Schiavina, A. (1998). Non-tariff trade barriers and consumers’ information: the case of the EU-US trade dispute over beef. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 25(4), 437–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Busch, M. L., & Pelc, K. J. (2010). The politics of judicial economy at the world trade organization. International Organization, 64(2), 257–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Bargaining in the shadow of the law: early settlement in GATT/WTO disputes. Fordham International Law Journal, 24(1–2), 158–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2002). Testing international trade law: Empirical studies of GATT/WTO dispute settlement. In D. L. M. Kennedy & J. D. Southwick (Eds.), The political economy of international trade law: Essays in honor of robert e. hudec (pp. 457–481). New York: Cambridge University Press.

  • Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Developing countries and general agreement on tariffs and trade/World trade organization dispute settlement. Journal of World Trade, 37(4), 719–735.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2006). Three’s a crowd: third parties and WTO dispute settlement. World Politics, 58(3), 446–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carrubba, C. J. (2005). Courts and compliance in international regulatory regimes. Journal of Politics, 67(3), 669–689.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudoin, S. (2014). Audiences features and the strategic timing of trade disputes. International Organization, 68(1), 1–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudoin, S., Kucik, J., & Pelc, K. J. (2013). Do WTO disputes actually increase trade?

  • Cleves, M. et al. (2008). An introduction to survival analysis using stata. Second. Stata Press.

  • Cramton, P. C. (1984). Bargaining with incomplete information: an infinite-horizon model with two-sided uncertainty. Review of Economic Studies, 51(4), 579–593.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, C. L. (2012). Why adjudicate? Enforcing trade rules in the WTO. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, C. L., & Bermeo, S. B. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. Journal of Politics, 71(3), 1033–1049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis, C. & Shirato, Y. (2007). Firms, governments, and WTO adjudication. 59(2): 274–313.

  • Elsig, M., & Stucki, P. (2012). Low-income developing countries and WTO litigation. 19(2), 292–316.

  • Esty, D. C. (1994). Greening the GATT: Trade, environment, and the future. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esty, D. (2002). Rejoinder. World Trade Review, 1(3), 297–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fattore, C. (2013). The influence of legal capacity on WTO dispute duration. International Trade Journal, 27(5), 450–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, J. L., & Steinberg, R. H. (2009). Regulatory shift: The rise of judicial liberalization at the WTO. In W. Mattli & N. Woods (Eds.), The politics of global regulation (pp. 211–241). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinols, E. L., & Perrelli, R. (2006). The WTO impact on international trade disputes: an event history analysis. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(4), 613–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Perry, M. (1986a). Perfect sequential equilibrium. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 97–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Perry, M. (1986b). Sequential bargaining under asymmetric information. Journal of Economic Theory, 39(1), 120–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. A. (2002). To settle or empanel? An empirical analysis of litigation and settlement at the world trade organization. Journal of Legal Studies, 31(1), S205–S235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guzman, A. T., & Simmons, B. A. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: the selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34(2), 557–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hobbs, J. E., Kerr, W. A., & Phillips, P. W. B. (2001). Identity preservation and international trade: signaling quality across national boundaries. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics, 49(4), 567–579.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hofmann, T., & Kim, S. Y. (2010). The domestic politics of compliance: Explaining time-to-compliance in WTO disputes. In In Annual meeting of the american political science association. Washington, DC: American Political Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, H. & Mavroidis, P. C. (2013.) The WTO dispute settlement data set 1995–2011: User’s guide. 3.0.

  • Hudec, R. E. (1993). Enforcing international trade law: The evolution of the modern GATT legal system. Salem: Butterworth Legal Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johns, L. & Pelc, K. J. (2014). Fear of crowds in WTO disputes: Why don’t more countries participate?

  • Kerr, W. A. (1999). International trade in transgenic food products: a new focus for agricultural trade disputes. World Economy, 22(2), 245–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, M. (2008). Costly procedures: divergent effects of legalization in the GATT/WTO dispute settlement procedures. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3), 657–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, M. (2012). Disguised protectionism and linkages to the GATT/WTO. World Politics, 64(3), 426–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kono, D. Y. (2006). Optimal obfuscation: democracy and trade policy transparency. American Political Science Review, 100(3), 369–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kucik, J., & Pelc, K. J. Forthcoming. Measuring the cost of privacy: A look at the distributional effects of private bargaining. British Journal of Political Science.

  • Lawrence, R. Z. (2007). The united states and the WTO dispute settlement system. Washington, DC: Council on Foreign Relations. Council Special Reports.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leitner, K., & Lester, S. (2015). WTO dispute settlement 1995–2014: a statistical analysis. Journal of International Economic Law, 18(1), 203–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Licht, A. A. (2011). Change comes with time: substantive interpretation of nonproportional hazards in event history analysis. Political Analysis, 19(2), 227–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. D., & Reinhardt, E. (2003). Multilateral determinants of regionalism: the effects of GATT/WTO on the formation of preferential trading arrangements. International Organization, 57(4), 829–862.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Márquez Peña, J. (2014). MoreClarify: Stata module to estimate quantities of interest through simulation and resampling methods.

  • Marshall, M. G., & Gurr, T. R. Polity IV project: Political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2012.

  • Pelc, K. J. (2009). Seeking escape: the use of escape clauses in international trade agreements. International Studies Quarterly, 53(2), 349–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pelc, K. J. (2010). Constraining coercion? Legitimacy and its role in U.S. trade policy, 1975–2000. International Organization, 64(1), 65–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pelc, K. J. (2014). The politics of precedent in international law: a social network application. American Political Science Review, 108(3), 547–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pervez, F. (2014a). Elections and dropped WTO trade disputes.

  • Pervez, F. (2015). Waiting for election season: the timing of international trade disputes. Review of International Organizations.

  • Pollack, M. A., & Shaffer, G. C. (2009). When cooperation fails: The international law and politics of genetically modified foods. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of 2-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhardt, E. (2001). Adjudication without enforcement in GATT disputes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(4), 174–195.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reynolds, K. M. (2009). Why are so many WTO disputes abandoned? In J. C. Hartigan (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO (pp. 191–211). Bingley: Emerald Group Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik, D. (1997). Has globalization gone too far? Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosendorff, B. P. (2005). Stability and rigidity: politics and design of the WTO’s dispute settlement procedure. American Political Science Review, 99(3), 389–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rossmiller, G. E. (1994). Discussion. In Agricultural trade conflicts and GATT, eds. Giovanni Anania, Colin A. Carter, and Alex F. McCalla. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, p. 262–265.

  • Rubinstein, A. (1982). Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica, 50(1), 97–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubinstein, A. (1985). A bargaining model with incomplete information about time preferences. Econometrica, 53(5), 1151–1172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, G. (2003). How to make the WTO dispute settlement system work for developing countries: Some proactive developing country strategies. Geneva, Switzerland: International Centre for Trade; Sustainable Development (ICTSD). ICTSD Resource Paper.

  • World Bank. World development indicators.

Download references

Acknowledgments

The research for this article was generously supported by the Colorado European Union Center of Excellence (CEUCE) and the Center to Advance Research and Teaching in the Social Sciences (CARTSS) at the University of Colorado at Boulder. Earlier versions of this article were presented at the 2011 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, the Institutions Group of the Institute of Behavioral Science (IBS) at the University of Colorado at Boulder, and Governance and Conflicts Workshop sponsored by CU Political Science and One Earth Foundation. I amgrateful for comments I received at these venues. I would like to especially thank David Bearce, Carew Boulding, David Brown, Julia Gray, Bobby Gulotty, Johannes Karreth, Soo Yeon Kim and Sarah Sokhey for helpful comments. Cliff Carrubba and Leslie Johns provided useful guidance on specifying the bargaining model portion of the argument. Jeff Kucik and Krzysztof Pelc provided me the trade data for WTO disputes. Chris Cyr and Megan Roosevelt provided valuable research assistance for the project. Lastly, two anonymous reviewers patiently encouraged me along through major revisions of the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Moonhawk Kim.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

ESM 1

(PDF 201 kb)

ESM 2

(ZIP 352 kb)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kim, M. Enduring trade disputes: Disguised protectionism and duration and recurrence of international trade disputes. Rev Int Organ 11, 283–310 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-015-9230-z

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-015-9230-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation