Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

A comparative analysis of African and Asian migrants’ effect on trade

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The trade creation effect of migrants is among the topics of interest of contemporary development economists. Using a 10-year interval comprehensive dataset of 136 countries for the period 1970–2000, this paper reveals African migrants promote homogeneous product exports, while Asians promote the export of manufactured and differentiated products. Unsurprisingly, however, both African and Asian migrants have a positive and significant impact on imports from the migrants’ destination countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. If a business owner violates an agreement, he is blacklisted, which is worse than being sued because the entire community will refrain from doing business with him.

  2. Asian countries export more differentiated products, while African countries export homogeneous commodities. For example, in 2000, manufacturing exports as a percentage of total merchandise exports was 26.84% for Sub-Saharan Africa and 85.66% for the East Asia and Pacific. Similarly, high technology exports as a percentage of manufactured exports are 3.76% for Sub-Saharan Africa, while this figure is 33.25% for the EAP region (World Bank WITS UNSD COMTRADE).

  3. However, Egger et al.’s (2012) study indicates that the trade-inducing effect of migrants is strong when the first migrants from a particular origin arrive, and then declines to zero for migrant stocks greater than 4000. A discussion on the comparative difference of African and Asian migrants is provided in “Appendix”.

  4. Both the relative and absolute migration stocks of Asian migrants in developed countries are higher than that of Africa. African countries’ migration is mainly within the low-wage African countries because African migration is mainly driven by conflicts, environmental pressures and artificial borders. There is relatively less migration from low-wage African countries to high-wage regions than migration within low-wage Africa (Naudé 2010; Naudé and Bezuidenhout 2014). However, more workers from Asian countries migrate to non-OECD countries (mainly within the region) as well. The skills of Asian migrants to OECD and non-OECD countries differ. Unlike the non-OECD countries, labour migration to OECD countries is mainly highly skilled (Xing et al. 2014). Given that migration is costly, most African migrants from low-per-capita-income countries cannot travel too far (Naudé 2010). On the other hand, the absence of conflicts and relatively better per capita income in Asian economies means that Asian migration is mainly driven by the income effect.

  5. Lack of information about international trade and investment opportunities is one of the informal barriers to trade.

  6. Migration may also facilitate the formation of the types of business links that lead to foreign direct investment (FDI) project deployment in a particular location. In developing countries in particular, migrants can be the bridge that solves uncertainties related to trade and investment opportunities. Migrants also affect trade indirectly via technology and knowledge transfers.

  7. The study on the effect of the average length of stay of a migrant in the host area by Herander and Saavedra (2005) shows a positive effect on exports while its square has a negative effect.

  8. Migrants are in a privileged position to provide information about distribution networks and about demand in their home countries to host country exporters and vice versa (Rauch 1996; Greif 1993).

  9. The global bilateral migrants’ stock database is a vast collection of destination country data sources detailing migrant stock from numerous origin countries and regions. It is constructed by combining over 100 censuses and population register records (Ozden et al. 2011).

  10. For example, the EU-type supranational level of coordination of visa policy at the destination country and visa waivers depending on citizenship can influence the flow of migrants.

  11. For example, a linguistic proximity that relies more closely on the country of birth and economic conditions in the country of the last residence might also shape the incentives to migrate (Bertoli and Moraga 2016; Hanson 2010; Bertoli et al. 2011; Bertoli and Moraga 2013).

  12. The determinants of migration include origin- or destination-specific factors such as income, and other dyadic factors such as networks that are correlated with unobserved cultural proximity of the pair countries (Rauch 1999; Bertoli and Moraga 2016; Karemera et al. 2000; Pedersen et al. 2008; Kim and Cohen 2010) also determine bilateral trade between pair countries. Hence, when left uncorrected, in gravity estimations, the error term may represent unobserved heterogeneity in trade flow determinants associated with the likelihood of migration.

  13. The best option to resolve the problem of endogeneity is, of course, to construct an exogenous instrument for migration which is a potential area for future research. This is beyond the scope of this study, and hence, this research used the same method adopted in previous studies.

  14. Three reasons: (1) GDP is a function of net multilateral exports, which on average tend to be less than 5% of a country’s GDP, and its connection to gross exports is much less direct; (2) the gravity equation relates bilateral trade flows to countries’ GDPs, which are a very small share of a country’s multilateral exports; (3) previous studies indicate that the potential endogeneity of GDPs with export is insignificant (Baier and Bergstrand 2007).

  15. Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003) clarify that the omitted variable bias arises by disregarding multilateral trade resistance terms that capture the idea that trade choices are established on relative rather than absolute prices.

  16. This might possibly be due to the labour movement, and social and human capital effects offset one another. The recent literature shows that migration has labour movement (substitute trade) and social and human capital movement (enhanced trade) effects. The labour movement effect reduces trade since it could equalise wages if migration was undertaken on a massive scale. On the other hand, the social capital and human capital movement effect increase trade since they provide market information. Hence, the net impact of migration on trade thus depends on which effect has the most weight, since the two effects work together to affect trade.

  17. The regional outliers are all North African countries and Hong Kong, Macao and Brunei Darussalam.

  18. The products are classified using the Rauch Classification of Goods frequently used in international trade literature.

  19. According to Bettin and Turco (2012), the south–north migration and trade reveal that migration enhances the import of primary and final goods (preference channel), the export of differentiated goods, and low elasticity of substitution goods (information channel). However, their study shows that there is no evidence that migration influences the export of labour-intensive goods (technology channel).

  20. As the data in the WB database http://wits.worldbank.org reveals, the structure of African exports is the same today.

  21. Most of Africa’s imports are composed of manufactured products, which constitute approximately 65% of Africa’s imports (UN COMTRADE). Given that African countries have weaker industrial bases and the neoclassical trade theories, Africa’s import basket should rightly contain relatively more manufactured goods imported from regions with more developed and more complex industrial bases.

References

  • Allen T (2014) Information frictions in trade. Econometrica 82(6):2041–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Van Wincoop E (2004) Trade costs. J Econ Lit 42:691–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baier SL, Bergstrand JH (2007) Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? J Int Econ 71(1):72–95

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Taglioni D (2006) Gravity for dummies and dummies for gravity equations. NBER Working Papers, 12516

  • Bertoli S, Moraga JFH (2013) Multilateral resistance to migration. J Dev Econ 102:79–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoli S, Moraga JFH (2016) A practitioners’ guide to gravity models of international migration. World Econ 39(4):496–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertoli S, Moraga JFH, Ortega F (2011) Immigration policies and the Ecuadorian exodus. World Bank Econ Rev 25(1):57–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bettin G, Turco AL (2012) A cross-country view on south-north migration and trade: dissecting the channels. Emerg Markets Finance Trade 48(4):4–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaney T (2011) The network structure of international trade. NBER Working Papers, 16753

  • Dunlevy JA (2006) The influence of corruption and language on the pro-trade effect of immigrants: evidence from the American states. Rev Econ Stat 88:182–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Egger PH, Von Ehrlich M, Nelson DR (2012) Migration and trade. World Econ 35(2):216–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr GJ, Toubal F (2012) Revisiting the trade-migration nexus: evidence from new OECD data. World Dev 40(5):928–937

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr GJ, Jung B, Toubal F (2010) Ethnic networks, information, and international trade: revisiting the evidence. Ann Econ Stat 97(98):41–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felbermayr G, Grossmann V, Kohler W (2012) Migration, international trade and capital formation: cause or effect?. IZA Discussion Papers, IZA DP 6975

  • Gil-Pareja S, Llorca-Vivero R, Martínez-Serrano JA (2014) Do nonreciprocal preferential trade agreements increase beneficiaries’ exports? J Dev Econ 107:291–304

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma S, Yi Z (2002) The link between immigration and trade: evidence from the United Kingdom. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 138(1):115–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gould DM (1994) Immigrant links to the home country: empirical implications for U.S. bilateral trade flows. Rev Econ Stat 76:302–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif A (1993) Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: the Maghribi traders’ coalition. Am Econ Rev 83(3):525–548

    Google Scholar 

  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, Zingales L (2009) Cultural biases in economic exchange? Q J Econ 124(3):1095–1131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson GH (2010) International migration and the developing world. In: Rodrik D, Rosenzweig M (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 4363–4414

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson GH, McIntosh C (2010) The great Mexican emigration. Rev Econ Stat 92(4):798–810

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hatzigeorgiou A (2010) Migration as trade facilitation: assessing the links between international trade and migration. BE J Econ Anal Policy 10:1

    Google Scholar 

  • Head K, Ries J (1998) Immigration and trade creation: econometric evidence from Canada. Can J Econ 31(1):47–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herander MG, Saavedra LA (2005) Exports and the structure of immigrant-based networks: the role of geographic proximity. Rev Econ Stat 87(2):323–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karemera D, Oguledo VI, Davis B (2000) A gravity model analysis of international migration to North America. Appl Econ 32(13):1745–1755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim K, Cohen JE (2010) Determinants of international migration flows to and from industrialized countries: a panel data approach beyond gravity. Int Migr Rev 44(4):899–932

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenig P (2009) Immigration and the export decision to the home country. PSE Working Papers, 2009-31

  • Lucas R (2005) International migration and economic development: lessons from low-income countries. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton

    Google Scholar 

  • Naudé W (2010) The determinants of migration from Sub-Saharan African countries. J Afr Econ 19(3):330–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Naudé W, Bezuidenhout H (2014) Remittances provide resilience against disasters in Africa. Atl Econ J 1:79–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ozden C, Parsons CR, Schiff M, Walmsley TL (2011) Where on Earth is everybody? The evolution of global bilateral migration 1960–2000. World Bank Econ Rev 25(1):12–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedersen PJ, Pytlikova M, Smith N (2008) Selection and network effects—migration flows into OECD countries 1990–2000. Eur Econ Rev 52(7):1160–1186

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Peri G, Francisco R (2010) The trade creation effect of immigrants: evidence from the remarkable case of Spain. Can J Econ 43(4):1433–1459

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE (1996) Trade and search: social capital, sogo shosha, and spillovers. NBER Working Papers, 5618. https://doi.org/10.3386/w5618

  • Rauch JE (1999) Networks versus markets in international trade. J Int Econ 48:7–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE (2001) Business and social networks in international trade. J Econ Lit 39(4):1177–1203

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rauch JE, Trindade V (2002) Ethnic Chinese networks in international trade. Rev Econ Stat 84(1):116–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos Silva JMC, Tenreyro S (2006) The log of gravity. Rev Econ Stat 88(4):641–658

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tai SHT (2009) Market structure and the link between migration and trade. Rev World Econ 145(2):225–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White R (2007) An examination of the Danish immigrant-trade link. Int Migr 45(5):61–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • White R, Tadesse B (2008) Cultural distance and the US immigrant-trade link. World Econ 31(8):1078–1096

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xing Y, Dumont JC, Baruah N (2014) Labor migration, skills & student mobility in Asia. Asian Development Bank Institute, ISBN 978-4-89974-040-7

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Samuel Admassu.

Additional information

I am grateful to Cong Pham, Debdulal Mallick, the editor as well as the anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions. I would also like to thank seminar participants at the Department of Economics of Deakin University for their useful comments and insights on the preliminary version of the paper. The usual disclaimers apply.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 A1. List of countries

Asian Bangladesh, Brunei Darussalam, Cambodia, China, Fiji, Guinea, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Kiribati, Macao SAR, Malaysia, Myanmar, Nepal, Pakistan, Papua New Guinea, Philippines, Samoa, Solomon Islands, Sri Lanka, Thailand, Tonga, Vanuatu and Vietnam.

African Algeria, Angola, Benin, Burkina Faso, Cabo Verde, Cameroon, Central African Republic, Congo, Cote d’Ivoire, Ethiopia, Egypt, Gabon, Gambia, Ghana, Kenya, Liberia, Libya, Madagascar, Malawi, Mali, Mauritania, Mauritius, Morocco, Niger, Nigeria, Senegal, Seychelles, Somalia, Sudan, Togo, Tanzania, Tunisia, Zambia and Zimbabwe.

ROW Argentina, Australia, Austria, Bahamas, Bahrain, Barbados, Belgium, Belize, Bermuda, Bolivia, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cuba, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Dominica, Ecuador, El Salvador, Faroe Islands, Finland, Germany, France, French Guiana, French, Polynesia, Greece, Greenland, Grenada, Guadeloupe, Guatemala, Guyana, Haiti, Honduras, Hungary, Iceland, Iran, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Jamaica, Japan, Jordan, Kuwait, Lebanon, Malta, Martinique, Mexico, Netherlands, New Caledonia, New Zealand, Nicaragua, Norway, Oman, Panama, Paraguay, Peru, Poland, Portugal, Qatar, Republic of Korea, Saint Lucia, St. Vincent and the Grenadines, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, Spain, Suriname, Sweden, Switzerland, Syria, Trinidad and Tobago, Turkey, USA, United Arab Emirates, UK, Uruguay and Venezuela.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Admassu, S. A comparative analysis of African and Asian migrants’ effect on trade. Empir Econ 56, 2079–2092 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1408-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1408-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation