Skip to main content
Log in

The elasticity of taxable income of individuals in couples

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the effect on the elasticity of taxable income for individuals in couples, where there is no income splitting for tax purposes but joint decisions are taken regarding taxable incomes. Two approaches are considered. First, the effects of minimising the total tax increase arising from a marginal rate increase are examined. Second, the paper considers the effects of joint utility maximisation. In both cases, analytical results suggest the possibility that empirical taxable income elasticity estimates obtained while ignoring the distinction between individuals and couples can be biased, sometimes substantially. Thus, in the presence of individual income taxation, both taxable income elasticity and revenue response estimates could be expected to be quite different when those estimates are obtained while erroneously treating the behaviour of members of couple households as if they were separate individuals.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The properties and literature are reviewed by Saez et al. (2012).

  2. On the approach to optimal taxation using the ETI, see Saez (2001) and Creedy (2015). The modification needed in the case of joint taxation with income splitting for couples is examined by Bach et al. (2012). The optimal taxation of couples is also examined by Kleven et al. (2009), using the elasticity of taxable income concept.

  3. On a specification of income effects and tests in the New Zealand context, see Creedy et al. (2018), who found negligible effects. Gelber (2014) found some statistically significant but small income effects for Swedish couples.

  4. For extensive discussion of this function and its revenue flexibility properties, see Creedy and Gemmell (2006).

  5. This uses \(\frac{dT_{1}}{d\tau _{1}}=z_{1}\left( 1+\eta _{z_{1},\tau _{1}}\right) \) and \(dT_{2}=\frac{T_{2}}{\tau _{1}}\eta _{z_{2},\tau _{1}}\). An equivalent expression for the response of \(z=z_{1}+z_{2}\) to \(\tau _{1}\) is given by: \(\eta _{z,\tau _{1}}=\left( \frac{z_{1}}{z}\right) \eta _{z_{1},\tau _{1}}+\left( \frac{z_{2}}{z}\right) \eta _{z_{2},\tau _{1}}\).

  6. Alternatively, the couple may be concerned with the reduction in the household’s net-of-tax income, \(\sum _{i=1}^{2}\left\{ y_{i}-T\left( y_{i}\right) \right\} \), by reducing or increasing gross income, \( \sum _{i=1}^{2}y_{i}\), or reducing \(\sum _{i=1}^{2}T\left( y_{i}\right) \), or reallocating income across household members. This potentially includes responses that generate an increase in total net-of-tax income if income effects on gross income are sufficiently large. These cases are not examined here.

  7. Additionally, as Saez et al. (2012) point out, avoidance and evasion responses that are not associated with income transfers to other household members, may also have limited welfare effects if they simply represent transfers among taxpayers in general.

  8. Clearly, if \(\beta =0\), Eq.(10) reduces to \(\eta _{T,\tau _{1}}=\frac{T_{1}}{T}\left\{ 1+\eta _{z_{1},\tau _{1}}\right\} +\frac{T_{2}}{ T}\eta _{z_{2},\tau _{1}}^{^{\prime }}\), capturing the two separate revenue response components for each member.

  9. The only study to allow for income effects for individual members of couple households, Gelber (2014) for Sweden, also found income effects to be small, around \(-0.05\) to \(-0.07\). These may be compared with compensated elasticities of taxable income estimates of around \(-0.41\) to \(-0.47\) (with uncompensated values of around \(-0.21~\) to \(-0.23\)).

  10. Some empirical evidence would appear to support the view that the source or composition of household income can affect household spending decisions; see, for example, evidence based on UK child benefit reforms by Lundberg et al. (1997) and Ward-Batts (2008).

  11. In a recent extension of such collective models, Meier and Rainer (2015) show how ‘optimal’ (Pigouvian) tax rules for both cooperative and non-cooperative approaches to utility maximisation by couples can be derived. However, in common with the collective literature, tax responses are again restricted to labour supply choices.

  12. If, alternatively, the two components of U in (18) are additive, income sharing has no effect on the solutions for \(z_{1}\) and \( z_{2}\).

  13. In his Swedish study, Gelber (2014, p. 295) examines different responses by members of married couple households (hence obtaining separate estimates of \( \eta _{y_{1},1-\tau _1}\), \(\eta _{y_{2},1-\tau _{2}}\), \(\eta _{y_{1},1-\tau _{2}}\) and \(\eta _{y_{2},1-\tau _{1}}\)), but excludes non-married and single-person households. Also, in the context of estimating structural female labour supply models for the UK, Blundell et al. (2016; section 7.3) find that labour supply elasticities for women in couples (with and without children) can differ substantially from equivalent elasticity estimates for single women (with and without children). Other studies to focus specifically on labour supply responses to taxation for married couples and/or parents include Eissa (1995) and LaLumia (2008) for the USA, and Stephens and Ward-Batts (2004) for the UK.

  14. Write \(\xi =\frac{k_{1}}{k_{2}}=\frac{1+\frac{1}{\varepsilon _{2}}}{ \varepsilon _{2}}\). The coefficient, \(\varepsilon _{2}\), can be obtained as the appropriate root of the quadratic \(\xi \varepsilon _{2}^{2}-\varepsilon _{2}-1=0\). Using the expression for \(k_{1}\), and the solution for \( \varepsilon _{2}\), the coefficient, \(\varepsilon _{1}\), can also be obtained as the root of another quadratic function, given by \(\left( 1+\frac{ k_{1}\varepsilon _{2}}{1+\frac{1}{\varepsilon _{2}}}\right) \varepsilon _{1}^{2}+\left( 1-k_{1}\right) \varepsilon _{1}-k_{1}=0\). The separate parameters, \(\varepsilon _{1}\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}\), can therefore be recovered from estimation of (31).

  15. In terms of impacts on tax revenue levels, this can translate into a substantive difference. For example, with \(y_{1}=\$120,000\) and \( y_{2}=\$65,000\), and other parameters as described above, person 1 pays tax of \(\$35,150\) when the top tax rate is 0.38. Raising this tax rate by 1%, to 0.3838, has a mechanical effect of raising tax revenue from person 1 by \(\$19{\dot{0}}\). Where person 1 is a single individual, the behavioural effect (of an ETI = 0.5 for person 1) is to cut this increase to \(\$50\), whereas if person 1 is coupled with person 2 (ETI = 0.25), the combined behavioural effect reduces the tax revenue increase to only \(\$39\), due to the reallocation of some taxable income to person 2 in this latter case. Clearly, this difference is non-trivial.

  16. As can be seen in Fig. 3, \(\eta _{T_{2},\tau _{1}}\) is always positive, unlike in Sect. 3. This is because of the absence of income effects arising from the form of the utility function in ( 18).

  17. For example, when \(\varepsilon _{1}=0.5\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}=0.25,\) then \( (\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}=0.0156\), while if \(\varepsilon _{1}=0.3\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}=0.15,\)\((\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}=0.0020\).

References

  • Bach, S., Corneo, G., & Steiner, V. (2012). Optimal top marginal tax rates under income splitting for couples. European Economic Review, 56, 1055–1069.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomquist, S., & Selin, H. (2010). Hourly wage rate and taxable labor income responsiveness to changes in marginal tax rates. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 878–889.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell, R., Costa Dias, M., Meghir, C., & Shaw, J. (2016). Female labor supply, human capital and welfare reform. Econometrica, 84, 1705–1753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P.-A. (1992). Collective labor supply and welfare. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 437–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori, P-A., & Donni, O. (2009). Non-unitary models of household behavior: A survey of the literature. IZA discussion paper , no. 4603.

  • Creedy, J. (2015). The elasticity of taxable income, welfare changes and optimal tax rates. New Zealand Economic Papers, 49, 227–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., & Gemmell, N. (2006). Modelling tax revenue growth. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., & Gemmell, N. (2013). Measuring revenue responses to tax rate changes in multi-rate income tax systems: Behavioural and structural factors. International Tax and Public Finance, 20, 974–991.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Creedy, J., Gemmell, N., & Teng, J. (2018). Income effects and the elasticity of taxable income. New Zealand Economic Papers, 52, 185–203.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eissa, N. (1995). Taxation and labor supply of married women: The ax Reform Act of 1986 as a natural experiment. NBER working paper no. 5023.

