Skip to main content
Log in

Regulated medical fee schedule of the Japanese health care system

  • Published:
International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study presents a theoretical framework for examining the effect of the Japanese government-regulated medical price schedule, ‘Shinryo-Houshu-Seido,’ on the behavior of medical providers. In particular, we discuss the optimal rule of this price schedule for the regulator, taking into account information asymmetry between the regulator and providers. Our simple model predicts that heterogeneous providers either under-provide or over-provide medical inputs in comparison with the socially optimal outcome. Moreover, our results show that when the allocated budget is reduced to a certain level, even the second-best outcome becomes unachievable, no matter how the price schedule is regulated. While the limited budget size is shown to have a clear negative effect on social welfare, we suggest that the prospect of obtaining the second-best outcome is left to negotiation between the regulator and the budget allocator.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The SHS is based on a point system in which the government allocates points to all items covered by the public health insurance.

  2. Wagstaff (2007) summarizes the features of the Japanese health care system in comparison with other Asian countries. See also Tokita (2002); Ikegami and Campbell (1999, 2004), and Naito (2006), for details.

  3. In practice, the fee schedule is revised biennially at the Central Social Insurance Medical Council, which is a committee within the MHLW.

  4. Many theoretical studies examine various issues related to payment systems such as prospective and cost-based payment systems (Newhouse 1983, 1996; Ellis and McGuire 1986, 1988, 1990, 1993; Dranove 1987; Pope 1989; Selden 1990; Allen and Gertler 1991; Glazer and McGuire 1994; Rogerson 1994; Ma 1994; Ma and McGuire 1997; Chalkley and Malcomson 1998; Ellis 1998; Lewis and Sappington 1999; Bos and Fraja 2002; Beitia 2003; Boadway et al. 2004; Mougeot and Naegelen 2005; Siciliani 2006, and Wright 2007). Several studies apply mechanism-design approaches to investigate the health care system with information asymmetry (Lewis and Sappington 1999 and Beitia 2003). See also McGuire (2000), and Dranove and Satterthwaite (2000) for the literature review.

  5. Grabowski and Vernon (1992); Jacobson et al. (2006), and O’Malley et al. (2006) discuss the relationship between the prices of medical inputs and the reimbursement schemes. Ii and Ohkusa (2002) examine the price sensitivity of demand for primary care services in Japan.

  6. Our model contains several similar elements as that of Liu and Ma (2012), such as altruistic physicians and consumers’ illness severity. Their model considers the role of the delegation regime of health insurance, where an insurance company establishes a payment contract with the physician, and an insurance contract with the consumer. However, this system is totally different from the Japanese heath care system. In Japan, central government regulates the prices and the financing system. All citizens are covered by a mandatory employment-based health insurance operating on non-profit basis (see Anabacken (1994)).

  7. Iizuka (2007) also argues that physicians consider more financial burdens of their patients than their own profits. Iizuka (2009) investigates the behavior of pharmaceutical firms which produce generic drugs in the regulated Japanese pharmaceutical market.

  8. We categorize hospitals and physicians as the medical provider in this paper. We do explicitly not consider the relationship between physicians and hospitals, since we believe that such a relationship is less relevant in the Japanese health care system. We do not discuss the behavior of insurers either, since the role of insurers is very limited in the current Japanese system, as pointed out by Tokita (2002). Regarding the relationship between physicians and hospitals, see Tirole (1988) within the context of the vertical control, and also see Pauly and Redisch (1973); Shortell et al. (1985); Custer et al. (1990); Dor and Watson (1995); Boadway et al. (2004), and Crainich et al. (2008).

  9. Our model assumes two medical inputs: one input is cheaper than the other, and it is less effective. An example may be the case of generic and brand-name drugs. Other examples may include the case of an old type and a new type of treatments in terms of various aspects, such as the installment of new medical facilities. The old type is generally cheaper than the new type, and it is less expensive.

  10. The Japanese health care system has mainly been based on the fee-for-service scheme. Many medical services are reimbursed based on the fee-for-service scheme, while there are several hospitals which adopt the prospective reimbursement scheme with the DPC (Diagnosis Procedure Combination) as a framework of Japan’s specific DRG.

  11. This model assumes that a new medical input recovers a patient completely, while an old medical input recovers a patient partially. The ineffectiveness of an old medical input is captured by \(\theta -\alpha \uplambda \), so that more severe patients face a larger payoff loss. There may be some alternative ways. For example, \(h(0,\uplambda )=\theta -\alpha \uplambda \) for an old medical input, and \(h(1,\uplambda )=\theta +\alpha \uplambda \) for a new medical input. This setting implies that the effectiveness of an old medical input is decreasing in the severity of the health status, while that of a new medical input is increasing in the severity of the health status. However, the qualitative implication would be the same as our assumed model. Thus, we simply assume that \(\uplambda \) affects the health-related payoff only when an old medical input is chosen.

  12. In our setting, providers care about the effectiveness of medical inputs they provide as well as the cost (co-payments) of medical inputs which their patients have to pay. The inclusion of patients’ co-payments in the payoff of providers is consistent with the argument of Lundin (2000) that physicians take into account patients’ costs significantly when they prescribe. Iizuka (2007) empirically finds that physicians consider patient’s out-of-pocket costs in the prescription drug market in Japan.

  13. The fee schedule, or points allocated to all items covered by the public health insurance, are revised biennially at the Central Social Insurance Medical Council. Points set to a newly developed, or a brand-name drug, are usually higher than those to an existing one, although the medical effect of a newly developed drug is similar to that of an existing one, in order to cover the research and development cost of the newly developed drug. Furthermore, points set to an existing one is usually decreased at the biennial revision of the fee schedule when a newly developed drug appears. See Ikegami and Campbell (2004) and Iizuka (2007, 2009).

  14. Ihori et al. (2011) evaluate the reforms of the Japanese public health insurance started in year 2006 in the dynamic general equilibrium framework with overlapping generations, where the effect of government deficits is explicitly considered.

  15. To reduce the total amount of reimbursements, the regulator controls prices of medical inputs. This would also affect the pharmaceutical industry. Kurata (2009) points out the relationship between the existing SHS and firms’ profitability and argues that high prices of brand-name drugs have induced strong incentives in the pharmaceutical industry to invest in the development of new and competitive drugs. However, our analysis has not incorporated the role of pharmaceutical firms and the relationship between medical providers and the pharmaceutical industry in Japan, which should be addressed in the future research.

References

  • Allen, R., & Gertler, P. (1991). Regulation and the provision of quality to heterogeneous consumers: The case of prospective pricing of medical services. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 3, 361–375.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anabacken, O. (1994). Japanese hospitals—culture and competition: A study of ten hospitals. International Journal of Health Planning and Management., 9, 87–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beitia, A. (2003). Hospital quality choice and market structure in a regulated duopoly. Journal of Health Economics, 22, 1011–1036.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Boadway, R., Marchand, M., & Sato, M. (2004). An optimal contract approach to hospital financing. Journal of Health Economics, 23, 85–110.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bos, D., & De Fraja, G. (2002). Quality and outside capacity in the provision of health services. Journal of Public Economics, 84, 199–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chalkley, M., & Malcomson, J. M. (1998). Contracting for health services when patient demand does not reflect quality. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 1–19.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Coscelli, A. (2000). The importance of doctors’ and patients’ preferences in the prescription decision. Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 349–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crainich, D., Leleu, H., & Mauleon, A. (2008). The optimality of hospital financing system: The role of physician-manager interactions. International Journal of Health Care Finance and Economics, 8, 245–256.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Custer, W. S., Moser, J. W., Musacchio, R. A., & Willike, R. J. (1990). The production of health care services and changing hospital reimbursement: The role of hospital-medical staff relationships. Journal of Industrial Economics, 9, 167–192.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Dor, A., & Watson, H. (1995). The hospital-physician interaction in U.S. hospitals: Evolving payment schemes and their incentives. European Economic Review, 39, 795–802.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dranove, D. (1987). Rate-setting by diagnosis related groups and hospital specialization. RAND Journal of Economics, 18, 417–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dranove, D., & Satterthwaite, M. A. (2000). The industrial organization of health care markets. In A. J. Culyer & J. P. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (Vol. 1B). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, R. P. (1998). Creaming, skimping and dumping: Provider competition on the intensive and extensive margins. Journal of Health Economics, 17, 537–555.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1986). Provider behaviour under prospective reimbursement. Journal of Health Economics, 5, 129–151.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1988). Insurance principles and the design of prospective payment systems. Journal of Health Economics, 7, 215–237.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1990). Optimal payment systems for health services. Journal of Health Economics, 9, 375–396.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ellis, R. P., & McGuire, T. G. (1993). Supply-side and demand-side cost sharing in health care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7, 135–151.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, R. G. (1974). Supplier-induced demand: Some empirical evidence and implications. In M. Perlman (Ed.), The Economics of Health and Medical Care. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, J., & McGuire, T. G. (1994). Payer competition and cost shifting in health care. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3(1), 71–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grabowski, H. G., & Vernon, J. M. (1992). Brand royalty, entry and price competition in pharmaceuticals after the 1984 drug reform act. Journal of Law and Economics, 35, 331–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hellerstein, J. K. (1998). The importance of the physician in the generic versus trade-name prescription decision. RAND Journal of Economics, 29, 108–136.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ihori, T., Kato, R. R., Kawade, M., & Bessho, S. (2011). Health insurance reform and economic growth: Simulation analysis in Japan. Japan and the World Economy, 23(4), 227–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ii, M., & Ohkusa, Y. (2002). Price sensitivity of the demand for medical services for minor ailments: Econometric estimates using information on illnesses and symptoms. Japanese Economic Review, 53, 154–166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iizuka, T. (2007). Expert’s agency problems: Evidence from the prescription drug market in Japan. RAND Journal of Economics, 38, 844–862.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Iizuka, T. (2009). Generic entry in a regulated pharmaceutical market. Japanese Economic Review, 60, 63–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ikegami, N., & Campbell, J. C. (1999). Health care reform in Japan: The virtues of muddling through. Health Affairs, 18, 56–75.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Ikegami, N., & Campbell, J. C. (2004). Japan’s health care system: Containing costs and attempting reform. Health Affairs, 23, 26–36.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Jacobson, M., O’Malley, A. J., Earle, C. C., Pakes, J., Gaccione, P., & Newhouse, J. P. (2006). Does reimbursement influence chemotherapy treatment for cancer patients? Health Affairs, 25, 437–443.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Kurata, K. (2009). The development of new drugs in the Japanese pharmaceutical industry (in Japanese). RIETI Highlight, 28, 10–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, T., & Sappington, D. (1999). Using subjective risk adjusting to prevent patient dumping in the health care industry. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 8, 351–382.

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, T., & Ma, C.-T. A. (2012). Health insurance, treatment plan, and delegation to altruistic physician. Department of Economics Working Papers, Stony Brook University.

  • Liu, Y.-M., Yang, Y.-H. K., & Hsieh, C.-R. (2009). Financial incentives and physicians’ prescription decisions on the choice between brand-name and generic drugs: Evidence from Taiwan. Journal of Health Economics, 28, 341–349.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Lundin, D. (2000). Moral hazard in physician prescription behavior. Journal of Health Economics, 19, 632–662.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, C.-T. A. (1994). Health care payment systems: Cost and quality incentives. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3, 93–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ma, C.-T. A., & McGuire, T. G. (1997). Optimal health insurance and provider payment. American Economic Review, 87(4), 685–704.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, A. (1985). The theory of the hospital: A review of the models. Social Science and Medicine, 20(11), 1177–1184.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, T. (2000). Physician agency. In A. J. Culyer & J. P. Newhouse (Eds.), Handbook of Health Economics (Vol. 1A). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mougeot, M., & Naegelen, F. (2005). Hospital price regulation and expenditure cap policy. Journal of Health Economics, 24, 55–72.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Naito, H. (2006). The Japanese health-care system and reimbursement for dialysis. Peritoneal Dialysis International, 26, 155–161.

    PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Newhouse, J. P. (1983). Two prospective difficulties with prospective payment of hospitals, or it’s better to be a resident than a patient with a complex problem. Journal of Health Economics, 2, 269–274.

    PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Newhouse, J. P. (1996). Reimbursing health plans and health providers: Efficiency in production versus selection. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 1236–1263.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Malley, A. J., Frank, R. G., Kaddis, A., Rothenberg, B. M., & McNeil, B. J. (2006). Impact of alternative interventions on changes in generic dispensing rates. Health Services Research, 41, 1876–1894.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Pauly, M. V., & Redisch, M. (1973). The not-for-profit hospital as a physicians’ cooperative. American Economic Review, 63, 87–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pope, G. C. (1989). Hospital nonprice competition and medicare reimbursement policy. Journal of Health Economics, 8, 147–172.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba, J. (1994). A skeptic’s view of global budget caps. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8, 67–73.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson, W. P. (1994). Choice of treatment intensities by a non-profit hospital under prospective pricing. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 3, 7–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selden, T. M. (1990). A model of capitation. Journal of Health Economics, 9, 397–409.

    Article  PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Shortell, S., Morrisey, M. A., & Conrad, D. A. (1985). Economic regulation and hospital behavior: The effects on medical staff organization and hospital-physician relationships. Health Services Research, 20, 597–628.

    PubMed  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Siciliani, L. (2006). Selection of treatment under prospective payment systems in the hospital sector. Journal of Health Economics, 25, 479–499.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tokita, T. (2002). The prospects for reform of the Japanese healthcare system. Pharmacoeconomics, 20, 55–66.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Van de Ven, W. P. M. M. (1995). Regulated competition in health care: With or without a global budget? European Economic Review, 39, 786–794.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagstaff, A. (2007). Health systems in East Asia: What can developing countries learn from Japan and the Asian Tigers? Health Economics, 16, 441–456.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Wright, D. J. (2007). Specialist payment schemes and patient selection in private and public hospitals. Journal of Health Economics, 26, 1014–1026.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank all participants in the Health Economics Workshop regularly held at Saku General Hospital, Nagano, Japan, and the Fifth Irvine-Japan Public Policy Conference at University of California, Irvine (March 2009) for their helpful comments and suggestions. The research fund by Promotion and Mutual Aid Corporation for Private Schools is acknowledged. Remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Makoto Kakinaka.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kakinaka, M., Kato, R.R. Regulated medical fee schedule of the Japanese health care system. Int J Health Care Finance Econ 13, 301–317 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-013-9133-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10754-013-9133-6

Keywords

Navigation