Skip to main content

Lobbying Mechanisms

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
State, Institutions and Democracy

Part of the book series: Studies in Political Economy ((POEC))

Abstract

Political influence of special interests is a rich phenomenon, challenging for both theory and empirics. One of the key questions is whether the influence is through the provision of money, information, or both. In the first generation of empirical studies, the monetary channel is examined by looking upon the effect of campaign contributions through Political Action Committees on roll call voting. The results of the roll call voting studies conducted in the United States since 1970s are nevertheless inconclusive. Even descriptive evidence suggests that campaign contributions through Political Action Committees are not as important as direct individual contributions (Ansolabehere et al. 2003).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Typically, the prize is considered a private good, but even collective goods can be covered as long as the net benefit is independent on the winner.

  2. 2.

    Like most of the literature, we cover only the polar cases with zero or infinite ‘cost of absorption’ of a message. Intermediate cases of positive but finite cost are covered in Dewatripont and Tirole (2005) and the subsequent papers.

  3. 3.

    Signaling refers to any interaction when a privately informed agent sends signals contingent on his or her type to an uninformed agent. Hence, it contains also cheap talk and disclosure games. In a narrow sense, signaling is used only for setting where utility varies with signals (hence signal costs exist) and where the informed agent’s utility is monotonic in the signals and actions. Both of these assumptions are violated for typical models of costless communication.

  4. 4.

    The preference structure has important consequences. For monotonic lobby’s preferences (invariant to states), a single-dimensional cheap talk is uninformative as all lobby’s types would send the same message that implements the most favorable policy. Monotonicity therefore restricts the modeler to communication with verifiable evidence and/or to evidence production. In other words, the preference structure (having a conflict or not having a conflict between the lobby’s types) is typically related also to the informational structure.

  5. 5.

    Notice that even if the lobby may have a different posterior than the policy-maker, we must use the policy-maker’s posterior. The reason is that the value of a mechanism is an ex ante expected value evaluated at μ 0, where information is symmetric, hence the lobby’s ex ante belief conditional on learning that the policy-maker will have μ belief must also be μ.

  6. 6.

    Notice that convexity or quasi-convexity of the lobbyist’s (Sender’s) payoffs is a recurrent topic in the communication literature (cf., Chakraborty and Harbaugh 2010).

  7. 7.

    One option to avoid an inconvenient step-wise indirect utility is to let the policy-maker’s optimal policy be stochastic in posteriors on fundamentals (Dahm and Porteiro 2008a). For example, suppose the states of the world are characterized by two independent dimensions, a fundamental dimension θ and a policy-maker’s type r (e.g., ideology, risk aversion, or relative weights attached to contributions). The policy-maker type is private information that only influences v(⋅ ), but no other payoff, and the policy-maker cannot communicate his/her type. A persuasion mechanism is invariant to the policy-maker’s type, hence implies a distribution of posteriors where the densities are constant in the type-dimension, and we may let μ(θ): = μ(θ, r). Then, discontinuity in U(μ) may disappear, since each d (μ(θ)) is constructed as an expected policy from a continuous distribution of policy-maker types, not as a (deterministic) policy of a single policy-maker with a known type r. An important corollary is that the value of the persuasion mechanism in the presence of uncertainty over the policy-maker’s type hinges on concavities and convexities in the distribution F(r). Typically, an assumption of the uniform distribution of the policy-maker’s types is applied as in the literature on the communication design. Rayo and Segal (2010) manage to characterize several properties of the optimal communication mechanisms under special assumptions that the policy-maker’s action space is binary ({d l , d h }) and that the policy-maker’s action is affected by noise to the policy-maker’s values, and the noise has a uniform distribution.

  8. 8.

    The body of evidence on the allocation of access through connected intermediaries is growing. Blanes-i-Vidal et al. (2012) measure the value of a political connection for revolving-door lobbyists who were previously congressional staffers. Specifically, by measuring how the exit of a former employer affects their payoff, they observe the premium for connections at above 20 %, and the premium lasts for over 3 years. Bertrand et al. (2014) compare the connection premium with the expertise premium using price tags per report. From price tags per report, the report-level analysis reveals that (1) the premium of having a relevant specialist in the report is 3–5 % and (2) the premium of having a relevant connected lobbyist is 8–10 %. Estimating the value of a lobbyist’s political connections from stock markets is another strategy. Gely and Zardkoohi (2001) study firms that retain law firms as lobbyists. The firms show abnormal gains when one of the partners at that firm obtains a federal cabinet position which disappear when anti-lobbying laws are enacted.

  9. 9.

    Typically, all information is revealed to the lobby. A modified case is when the lobby has only partial advantage of knowing her bias (Austen-Smith 1995; Lohmann 1993).