  • Feldstein, M. (1995). The effect of marginal tax rates on taxable income: a panel study of the 1986 Tax Reform Act. Journal of Political Economy, 103, 551–572.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. (1999). Tax avoidance and the deadweight loss of the income tax. Review of Economics and Statistics, 81, 674–680.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelber, A. (2014). Taxation and the earnings of husbands and wives: evidence from Sweden. Review of Economics and Statistics, 96, 287–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleven, H. J., Kreiner, C. T., & Saez, E. (2009). The optimal income taxation of couples. Econometrica, 77, 537–560.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LaLumia, S. (2008). The effects of joint taxation of married couples on labor supply and non-wage income. Journal of Public Economics, 92, 1698–1719.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg, S. J., Pollak, R. A., & Wales, T. J. (1997). Do husbands and wives pool their resources? Evidence from the United Kingdom child benefit. Journal of Human Resources, 32, 463–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meier, V., & Rainer, H. (2015). Pigou meets Ramsey: gender-based taxation with non-cooperative couples. European Economic Review, 77, 28–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E. (2001). Using elasticities to derive optimal income tax rates. Review of Economic Studies, 68, 205–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., Slemrod, J. B., & Giertz, S. H. (2012). The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: a critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 50, 3–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stephens, M., & Ward-Batts, J. (2004). The impact of separate taxation on the intra-household allocation of assets: Evidence from the UK. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1989–2007.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ward-Batts, J. (2008). Out of the wallet and into the purse. Using micro data to test income pooling. Journal of Human Resources, 43, 325–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper is part of a larger project on ‘Improving New Zealand’s Tax Policy via International Tax Transfer Model Benchmarking’, funded by an Endeavour Research Grant from the Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment (MBIE) and awarded to the Chair in Public Finance. We are grateful to two referees for comments on an earlier version.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Norman Gemmell.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Relationships between revenue elasticities

Appendix: Relationships between revenue elasticities

This Appendix demonstrates why the four profiles in Fig. 3 are approximately linear. To see why this is the case, it is useful to consider each profile separately. Consider first \(\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}\). From Eq. (35), since \(\eta _{y_{1},1-\tau _{1}}=\varepsilon _{1}\) for a single individual, then

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}=\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}^{\prime }-\left( \frac{\tau _{1}}{1-\tau _{1}}\right) \left( \eta _{T_{1},y_{1}}\right) \varepsilon _{1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Hence, it can be seen that the slope of the relationship between \(\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}\) and \(\varepsilon _{1}\) is constant with respect to changes in \(\varepsilon _{1}\), given by \(-\left( \frac{\tau _{1}}{1-\tau _{1} }\right) \left( \eta _{T_{1},y_{1}}\right) \) where, from (37), \(\eta _{T_{1},y_{1}}=\frac{y_{1}}{y_{1}-a_{k}^{*}}\). The single-person \(\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}\) profile is therefore exactly linear, given a fixed tax structure and the individual’s income.

For two individuals in a couple, first consider person 1, where from (35) and (25):

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}=\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}^{\prime }-\left( \frac{\tau _{1}}{1-\tau _{1}}\right) \left( \eta _{T_{1},y_{1}}\right) \varepsilon _{1} \left[ \frac{(1+\varepsilon _{1})(1+\varepsilon _{2})}{(1+\varepsilon _{1})(1+\varepsilon _{2})-(\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

For most plausible values of \(\varepsilon _{1}\) and \(\varepsilon _{2}\), it can be expected that \((\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}\) is small.Footnote 17 Thus, from Eq. (A.2), if \((\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}\approx 0\), the variation between \(\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}\) and \(\varepsilon _{1}\) reduces to:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}\approx \eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}^{\prime }-\left( \frac{\tau _{1}}{1-\tau _{1}}\right) \left( \eta _{T_{1},y_{1}}\right) \varepsilon _{1} \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

Following a similar process for person 2, from (41 ) and (25) it can be shown that:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{T_{2},\tau _{1}}=\left( \frac{\tau _{1}}{1-\tau _{1}}\right) \left( \frac{y_{2}}{y_{2}-a_{s}^{*}}\right) \left( \frac{\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}}{1+\varepsilon _{1}}\right) \left[ \frac{(1+\varepsilon _{1})(1+\varepsilon _{2})}{(1+\varepsilon _{1})(1+\varepsilon _{2})-(\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}}\right] \quad \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

and:

$$\begin{aligned} \eta _{T_{2},\tau _{1}}\approx \left( \frac{\tau _{1}}{1-\tau _{1}}\right) \left( \frac{y_{2}}{y_{2}-a_{s}^{*}}\right) \left( \frac{\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2}}{1+\varepsilon _{1}}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

if \((\varepsilon _{1}\varepsilon _{2})^{2}\approx 0\). However, unlike the case for \(\eta _{T_{1},\tau _{1}}\) in (A.3), the approximation for \( \eta _{T_{2},\tau _{1}}\) does not display a simple linear relationship with \( \varepsilon _{1}\). That is, both the exact specification in (A.4) and the approximation in (A.5) suggest nonlinear relationships between \( \eta _{T_{2},\tau _{1}}\) and \(\varepsilon _{1}\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Creedy, J., Gemmell, N. The elasticity of taxable income of individuals in couples. Int Tax Public Finance 27, 931–950 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-019-09581-6

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-019-09581-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation