Skip to main content
Log in

Virginia, Rochester, and Bloomington: Twenty-five years of public choice and political science

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

References

  • Aranson, P.H. (1981). American government. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aranson, P.H. and Ordeshook, C. (1977). A prolegomenon to a theory of the failure of representative government. In R.D. Auster and B. Sears (Eds.), American re-evolution: Papers and proceedings, 23–46. Tucson: Department of Economics, University of Arizona.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aranson, P.H., and Ordeshook, P.C. (1981). Alternative theories of the growth of government and their implications for constitutional tax and spending limits. In H.F. Ladd and T.N. Tideman (Eds.), Tax and expenditure limitations, 143–176. Washington, DC: Urban Institute Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aranson, P.H., and Ordeshook, P.C. (1985). Public interest, private interest, and the democratic polity. In R. Benjamin and S.L. Elkin (Eds.), The democratic state, 87–178. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K.J. (1952). Social choice and individual values. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (1958). Competition and democracy. The Journal of Law and Economics 1: 105–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bonner, J. (1986) Introduction to the theory of social choice. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding, K.E. (1962). Conflict and defense. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brams, S.J., and Fishburn, P.C. (1983). Approval voting. Boston: Birkhauser.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1954a). Individual choice in voting and the market. Journal of Political Economy 62: 334–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1954b). Social Choice, Democracy, and Free Markets. Journal of Political Economy 62: 114–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. (1968). Democracy and Duopoly: A Comparison of Analytical Models. American Economic Association Proceedings 58: 322–340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M., and Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M., Tollison, R.D., and Tullock, G., Eds. (1980). Rent-seeking society. College Station: Texas A & M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coleman, J. (1966). The possibility of a social welfare function. American Economic Review 56: 1105–1122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ekelund, R.B., and Tollison, R.D. (1981). Mercantilísm as a rent-seeking society. College Station: Texas A & M University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Farquharson, R. (1969). Theory of voting. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feldman, A.M. (1980). Welfare economics and social choice theory, Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenno, R.F., Jr. (1973). Congressmen in committees. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P. (1977). Congress: Keystone of the Washington establishment. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P. and Shepsle, K.A. (1982). Equilibrium, disequilibrium, and the general possibility of a science of politics. In P.C. Ordeshook and K.A. Shepsle (Eds.), Political equilibrium, 49–64. Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P. (1983). Flagellating the federal bureaucracy. Society (March/April): 66–73.

  • Gosnell, H.F. (1937). Machine politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, R. (1976). Hollow victory: The minimum winning coalition. American Political Science Review 70: 1202–1214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herring, E.P. (1940). The politics of democracy. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review 71: 1467–1487.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B., and Rubin, P.H. (1982). Congressmen, constituents, and contributors. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Key, V.O. (1949). Politics, parties, and pressure groups. New York: Crowell Publishing Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, D.R. (1982). The political economy of social conflict, or malice in blunderland. Los Angeles: International Institute for Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce, R.D., and Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and decisions. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacRae, C.D. (1977). A political model of the business cycle. Journal of Political Economy 85: 239–263.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayhew, D.R. (1974). Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R.E., and Tollison, R.D. (1981). Politicians, legislation, and the economy. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D. (1984). An experimental study of the effects of procedural rules on committee behavior. Journal of Politics 46: 182–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D., and Ordeshook, P.C. (1984). The influence of committee procedures on outcomes: Some experimental evidence. Journal of Politics 46: 182–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D., and Wendell, R.E. (1976). Voting equilibria in multi-dimensional choice spaces. Mathematics of operations research 1: 144–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nordhaus, W.D. (1975). The political business cycle. Review of Economic Studies 42: 169–190.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1986). An agenda for the study of institutions. Public Choice 48: 3–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., and Parks, R. (1973). Suburb police departments: Too many? Too small? In L.H. Masotti and J.K. Haddens (Eds.), The urbanization of the suburbs, 367–402. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., and Whitacker, G.P. (1974). Community control and governmental responsiveness: A case of police in black communities. In D. Rogers and W. Hawley (Eds.), Improving the quality of urban management, 303–334. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1953). Water & politics. Los Angeles: The Haynes Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1973). The intellectual crisis in American public administration. University, AL: University of Alabama Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1976). The American experiment in constitutional choice. Public Choice 27: 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1987). The political theory of compound republic, 2nd Ed. Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V., and Ostrom, E. (1971). Public choice: A different approach to the study of public administration. Public Administration Review 31: 203–216.

    Google Scholar 

  • Page, B.I. (1983). Who gets what from government. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1976). Comments on Vincent Ostrom's paper. Public Choice 27: 13–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1979). Is ‘A new and superior process’ really superior? Journal of Political Economy 87: 875–890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1980). Constitutional limitations as self-denying ordinances. In W.S. Moore and R.G. Penner (Eds.), The Constitution and the budget, 85–90. Washington DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1982a). Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. In P.C. Ordeshook and K.A. Shepsle (Eds.), Political equilibrium. Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1982b). Liberalism against populism. San Francisco: Freeman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1986). The art of political manipulation. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H., and Brams, S. (1973). The paradox of vote trading. American Political Science Review 67: 1235–1247.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H., and Ordeshook, P.C. (1973). An introduction to positive political theory. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowley, C.K. (1986). Review article: J. Enelow and M.J. Hinich, The spatial theory of voting. Public Choice 48: 93–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E.E. (1960). The semi-sovereign people. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schattschneider, E.E. (1969). Two hundred million Americans in search of a government. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. (1982). The budget: Will a constitutional amendment help? Challenge 53–56.

  • Shepsle, K., and Weingast, B.R. (1981). Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice 37: 503–519.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K., and Weingast, B.R. (1987). The institutional foundations of committee power. American Political Science Review 81: 85–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1972). Economic competition and political competition. Public Choice 13: 91–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tideman, T.N., and Tullock, G. (1976). A new and superior process for making social choices. Journal of Political Economy 84: 1145–1159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tufte, E.R. (1978). Political control of the economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The general irrelevance of the general impossibility theorem. Quarterly Journal of Economics 81: 256–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1981). Why so much stability? Public Choice 37: 189–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1984). A (partial) rehabilitation of the public interest theory. Public Choice 42: 89–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R.E. (1978). Advertizing and the public economy: Some preliminary ruminations. In D.G. Tuerck (Ed.), The political economy of advertizing. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, R.E. (1980). Boom and bust: The political economy of economic disorder. Journal of Libertarian Studies 4: 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Mitchell, W.C. Virginia, Rochester, and Bloomington: Twenty-five years of public choice and political science. Public Choice 56, 101–119 (1988). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00115751

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00115751

Keywords

Navigation