References

  • Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. (2003). Why is there so little money in U.S. politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 105–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1995). Campaign contributions and access. American Political Science Review, 89, 566–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D. (1998). Allocating access for information and contributions. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 14(2), 277–303.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. S. (2000). Cheap talk and burned money. Journal of Economic Theory, 91(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. S. (2002). Costly signaling and cheap talk in models of political influence. European Journal of Political Economy, 18, 263–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ball, R. (1995). Interest groups, influence and welfare. Economics and Politics, 7(2), 119–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. (1989). Service-induced campaign contributions and the electoral equilibrium. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104, 45–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baye, M. R., & Hoppe, H. H. (2003). The strategic equivalence of rent-seeking, innovation, and patent-race games. Games and Economic Behavior, 44, 217–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen, M., & Feldmann, S. E. (2002). Lobbying legislatures. Journal of Political Economy, 110(4), 919–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen, M., & Feldmann, S. E. (2006). Informational lobbying and political contributions. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 631–656.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bennedsen, M., Feldmann, S. E., & Lassen, D. D. (2011). Lobbying and Bribes: A Survey-Based Analysis of the Demand for Influence and Corruption. CESifo Working Paper 3496.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand, M., Bombardini, M., & Trebbi, F. (2014). Is it whom you know or what you know? An empirical assessment of the lobbying process. American Economic Review, 104(12), 3885–3920.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanes-i-Vidal, J., Draca, M., & Fons-Rosen, C. (2012). Revolving door lobbyists. The American Economic Review, 102(7), 3731–3748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borisov, A., Goldman, A., & Gupta, N. (2014). The Corporate Value of (Corrupt) Lobbying. European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI) Finance Working Paper No. 423/2014.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brocas, I., & Carrillo, J. D. (2007). Influence through ignorance. RAND Journal of Economics, 38(4), 931–947.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campos, N., & Giovannoni, F. (2007). Lobbying, corruption and political influence. Public Choice, 131, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chakraborty, A., & Harbaugh, R. (2010). Persuasion by cheap talk. American Economic Review, 100, 2361–2382.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari, R., Hogan, J., & Murphy, G. (2010). Regulating lobbying: A global comparison. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Che, Y., & Gale, I. L. (1998). Caps on political lobbying. American Economic Review, 88(3), 643–651.

    Google Scholar 

  • Che, Y., & Gale, I. L. (2006). Caps on political lobbying: Reply. American Economic Review, 96(4), 1355–1360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chong, A., & Gradstein, M. (2010). Firm-level determinants of political influence. Economics and Politics, 22(3), 233–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corchon, L., & Dahm, M. (2010). Foundations for contest success functions. Economic Theory, 43(1), 81–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotton, C. (2009). Should we tax or cap political contributions? A lobbying model with policy favors and access. Journal of Public Economics, 93, 831–842.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotton, C. (2012). Pay-to-play politics: Informational lobbying and contribution limits when money buys access. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 369–386.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cotton, C. (2016, in press). Competing for attention: Lobbying time-constrained politicians. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 18, 642–665.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cotton, C., & Dellis, A. (2016, in press). Informational Lobbying and Agenda Distortion. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. doi:10.1093/jleo/eww005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008a). Side-effects of campaign finance reform. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(5), 1057–1077.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008b). Informational lobbying under the shadow of political pressure. Social Choice and Welfare, 30, 531–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damania, R., Fredriksson, P. G., & Mani, M. (2004). The persistence of corruption and regulatory compliance failures: Theory and evidence. Public Choice, 121(3), 363–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Figueiredo, J. M., & Cameron, C. (2009). Endogenous cost lobbying: Theory and evidence. In CELS 2009–4th Annual Conference on Empirical Legal Studies. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1443559.

  • Dewatripont, M., & Tirole, J. (2005). Modes of communication. Journal of Political Economy, 113(6), 1217–1238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, G. S., Mealem, Y., & Nitzan, S. (2011). Political culture and discrimination in contests. Journal of Public Economics, 95, 88–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, G. S., & Nitzan, S. (2004). Strategic restraint in contests. European Economic Review, 48, 201–210.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, G. S., & Nitzan, S. (2006a). Reduced prizes and increased effort in contests. Social Choice and Welfare, 26, 447–453.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, G. S., & Nitzan, S. (2006b). The politics of randomness. Social Choice and Welfare, 27, 423–433.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, H. (2002). Lottery versus all-pay auction models of lobbying. Public Choice, 112(3–4), 351–371.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, J. (1993). Meaning and credibility in cheap-talk games. Games and Economic Behavior, 5(4), 514–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felgenhauer, M. (2010). Transparency and special interests. Economics Letters, 106(1), 4–7.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gely, R., & Zardkoohi, A. (2001). Measuring the effects of post-government employment restrictions. American Law and Economics Review, 3, 288–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giovannoni, F., & Seidmann, D. J. (2007). Secrecy, two-sided bias and the value of evidence. Games and Economic Behavior, 59(2), 296–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A. (2008). Bargaining with rent seekers. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 10(5), 859–871.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, J., & Rubinstein, A. (2004). On optimal rules of persuasion. Econometrica, 72(6), 1715–1736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gregor, M. (2011). Corporate Lobbying: A Review of the Recent Literature. IES Working Paper 32/2011. Institute of Economic Studies, Faculty of Social Sciences, Charles University in Prague.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gregor, M. (2015). To invite or not to invite the lobby, that is the question. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 15(2), 143–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groll, T., & Ellis, C. J. (2014). A simple model of the commercial lobbying industry. European Economic Review, 70, 299–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossmann, M., & Dietl, H. (2012). Asymmetric contests with liquidity constraints. Public Choice, 150, 691–713.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special interest politics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harstad, B., & Svensson, J. (2011). Bribes, lobbying, and development. American Political Science Review, 105(1), 46–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henry, E. (2009). Strategic disclosure of research results: The cost of proving your honesty. Economic Journal, 119, 1036–1064.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hillman, A., & Ursprung, H. (1988). Domestic politics, foreign interests, and international trade policy. American Economic Review, 78, 729–745.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, P. E. (1996). Corporate political offices in a rent-seeking society. Public Choice, 88, 309–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamenica, E., & Gentzkow, M. (2011). Bayeasian Persuasion. American Economic Review, 101, 2590–2615.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, K. (2016). Policy influence and private returns from lobbying in the energy sector. Review of Economic Studies, 83(1), 269–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, K., & You, H. Y. (2015). Lobbyists as matchmakers in the market for access. Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan, T. R. & Wettstein, D. (2006). Caps on political lobbying: Comment. American Economic Review, 96(4), 1351–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaufmann, D., & Vicente, P. C. (2011). Legal corruption. Economics and Politics, 23(2), 195–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, W. R., Lincoln, W. F., & Mishra, P. (2014). The dynamics of firm lobbying. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 6(4), 343–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Konrad, K. A. (2009). Strategy and dynamics in contests. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lagerlöf, J. (1997). Lobbying, information, and private and social welfare. European Journal of Political Economy, 13, 615–637.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lagerlöf, J. (2007). A theory of rent seeking with informational foundations. Economics of Governance, 8(3), 197–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1993). A signaling model of informative and manipulative political action. American Political Science Review, 87(2), 319–333.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lohmann, S. (1995). Information, access, and contributions: A signaling model of lobbying. Public Choice, 85, 267–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. (1981). Good news and bad news: Representation theorems and applications. Bell Journal of Economics, 12, 350–391.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. (2008). What the seller won’t tell you: Persuasion and disclosure in markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 22(2), 115–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Münster, J. (2006). Lobbying contests with endogenous policy proposals. Economics and Politics, 18(3), 389–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pastine, I., & Pastine, T. (2010). Politician preferences, law-abiding lobbyists and caps on political contributions. Public Choice, 145, 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polk, A., & Schmutzler, A. (2005). Lobbying against environmental regulation vs. lobbying for loopholes. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 915–931.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potters, J., & van Winden, F. (1992). Lobbying and asymmetric information. Public Choice, 74, 269–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rayo, L., & Segal, I. (2010). Optimal information disclosure. Journal of Political Economy, 118(5), 949–987.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Richter, B. K., Samphantharak, K., & Timmons, J. F. (2009). Lobbying and taxes. American Journal of Political Science, 53(4), 893–909.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ryan, M., & Vaithianathan, R. (2011). Verifiability and neologism-proofness in a Sender-Receiver game. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 79(3), 256–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, R. (2009). All pay contests. Econometrica, 77(1), 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sisak, D. (2009). Multiple-prize contests – the optimal allocation of prizes. Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(1), 82–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S., & Vaidya, S. (2012). Persuasion as a contest. Economic Theory, 51(2), 465–486.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sloof, R. (1998). Game-theoretic models of the political influence of interest groups. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, J. M. (1990). Campaign contributions as investments: The U.S. House of Representatives 1980–1986. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1195–1227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, J. (2010). Giving and receiving advice. Presented at Econometric Society 10th World Congress.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone, D. F. (2011). A signal-jamming model of persuasion: Interest group funded policy research. Social Choice and Welfare, 37(3), 397–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Economist (2011). Money and politics. The Economist, October 1st 2011, p. 70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tovar, P. (2011). Lobbying costs and trade policy. Journal of International Economics, 83, 126–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent-seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Winden, F. (2003). Interest group behavior and influence. In C. K. Rowley & F. Schneider (Eds.), The encyclopedia of public choice (pp. 118–129). Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Z. (2010). The optimal accuracy level in asymmetric contests. The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, 10(1). Art. 13.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank participants at ICOPEAI 2015 for their useful comments. An early version of the paper circulated under the title ‘Corporate lobbying: a review of the recent literature’ (Gregor 2011). Financial support from the Grant Agency of the Czech Republic No. P402/12/G097 is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Martin Gregor .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Gregor, M. (2017). Lobbying Mechanisms. In: Schofield, N., Caballero, G. (eds) State, Institutions and Democracy. Studies in Political Economy. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-44582-3_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics