Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Rwanda’s involvement in Eastern DRC: A criminal real options approach

  • Published:
Crime, Law and Social Change Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper applies an alternative model to analyze criminal behaviour by countries based on real option models. Criminal options incorporate a richer framework than traditional cost-benefit models and allow examining the optimal timing of a crime as criminals have the possibility but not the obligation to commit a crime in the near future. From the model, we show how criminal states can actively manage their criminal options. More importantly, we show how the international community can optimally intervene pro-actively, by reducing the incentives for criminal states to execute their criminal options. These novel insights are then applied to two episodes of criminal behaviour by Rwanda in the Democratic Republic of Congo (DRC): the massive killing of Hutu refugees by the Rwanda Patriotic Army (RPA) in late 1996-early 1997 and the illegal exploitation of Congolese resources from August 1998 onwards. This article describes and assesses these activities from this real option perspective.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We use the expression “so-called”, because the “international community” does not really exist. Is it its institutional translation, namely the United Nations? Or does it refer to specific countries with a particular interest in a given situation or the press or vocal NGOs attempting to influence international public opinion? The international community is all of the above, and the notion lacks clarity and allows the actors to escape their responsibilities. However, after this caveat, the expression will be used throughout this article.

  2. More formally, a criminal will maximize the following expected utility function [5]: \( EU=pU\left( {Y-f} \right)+\left( {1-p} \right)U(Y) \), with EU expected utility, p the probability of punishment, U the criminal’s utility function, f the severity of punishment, Y the income if undetected, and Y-f the income if punished.

  3. The time value of an option is the difference between the market value of the option and the intrinsic value.

  4. This is analogous to holding an American call option alive before the maturity date despite the fact that it can be exercised on any moment.

  5. Real-life real option modeling often requires more sophisticated models such as compound option models [8, 9], or numerical approaches. An overview of such models is beyond the scope of the article.

  6. The sixth lever (the risk-free interest rate) is largely exogenous and will be left out of consideration.

  7. The previous footnote also applies here.

  8. It should be noted that this threat also affects persons other than those occupying state functions, such as rebel leaders.

  9. The EU Special Representative for the Great Lakes Region Aldo Ajello has confirmed this information.

  10. According to the then U.S. Ambassador to Kigali Robert Gribbin, already in March 1996 Kagame told him that “if Zaire continues to support the ex-FAR/Interahamwe against Rwanda, Rwanda in turn could find anti-Mobutu elements to support”, adding that “if the international community could not help improve security in the region, the RPA might be compelled to act alone” [18]: 144–145.

  11. The existence of this project was later confirmed by documents discovered in November 1996 in Mugunga refugee camp, where many ex-FAR had regrouped.

  12. U.S. Ambassador in Kigali Gribbin believes that Kagame’s August 1996 visit to Washington ended in a misunderstanding: “Kagame judged that he was honest about Rwanda’s intent to dismantle the camps in the absence of an international undertaking to do so. In turn Secretary of Defense William Perry thought he laid down a clear marker that unilateral action was not advisable. Kagame thought he got an okay. Perry thought he had quashed the idea. Each went away happy” [18]: 175–176.

  13. As we shall see later, it (unsuccessfully) did during the second war.

  14. The report does not just point an accusing finger at Rwanda, but at other players (such as the armies of the DRC, Angola and Uganda, and nonstate armed groups) as well. However, the crimes committed by the Rwandan army were the most serious and widespread.

  15. Thus, for example, did The Washington Post of 3 October 2008 carry a story about the support of the US for the renewal of the contract of one of the indicted officers as deputy commander of the peacekeeping force in Darfur. The article argues that this support was in breach of US legislation outlawing “assistance to human rights violators”. The executive director of Human Rights Watch is quoted as stating that the US position prevents “any effort to hold a senior Rwandan officer accountable for serious atrocities”. Obviously, for Washington this sort of debate raises the issue of the political price it is willing to pay for its support for the Kigali regime.

  16. During the period 2003–2008 period, on average ODA amounted to 26 % of GDP and slightly more than 50 % of the state budget. Of total ODA, budget support type of aid interventions (sector and general budget support as well as HIPC debt relief funds) amounted to slightly more that 40 % on average. For details, see ODI/Mokoro [35].

  17. This section builds upon Reyntjens [39] where more details can be found.

  18. The Panel produced another “Final Report” in October 2003 (see infra).

  19. After Bout’s companies started providing logistical support to US forces in Iraq, he disappeared from the radar screen. Under US pressure, his name was taken off a draft UN list of mercenaries and arms dealers [17]. Cynically enough, Bout was arrested in Thailand in March 2008, on the basis of a US warrant issued for weapons deals with the Colombian FARC rebels.

  20. Aircraft owned by Bout and his frontmen continued to operate in the region during 2004 [52], paras 67, 69, 73, 151.

  21. Several reports point to the direct link between the exploitation of resources and the continuation of the conflict. The UN Panel notes that the control of mineral-rich areas “could be seen primarily as an economic and financial objective rather than a security objective for Rwanda” [49], para. 175; “Most of the fights between Rwandan soldiers and mai-mai have occurred in the so-called ‘coltan belt’” (idem, para. 176). Under the title “Rwanda’s unusual tactics”, the Panel found that “attacks (by the RPA) seem to coincide with the period when coltan has been extracted and put in bags for evacuation by the mai-mai. Attacked, the mai-mai abandon their coltan, which is then taken away by small aircraft” (idem, para. 177).

  22. In 2003, Rwanda produced about 120 metric tonnes of columbite-tantalite concentrates, 284 metric tons of cassiterite, and 109 metric tons of wolframite. These are very small volumes. However, exports amounted to 861, 3,553 and 156 metric tons respectively, still quite small figures, but showing the gap between production and (re-)export (US Geological Survey Minerals Yearbook 2004).

  23. This may seem a modest figure, but in light of the structure of the Rwandan economy, it is gigantic. Indeed in that same year, the production of export crops (mainly coffee and tea) only accounted for 0.4 % of GDP [23]: 80.

  24. Of course, it was not really invisible, but the international community preferred to turn a blind eye to these practices.

  25. This is a very clear example of what in option theory is called a growth option, i.e. an option to do a crime that, once committed, may give rise to other criminal options with additional potential net returns.

  26. Marysse [31] added that “as military spending … was limited as a condition for access to financial flows provided by the Bretton Woods institutions, … wartime plunder has helped finance the conflict”. He denounced the “ostrich policy” of a number of bilateral donors and the International Financial Institutions which, by continuing to fund the invading countries (Rwanda and Uganda) in the knowledge that their aid is fungible, indirectly supported the continuation of the war.

  27. The UN “Panel of experts on the illegal exploitation of natural resources and other forms of wealth in the Democratic Republic of the Congo”, also known as the “Kassem Panel”, has been criticised on account of its methodology and even political bias. However, the facts mentioned in this article are established beyond reasonable doubt and corroborated by several other sources (see e.g., [16, 26]).

  28. The “Congo Desk” had an office called “Production” which oversaw the economic aspects of Rwandan operations in the DRC.

  29. Many civil society sources in North and South Kivu reported Rwandan troop movements, and MONUC openly suspected the presence of the Rwandan army on Congolese soil (see, for instance, [24]).

  30. This unpublished Section V of the report is on file with the editors of this journal.

  31. Letter dated 20 October 2003 from Mahmoud Kassem, chairman of the Panel, to UN Secretary General Kofi Annan. Also this letter is on file with the editors of this journal.

  32. A few examples among many: the already mentioned unit with the telling name “Production” within the Congo Desk of the Rwandan External Security Organisation; the fact that Congolese minerals were exported by Rwanda Metals and Grands Lacs Metals, two companies controlled by the RPF/RPA and that foreign clients were contacted directly by the Congo Desk ([57]: 44); and the fact that the Rwandan embassy in Brussels contacted potential buyers for 32 tons of Papaine looted in the DRC [56]: 137.

  33. This was a structural feature, not linked to the decline as a result of war and genocide in 1990–1994. In 1989, the year before the war started, coffee accounted for US$ 59 million out of total exports worth US$ 97 million.

  34. For an analysis of these and other figures on the mineral trade, see Willum [57].

  35. The UN Panel of Experts adopts a broad interpretation of the concept of illegality. This included all or some of the following: violation of sovereignty, of regulatory frameworks, of widely accepted practices in trade and business, and of international law including “soft law” [49]: para. 15.

  36. “Foreign Troops in Congo Fighting, Rwanda Levels Genocide Charges”, DPA, 28 August 1998, quoted by [30]: 131. In this short sentence, Mazimhaka manages to lie twice: the Rwandan army was already in the DRC and the anti-Tutsi pogroms started after the beginning of the war, and indeed as a reaction to it.

  37. Uganda was less fortunate. It accepted the ICJ’s jurisdiction in a similar case and was found guilty of violating its obligations under a number of international legal instruments, and condemned to making reparations to the DRC [20].

  38. Right at the beginning, it even involved a daring airborne operation in the Bas-Congo, west of Kinshasa, over 1,500 km from Rwanda.

  39. “Congo rebels declare ceasefire, gunfire goes on”, Goma, Reuters, 29 October 2008.

  40. “UN says Rwanda fired tanks at Congo”, Goma, AP, 3 November 2008.

  41. Thus Richard Dowden, the director of the Royal African Society, published an op-ed in The Independent of 15 December 2008 under the title “Britain should cease its one-sided support for Rwanda”. Early March 2009, Canada announced that Rwanda was removed from its list of bilateral beneficiaries (it did not however explicitly link this decision to the UN report).

  42. See also Human Rights Watch, DR Congo: Rwanda Should Stop Aiding War Crimes Suspect. Congolese Renegade General Bosco Ntaganda Receives Recruits and Weapons from Rwanda, Goma, 4 June 2012.

  43. “Rwanda’s Paul Kagame warned he may be charged with aiding war crimes”, The Guardian, 25 July 2012.

References

  1. AFP, Nairobi, 29 January 1997.

  2. AFP, Nairobi, 30 January 1997.

  3. Amran, M. (2003). The Value of Film Studios. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15, 24–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Amran, M., Kulatilaka N. (1999). Real options, Harvard Business School Press, 246 p.

  5. Becker, G. (1968). Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76, 169–217.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Black, F., & Scholes, M. (1973). The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 637–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Carr, P. (1988). The Valuation of Sequential Exchange Opportunities. Journal of Finance, 43, 1235–1256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Cassimon, D., De Backer, M., Engelen, P. J., Van Wouwe, M., & Yordanov, V. (2011). Incorporating Technical Risk in Compound Real Option Models to Value a Pharmaceutical R&D Licensing Opportunity. Research Policy, 40, 1200–1216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Cassimon, D., Engelen, P. J., & Yordanov, V. (2011). Compound Real Option Valuation with Phase-Specific Volatility: a Multi-phase Mobile Payments Case Study. Technovation, 31, 240–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Cooter, R., & Ulen, T. (2000). Law and Economics (p. 445). Reading: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Dietrich, C. (2001). The Commercialisation of Military Deployment in Africa. Pretoria: ISS.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Dietrich, C. (2002). Hard Currency. The Criminalized Diamond Economy of the Democratic Republic of the Congo and its Neighbours, Ottawa, Partnership Africa Canada, Occasional Paper #4, June.

  13. Emizet, K. (2000). The massacre of refugees in Congo: a case of UN peacekeeping failure and international law. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 38, 163–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Engelen, P. J. (2004). Criminal Behavior: A Real Option Approach. With an Application to Restricting Illegal Insider Trading. European Journal of Law and Economics, 17, 329–352.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Feinstein, S., & Lander, D. (2002). A Better Understanding of Why NPV Undervalues Managerial Flexibility. The Engineering Economist, 47, 418–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Global Witness (2009). Natural Resource Exploitation and Human Rights in the Democratic Republic of Congo 1993 to 2003, Briefing Paper, December 2009.

  17. Godoy, J. (2004). Special Report: Wanted in Africa, Needed in Iraq, Paris, IPS, 20 May.

  18. Gribbin, R. E. (2005). In the Aftermath of Genocide. The U.S. Role in Rwanda. New York: iUniverse.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Guerrero, R. (2007). The Case for Real Options Made Simple. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 19, 38–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. International Court of Justice (2005). Case concerning armed activities on the territory of the Congo (Democratic Republic of the Congo v. Uganda), Judgment of 19 December 2005.

  21. International Court of Justice (2006). Case concerning armed activities on the territory of the Congo (Democratic Republic of the Congo v. Rwanda), Judgment of 3 February 2006.

  22. International Crisis Group (2003). The Kivus: the forgotten crucible of the Congo conflict, Nairobi-Brussels, 24 January.

  23. International Monetary Fund (2004). Rwanda: selected issues and statistical appendix, IMF Country Report No. 04/383.

  24. IRIN (2003). “DRC: MONUC denounces obstruction of verification missions in east”, Nairobi, IRIN, 29 October.

  25. Jackson, S. (2002). Making a Killing: Criminality & Coping in the Kivu War Economy. Review of African Political Economy, 29, 517–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Jackson, S. (2003). Fortunes of War: the coltan trade in the Kivus. London: HPG Background Paper. ODI, February 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Jensen, K., & Warren, P. (2001). The Use of Options Theory to Value Research in the Service Sector. R&D Management, 31(2), 173–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Kester, W. (1984). Today’s Options for Tomorrow’s Growth. Harvard Business Review, 62(1), 153–160.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Kulatilaka, N., & Trigeorgis, L. (1994). The general flexibility to switch: Real options revisited. International Journal of Finance, 6, 778–798.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Longman, T. (2002). The Complex Reasons for Rwanda’s Engagement in Congo. In J. F. Clark (Ed.), The African Stakes of the Congo War (pp. 129–144). Palgrave MacMillan: New York-Houndmills.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Marysse, S. (2003). Regress and war: the case of the DR Congo. European Journal of Development Research, 15, 75–99.

    Google Scholar 

  32. McDonald, R., & Siegel, D. (1986). The Value of Waiting to Invest. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 10, 707–727.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Misser, F. (1995). Vers un nouveau Rwanda? Entretiens avec Paul Kagame. Brussels: Luc Pire.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Myers, S., & Majd, S. (1990). Abandonment value and project life. Advances in Futures and Options Research, 4, 1–21.

    Google Scholar 

  35. ODI/Mokoro (2009), Sector Budget Support in Practice. Case Study Education Sector in Rwanda, ODI/Mokoro, November 2009.

  36. Paddock, J., Siegel, D., & Smith, J. (1988). Option valuation of claims on physical assets: the case of offshore petroleum leases. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103, 479–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Pomfret, J. (1997). “Defence Minister Says Arms, Troops Supplied for Anti-Mobutu Drive”, The Washington Post, 9 July.

  38. Posner, R.A. (1998). Economic analysis of law, Aspen Law & Business, 5th edition, 802 p.

  39. Reyntjens, F. (2005). The privatization and criminalization of public space in the geopolitics of the Great Lakes Region. The Journal of Modern African Studies, 43, 587–607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Reyntjens, F. (2009). The Great African War. Congo and Regional Geopolitics, 1996–2006. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  41. Samset, I. (2002). Conflict of Interests or Interests of Conflict? Diamonds & War in the DRC. Review of African Political Economy, 29, 463–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Schwartz, E., & Moon, M. (2000). Rational Pricing of Internet Companies. Financial Analysts Journal, 56, 62–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Sénat de Belgique (2003). Rapport fait au nom de la commission denquête Grands Lacs par MM. Colla et Dallemagne, session 2002–3, 20 February 2003, No. 2 - 942/1.

  44. Trigeorgis, L. (2000). “Real options and financial decision-making”, Contemporary Finance Digest, 5–42.

  45. Trigeorgis, L., & Mason, S. (1987). Valuing managerial flexibility. Midland Corporate Finance Journal, 5, 14–21.

    Google Scholar 

  46. United Nations High Commission for Human Rights (2010). Report of the Mapping Exercise documenting the most serious violations of human rights and international humanitarian law committed within the territory of the Democratic Republic of the Congo between March 1993 and June 2003, Geneva, August 2010.

  47. United Nations Security Council (1998). Report of the Investigative Team Charged with Investigating Serious Violations of Human Rights and International Humanitarian Law in the Democratic Republic of Congo, S/1998/581, 29 June 1998.

  48. United Nations Security Council (2000). Report of the Panel of Experts on Violations of Security Council Sanctions against UNITA, S/2000/203, 10 March 2000.

  49. United Nations Security Council (2001). Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2001/357, 12 April 2001.

  50. United Nations Security Council (2002). Final Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2002/1146, 16 October 2002.

  51. United Nations Security Council (2003). Final Report of the Panel of Experts on the Illegal Exploitation of Natural Resources and Other Forms of Wealth of the Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2003/1027, 23 October 2003.

  52. United Nations Security Council (2005). Report of the Group of Experts on the Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2005/30, 25 January 2005.

  53. United Nations Security Council (2008). Final Report of the Group of Experts on the Democratic Republic of the Congo, S/2008/773, 12 December 2008.

  54. United Nations, Security Council (2012). Addendum to the interim report of the Group of Experts on the Democratic Republic of the Congo (S/2012/348) concerning violations of the arms embargo and sanctions regime by the Government of Rwanda, S/2012/348/Add.1, 27 June 2012.

  55. United States, U.S. Department of State (2012). Findings of the Group of Experts, Press Statement, 30 June 2012.

  56. Willame, J.C. (1997). Banyarwanda et Banyamulenge. Violences ethniques et gestion de lidentitaire au Kivu, Brussels, Paris, Institut Africain-L’Harmattan, Cahiers Africains No. 25.

  57. Willum, B. (2001). Foreign Aid to Rwanda: Purely Beneficial or Contributing to War?, Dissertation Political Science, University of Copenhagen.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Danny Cassimon.

Appendix 1: The Black-Scholes formula for call option valuation

Appendix 1: The Black-Scholes formula for call option valuation

The value of a criminal call option according to the Black-Scholes model can be calculated as:

$$ C=V\,{e^{{-\delta \left( {T-t} \right)}}}\,N\left( {d_1 } \right)-I\,{e^{{-{r_c}\left( {T-t} \right)}}}\,N\left( {d_2 } \right), $$
(A.1)

Where

$$ {d_1}=\frac{{\ln \left( {\frac{V}{I}} \right)+\left( {r_c -\delta +\frac{1}{2}{\sigma^2}} \right)\left( {T-t} \right)}}{{\sigma \sqrt{T-t }}} $$
(A.2)
$$ {d_2}=\frac{{\ln \left( {\frac{V}{I}} \right)+\left( {r_c -\delta -\frac{1}{2}{\sigma^2}} \right)\left( {T-t} \right)}}{{\sigma \sqrt{T-t }}}={d_1}-\sigma \sqrt{T-t }, $$
(A.3)

with

C:

value of a call-option

V:

present value of the expected proceeds of the crime (Y)

I:

expected cost of the crime (p.f)

T-t:

time to expiration (expressed in terms of years)

σ:

annualized standard deviation of the criminal return

rc :

continuous risk-free interest rate

δ:

opportunity cost (expressed in terms of years), and

N(d):

value of d under the cumulative normal probability density function.

The effect of a change in one of the parameters on the value of the call option (the so-called Greeks), i.e., the first derivative, is calculated as follows

Sensitivity of C to:

Name and symbol

Formula and sign of impact on C

Benefits of the crime (Y)

Delta

Δ

\( {e^{{-\delta \,\left( {T-t} \right)}}}\,N\left( {d_1 } \right) > 0 \)

Cost of the crime (p.f)

Psi

Ψ

\( -{e^{{-r\,\left( {T-t} \right)}}}\,N\left( {d_2 } \right) < 0 \)

Lifetime (T-t)

Theta

Θ

\( \begin{array}{*{20}{c}} {\frac{{-Y\:n\left( {{{d}_{1}}} \right)\:\sigma \:{{e}^{{-\delta \:\left( {T-t} \right)}}}}}{{2\:\sqrt{{T-t}}}}-r\:\left( {p.f} \right)\:{{e}^{{-r\:\left( {T-t} \right)}}}\:N\left( {{{d}_{2}}} \right)} \hfill \\ {+\delta \:Y\:N\left( {{{d}_{1}}} \right)\:{{e}^{{-\delta \:\left( {T-t} \right)}}}} \hfill \\ \end{array}>0 \)

Risk-free interest rate (r)

Rho

ρ

\( \left( {p.f} \right)\,\left( {T-t} \right)\,{e^{{-r\,\left( {T-t} \right)}}}\,N\left( {d_2 } \right) > 0 \)

Volatility (σ)

Vega

ν

\( Y\,\sqrt{T-t}\,n\left( {d_1 } \right)\,{e^{{-\delta \,\left( {T-t} \right)}}} > 0 \)

Opportunity cost (δ)

Ksi

Ξ

\( -Y\,\left( {T-t} \right)\,{e^{{-\delta \left( {T-t} \right)}}}\,N\left( {d_1 } \right) < 0 \)

The value N(d1) is the derivative of the standard normal distribution function with respect to d1

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cassimon, D., Engelen, PJ. & Reyntjens, F. Rwanda’s involvement in Eastern DRC: A criminal real options approach. Crime Law Soc Change 59, 39–62 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-012-9397-7

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10611-012-9397-7

Keywords

Navigation