Skip to main content
Log in

Why do suppliers choose wholesale price contracts? End-of-season payments disincentivize retailer marketing effort

  • Original Empirical Research
  • Published:
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Although theoretical work has shown that end-of-season payment contracts, which allow suppliers and retailers to share the cost of unsold inventory, increase total profit, most suppliers and retailers today still use simple wholesale price contracts. In a series of experimental studies, we show that supplier preferences for wholesale price contracts can be explained by their concern that end-of-season payments contracts will disincentivize retailer marketing effort. Moreover, suppliers’ pessimistic predictions regarding reduced retailer effort are confirmed by retailers’ reduced investment in marketing effort in our experiments. Our results suggest that for suppliers and retailers to benefit from end-of-season payments contracts, retailers should publicize their demand-enhancing marketing practices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aiken, D. K., & Boush, D. M. (2006). Trustmakers, objective-source ratings, and implied investments in advertising; investigating online trust and the context-specific nature of internet signals. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 34(3), 308–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arya, A., & Mittendorf, B. (2004). Using returns policies to elicit retailer information. RAND Journal of Economics, 35(3), 617–630.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Associated Press (2005). Apparel suppliers, retailer at odds. Associated Press. http://www.nbcnews.com/id/7592508/#.VbCBtvlViko. Accessed 24 April 2005.

  • Bagwell, K., & Riordan, M. H. (1991). High and declining prices signal product quality. American Economic Review, 81, 224–239.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, G. (2002). Distortion and risk in incentive contracts. Journal of Human Resources, 37, 728–751.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bandyopadhyay, S., & Paul, A. A. (2010). Equilibrium returns policies in the presence of supplier competition. Marketing Science, 846–857.

  • Becker-Peth, M., Katok, E., & Thonemann, U. (2014). Designing buyback contracts for irrational but predictable newsvendors. Management Science, 59(8), 1800–1816.

  • Boulding, W., & Kirmani, A. (1993). A consumer-side experimental examination of signaling theory: Do consumers perceive warranties as signals of quality? Journal of Consumer Research, 20, 111–123.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruner II, Gordon C. (2013). Marketing Scales Handbook: Multi-item Measures For Consumer Insight Research, Vol 7. GCBII Productions, LLC: Fort Worth.

  • Byron, E. (2005). Saks sued again for withholding markdown money. The Wall Street Journal, B4, 8.

  • Cachon, G. P. (2003). Supply chain coordination with contracts. In A.G. de Kok and S.C. Graves (Eds.), Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, Vol 11. Amsterdam: North Holland.

  • Cachon, G. P. (2006). You say channels, I say supply chains: Shall we get it on, or call the whole thing off? Working paper. The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania.

  • Collier, J. E., & Sherrell, D. L. (2010). Examining the influence of control and convenience in a self-service setting. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 38(4), 490–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Croson, R. & Karen, D. (2002). Experimental economics and supply chain management. Interfaces, 32(5), 74–82.

  • Croson, R., Kenneth, S., Enno, S., & Lisa Yeo, M. (2013). Behavioral operations: The state of the field. Journal of Operations Management, 31(1–2), 1–5.

  • Davis, A., & Leider S. (2015). Contracts and capacity investment in supply chains. Working Paper, Cornell University.

  • Design Council of the UK (2008). Measuring return on investment in design (ROI). www.designcouncil.org.uk/our-work/Insight/Research/How-businesses-use-design/Design-in-Britain-2008/Measuring-ROI-in-design/

  • Emmons, H., & Gilbert, S. M. (1998). The role of returns policies in pricing and inventory decisions for catalogue goods. Management Science, 44(2), 276–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fagerlin, A., Zikmund-Fisher, B. J., Ubdel, P. A., Jankovic, A., Derry, H. A., & Smith, D. M. (2007). Measuring numeracy without math test: Development of the subjective numeracy scale. Medical Decision Making, 27(5), 672–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E. and Gatcher, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation: the economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3), 159–181.

  • Franco-Watkins, A., Edwards, B. D., & Acuff, R. E. (2013). Effort and fairness in bargaining games. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 26, 79–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frazier, G. L. (1999). Managing channels of distribution. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 27(2), 226–240.

  • Gibbons, R. (1998). Incentives in organizations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(4), 115–132.

  • Gilliland, D., & Kim, S. (2014). When do incentives work in channels of distribution? Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 42, 361–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granot, D., & Yin, S. (2005). On the effectiveness of returns policies in the price-dependent newsvendor model. Naval Research Logistics, 52(8), 765–779.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregoire, Y., Laufer, D., & Tripp, T. M. (2010). A comprehensive model of customer direct and indirect revenge: Understanding the effects of perceived greed and customer power. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 38(6), 738–758.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gumus, M., Ray, S., & Yin, S. (2013). Channel returns policies between channel partners for durable products. Marketing Science, 32(4), 622–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurnani, H., & Erkoc, M. (2008). Supply contracts in manufacturer-retailer interactions with manufacturer-quality and retailer effort-induced demand. Naval Research Logistics, 55(3), 200–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gurnani, H., Sharma, A., & Grewal, D. (2010). Optimal returns policies under demand uncertainty. Journal of Retailing, 86(2), 137–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • He, Y., Zhao, X., Zhao, L., & He, J. (2009). Coordinating a supply chain with effort and price dependent stochastic demand. Applied Mathematical Modeling, 33, 2777–2790.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ho, T.-H., & Zhang, J. (2008). Designing price contracts for boundedly rational customers: Does the framing of the fixed fee matter? Management Science, 54(4), 686–700.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holstrom, B. & Paul, M. (1991). Multitask principal-agent analyses: Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 24–52.

  • Iyer, G., & Miguel Villas-Boas, J. (2003). A bargaining theory of distribution channels. Journal of Marketing Research, 40(1), 80–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kandel, E. (1996). The right to return. Journal of Law and Economics, 39(1), 329–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kashyap, V., Antia, K. D., & Frazier, G. F. (2012). Contracts, extracontractual incentives, and ex post behavior in franchise channel relationships. Journal of Marketing Research, 49(2), 260–276.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Katok, E. (2011). Laboratory experiments in operations management. In J. Geunes (Ed.), TutORials in operations research (pp. 15–35). Hanover: INFORMS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katok, E., & Wu, D. (2009). Contracting in supply chains: A laboratory investigation. Management Science, 55(12), 1953–1968.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keser, C., & Paleologo, G. A. (2004). Experimental investigation of supplier-retailer contracts: The wholesale price contract, Working Paper, IBM T. Yorktown Heights: J. Watson Research Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirmani, A., & Wright, P. (1989). Money talks: Perceived advertising expense and expected product quality. Journal of Consumer Research, 16(3), 344–353.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kozlenkova, I. V., Samaha, S. A., & Palmatier, R. W. (2014). Resource-based theory in marketing. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 42, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishnan, H., Kapuscinski, R., & Butz, D. A. (2004). Coordinating contracts for decentralized supply chains with retailer promotional effort. Management Science, 50(1), 48–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kugler, T., Connolly, T., & Kausel, E. (2009). The effect of consequential thinking on trust game behavior. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 22, 101–119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy, M., & Weitz, B. A. (2009). Retailing Management (7th ed.). Burr Ridge: Irwin/McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, R. A., & Reiley, D. Jr (2011). Does retail advertising work? Measuring the effects of advertising on sales via a controlled experiment on yahoo! Working paper, yahoo! Research.

  • Lim, N., & Ho, T.-H. (2007). Designing price contracts for boundedly rational customers: Does the number of blocks matter? Management Science, 26(3), 312–326.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., Su, C., Li, Y., & Liu, T. (2010). Managing opportunism in a developing interfirm relationship: The interrelationship of calculative and loyalty. Industrial Marketing Management, 39(5), 844–852.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lusch, R. F., & Brown, J. R. (1996). Interdependency, contracting, and relational behavior in marketing channels. Journal of Marketing, 60, 19–38.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mantrala, M. K., & Raman, K. (1999). Demand uncertainty and supplier’s returns policies for a multi-store style good retailer. European Journal of Operational Research, 115(2), 270–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, W. S., & Collins, B. H. (1991). Interactive video technology in sales training: A case study. The Journal of Personal Selling and Sales Management, 11(3), 61–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marvel, H. P., & Peck, J. (1995). Demand uncertainty and returns policies. International Economic Review, 36(3), 691–714.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marvel, H. P., & Wang, H. (2007). Inventories, manufacturer returns policies, and equilibrium price dispersion. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 6(4), 1031–1051.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mooi, E. A., & Ghosh, M. (2010). Contract specificity and its performance implications. Journal of Marketing, 74, 105–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morales, A. C. (2005). Giving firms an “E” for effort: Consumer responses to high effort firms. Journal of Consumer Research, 31(4), 806–812.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mukhopadhyay, S. R., Xuemei, S., & Ghose, S. (2009). Motivating retail marketing effort: Optimal contract design. Production and Operations Management, 18(2), 197–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padmanabhan, V., & Png, I. P. L. (1997). Manufacturer’s returns policies and retail competition. Marketing Science, 16(1), 81–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Padmanabhan, V., & Png, I. P. L. (2004). Reply to do returns policies intensify retail competition. Marketing Science, 23(4), 614–618.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pasternack, B. A. (1985). Optimal pricing and returns policies for perishable commodities. Marketing Science, 4(2), 166–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rokkan, A. I., Heide, J. B., & Wathne, K. H. (2003). Specific investments in marketing relationships: Expropriation and bonding effects. Journal of Marketing Research, 40(2), 210–224.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozhon, T. (2005). First the markdown, then the showdown. The New York Times, February 25, 2005.

  • Sarvary, M., & Padmanabhan, V. (2001). The informational role of manufacturer returns policies: How they can help in learning the demand. Marketing Letters, 12(4), 341–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shen, B., Chow, P.-S., & Choi, T.-M. (2014). Supply chain contracts in fashion department stores: Coordination and risk analysis. Mathematical Problems in Engineering, 1–11.

  • Shen, B., Choi, T.-M., & Lo, C. K.-Y. (2015). Enhancing Economic sustainability by markdown money supply chain contracts in the fashion industry: China vs. USA. Sustainability, 8(31), 1–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Song, Y., Ray, S., & Li, S. (2006). Structural properties of buyback contracts for a price-setting newsvendor. Manufacturing and Service Operations Management, 10(1), 1–18.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock, J. R., & Mulki, J. P. (2009). Product returns processing: An examination of returns practices of manufacturers, wholesalers/distributors, and retailers. Journal of Business Logistics, 30(1), 33–61.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Su, C. T., & Shi, C. S. (2002). A Manufacturer’s optimal quantity discount strategy and return policy through a game-theoretic approach. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 53, 922–926.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, T. (2002). Coordination under channel rebates with sales effort effect. Management Science, 48(8), 992–1007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tsay, A. (2001). Managing Retail Channel overstock: Markdown money and return Policies. Journal of Retailing, 77, 457–492.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, H. (2004). Do returns policies intensify retail competition? Marketing Science, 23(4), 611–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Q., Li, J., Ross Jr., W., & Craighead, C. (2013). The interplay of drivers and deterrents of opportunism in buyer-supplier relationships. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 41, 111–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wathne, K. H., & Heide, J. B. (2000). Opportunism in interfirm relationships: Forms, outcomes and solutions. Journal of Marketing, 64(4), 36–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watson, G., Worm, S., Palmatier, R. W., & Ganesan, S. (2015). The evolution of marketing channels: Trends and research directions. Journal of Retailing, 91(4), 546–568.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, E., Blais, A., & Betz, N. (2002). A domain specific risk attitude scale: Measuring risk perceptions and risk behaviors. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 15(4), 263–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yue, X., & Raghunathan, S. (2007). The impacts of the full returns policy on a supply chain with information asymmetry. Euroean Journal of Operational Research, 180(2), 630–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, Y., Donohue, K., & Cui, T. (2015). Contract preferences and performance for the loss averse supplier: Buyback versus revenue sharing. Management Science, 62(6).

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to acknowledge funding for this research from the National Science Foundation (an ADVANCE Grant to the coauthors for “Understanding the Appeal of Suboptimal Contracts”). They would also like to thank the Editor, Associate Editor and three reviewers for very helpful suggestions on previous versions of this manuscript, and their colleagues at the INFORMS, POMS, Behavioral Operations Management and Theory + Practice in Marketing conferences for their very helpful suggestions on this research.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rebecca W. Hamilton.

Additional information

Dhruv Grewal served as Area Editor for this article.

Appendix

Appendix

Study 1 stimuli

Attention/Comprehension Checks for Contracts

Questions

Multiple Choice Options (correct answer in bold)

Under which form of contract is the retailer solely responsible for leftover items?

• Wholesale price contract

Buyback contract

If you offer the retailer a buyback contract, under what circumstances do you pay the retailer a buyback payment?

When demand is higher than the retailer’s order quantity

When demand is equal to the retailer’s order quantity

• When demand is lower than the retailer’s order quantity

All else being equal, the value of a leftover item (not sold during selling season) to the retailer is:

The same under WP and BB contracts

Greater under WP than BB contract

• Less under WP than BB contract

Decision Setting Information

 

High Cost Condition

Low Cost Condition

Demand Distribution

Uniform: [110, 510]

*

Effort level options

0, 1, or 2

*

Increase per unit effort

60 units

*

Cost for 1 unit effort

200

*

Cost for 2 units effort

645 (total)

450 (total)

Contract parameters

WP: 43

BB: 40, 30

*

Profit-maximizing order quantity

WP: 310

BB: 530

*

Profit-maximizing effort level

WP: 2

BB: 2

*

Expected profit

WP: 6820

BB: 7646

*

  1. *Indicates information was the same across cost conditions

Manipulation Checks

Question

Answer type

Rate the retailer’s cost of exerting 1 unit of effort

Scale of 1 (cheap) to 7 (expensive)

Rate the retailer’s cost of exerting 2 units of effort

Scale of 1 (cheap) to 7 (expensive)

If the retailer decides to exert 1 unit of effort, demand for the product will be:

• Remain between 110 and 510 units

• Increase to between 170 and 570 units

• Increase to between 230 and 630 units

If the retailer’s cost of exerting 2 units of effort increases, I would expect the retailer to be:

• More likely to exert 2 units of effort

• Less likely to exert 2 units of effort

• Equally likely to exert 2 units of effort

Dependent Measures

Question

Answer Options

Which contract would you like to offer the retailer?

• Wholesale price contract

• Buyback contract

Please use the sliding scale to indicate which contract you believe effort will be higher under

• WP contract (slide scale to left = 1)

• BB contract (slide scale to right = 7)

What level of effort do you think Highland Fashions will exert under the WP contract?

• 0 units (cost of 0, no increase in demand, no increase in profit)

• 1 units (cost of 200, 60 unit increase in demand)

• 2 units (cost of 450 (or 645), 120 unit increase in demand)

What level of effort do you think Highland Fashions will exert under the BB contract?

• 0 units (cost of 0, no increase in demand, no increase in profit)

• 1 units (cost of 200, 60 unit increase in demand)

• 2 units (cost of 450 (or 645), 120 unit increase in demand)

Scale Questions

For each of the following statements, please use the sliding scale to indicate the degree to which you think the statement is:

  • “More True of WP” (by sliding to the left = 1)

  • “More True of BB” (by sliding to the right = 7)

  • “Same for Both” (by leaving the sliding scale in the center = 4).

Scale

Items

Source

Retailer opportunism

• Under this contract, I believe the retailer would lie about certain things to protect their interests.

• Under this contract, I believe the retailer will promise to things without actually doing them later.

• The retailer will try to take advantage of wiggle room in this contract to further their own interests.

Rokkan et al. 2003 , Liu et al. 2010 ; alpha of 0.75–0.91

Contract complexity

• I found this contract complicated.

• I found this contract difficult to use.

• This contract requires a lot of time to use properly.

Adapted from Marketing Scales Handbook: Volume 7 Bruner

Perceived control

• When using this contract, I feel in control.

• This contract lets me (the supplier) be in charge.

• This contract gives me control over profits.

Adapted from Collier and Sherrell 2010 ; alpha of 0.90

Power

• This contract benefits me (the supplier) more than the retailer.

• This contract gives me leverage over the retailer.

• This contract allows me to influence the decisions made by the retailer.

• This contract allows me to convince the retailer to take specific action.

Adapted from Gregoire et al. 2010 ; alpha of 0.94 and 0.90

Perceived risk of contract performance

• My (the supplier’s) profits are risky under this contract.

• If I were offering this contract, I would be concerned about my potential profits.

• Offering this contract to the retailer would leave me worried about my potential profits.

Adapted from Marketing Scales Handbook: Volume 7 Bruner

Perceived risk of depending on retailer effort

• This contract leaves me vulnerable to the retailer’s actions.

• I am concerned about my dependency on the retailer’s actions when I use this contract.

• Offering the contract to the retailer would leave me worried about my dependency on the retailer’s actions.

Adapted from Marketing Scales Handbook: Volume 7 Bruner

Perception of contract profit

• If I offer this contract to the retailer I can earn high profits.

• The ability to earn high profits is a reason to offer this contract.

 

Supplier belief about retailer focus on cost rather than revenue

• Under this contract, I believe the retailer will focus more on their costs than their revenues.

• Under this contract, I believe the retailer will focus more on the cost of exerting effort now than an increase in revenue later.

 

Study 2 stimuli

Decision Setting Information

Same as in Study 1.

Dependent Measures

Question

Potential Answers

What level of effort would you like to exert?*

• 0 units (resulting in 0 cost and demand between 110 and 510 units)

• 1 unit (resulting in 200 cost and demand between 170 and 570 units)

• 2 units (resulting in 450 (or 645) cost and demand between 230 and 630 units)

  1. *This question was asked twice, once for the WP contract and once for the BB contract.

Study 3 and Study 4 stimuli

Marketing Effort Manipulation

Condition

Description of Retailer

Low marketing effort condition

You have gathered some information about the retailer’s business practices and reputation. For example, you know that Highland Fashions does not actively promote items in their store via ads or targeted emails to customers throughout the season. They also do not go to great lengths to maximize foot traffic throughout their store. Recently, customers have noticed that the retailer is either understaffed or the salespeople have not been very helpful.

Control Condition

You have not been able to gather information about the business practices of both retailers.

High marketing effort condition

You have gathered some information about the retailer’s business practices and reputation. For example, you know that Highland Fashions actively promotes items in their store via ads or targeted emails to customers throughout the season. They also go to great lengths to maximize foot traffic throughout their store. Recently, customers have commented that the salespeople are very helpful.

Decision Setting Information

 

Season A

Season B

Demand distribution

Uniform [150,350]

Uniform [200,500]

Retail price

48

32

Production cost

12

8

Retailer salvage value

24

16

Dependent Measures (before presentation of contracts)

 

Season A

Season B

How many units do you expect (the retailer) to sell during the selling season?

Slide cursor between 150 and 350 units

Slide cursor between 200 and 500 units

Please indicate how successful you think (the retailer) will be in selling (items) this season?

Sliding scale from 1 (not successful) to 7 (very successful)

Sliding scale from 1 (not successful) to 7 (very successful)

Contract Parameters

 

Season A

Season B

Wholesale price

45

30

BB/MM price

12

24

Expected profit

WP: 5511

MM: 6524

WP: 5214

BB: 5823

Dependent Measures (after presentation of the contracts)

Which contract would you prefer to offer the retailer?

– Wholesale price contract

– Markdown money contract

– Wholesale price contract

– Buyback contract

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Devlin, A.G., Elmaghraby, W. & Hamilton, R.W. Why do suppliers choose wholesale price contracts? End-of-season payments disincentivize retailer marketing effort. J. of the Acad. Mark. Sci. 46, 212–233 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-017-0550-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-017-0550-9

Keywords

Navigation