Introduction

There is considerable debate on when and how steeply oil production will peak, with a range of estimates from 2004 to 2047 (e.g., Aleklett, 2004; Deffeyes, 2002; Bakhtiari, 2004; Mohr and Evans, 2007; Wells, 2005a, 2005b; Wood, Long, and Morehouse, 2004). The considerable range in peak oil estimates is due to two main factors. The first factor is uncertainty in the conventional oil ultimately recoverable resources (URR), with Bauquis (2003) indicating that estimates typically range from 2 to 3 trillion barrels. The second factor is the different methods for modeling conventional oil production. Oil production is modeled in three distinct ways. Wells (2005a, 2005b), Mohr and Evans (2007), and Deffeyes (2002) used a bell (or Hubbert) curve to model oil production. The second method, used by Aleklett (2004) and Bakhtiari (2004), was a graphical model with limited data as to how the model is created. The last method, used by Wood, Long, and Morehouse (2004), assumed oil production declines with a reserves-to-production (R/P) ratio of 10. The different models create very different production profiles, and hence a wide range of predictions, which ultimately confuse the wider community. Rather than assume a production curve, and attempt to justify its use, this article will endeavor to generate a model based on theory. With the theory explained, we will then determine what the oil production profile looks like.

Review of Literature

Before explaining how the current model works, it is important to look carefully at the theoretical models developed by Reynolds (1999) and Bardi (2005). Reynolds (1999) explains qualitatively how oil discoveries are comparable to the Mayflower problem. Bardi (2005) using this technique explains the model mathematically as:

$$ p(t) = k(t)\frac{URR-C_{\rm d}(t)}{URR}, $$
(1)

where p(t) is the expected discovery percentage, URR is the Ultimate Recoverable Resources (TL), C d(t) is the cumulative discoveries (TL), and k(t) is the technology function, which Bardi (2005) defines as “a simple linear function of the amount of previously found [oil reserves] that starts at 1 and increases proportionally to the total amount of found [oil reserves].” The models of Reynolds (1999) and Bardi (2005) are based on a simplified scenario with Robinson Crusoe digging for buried hardtacks (food).

The work done by Brandt (2007) is statistical. Brandt (2007) obtained production data for many places of various sizes. The result from Brandt’s (2007) research is that the rate difference, Δr, is slightly positive with a median value of 0.05 year−1, which implies that on average the rate of increase is slightly larger than the rate of decrease (see Appendix A).

Model

The model of oil production is determined in several subsections. In the “Discovery” subsection, the amount of oil found in a given year will be determined. It will then be assumed that the amount of oil found each year is located in a single reservoir. The “Reservoir Production” subsection will model oil production in a reservoir by estimating the number of wells in operation and estimating the oil production per well. The world production model is then determined by adding up the oil production of all the reservoirs.

Discoveries

We will assume that finding oil is equivalent to the Mayflower problem, hence the expected discovery percentage function will be determined by Equation (1) (Bardi, 2005). Now the technology function k(t) must be between 0 and 1, in order for the expected discovery percentage to remain bounded between 0 and 1. It is worth noting that some optimists such as Linden (1998) believe that technology makes “marginal hydrocarbon resources” economic. It is also reasonable to assume that the technology function is non-decreasing. Given these constraints we will assume the technology function k(t) as:

$$ k(t) = \left[\hbox{tanh } \left(b_{\rm t}\left(t-t_{\rm t}\right)\right)+1\right]/2, $$

where b t and t t are constants with units (year−1) and (year), respectively. Hence the expected discovery percentage function is:

$$ p(t)= \left[\hbox{tanh}\ \left(b_{\rm t}\left(t-t_{\rm t}\right)\right)+1\right] \frac{URR-C_{\rm d}(t)}{2URR}. $$
(2)

Initially, the expected discovery percentage is low as our knowledge is limited. As time goes by, the expected discovery percentage increases as our knowledge grows, whilst the amount of oil discovered is still small (relative to the URR). Eventually we have good knowledge of where the oil is to be found, but the amount of oil left to be discovered is small (relative to the URR), hence the expected discovery percentage is low. Let C d(t) denote the cumulative discoveries of oil made at the beginning of year t. Now, the amount of oil found in year t equals the expected discovery percentage times the amount of oil left to be found in year t,

$$ C_{\rm d}(t+1)-C_{\rm d}(t) = p(t)(URR-C_{\rm d}(t)). $$
(3)

Now since the expected discovery percentage function p(t) is continuous, we can express Equation (3) in the continuous form as

$$ \frac{dC_{\rm d}(t)}{dt}= p(t) (URR-C_{\rm d}(t)). $$

Substituting Equation (2) for the expected discovery percentage function p(t) we obtain

$$ \frac{dC_{\rm d}(t)}{dt}=\left[\hbox{tanh } \left(b_{\rm t}\left(t-t_{\rm t}\right)\right)+1\right] \frac{(URR-C_{\rm d}(t))^2}{2 URR}. $$
(4)

With the trivial assumption that initially C d(0) = 0, Equation (4) is solved to obtain

$$ C_{\rm d}(t)= URR - \frac{2 b_{\rm t} URR }{2 b_{\rm t} +t b_{\rm t} + \hbox{ln} \left(\frac{{\rm cosh} (b_{\rm t}(t-t_{\rm t}))}{{\rm cosh} (b_{\rm t} t_{\rm t})}\right)}. $$
(5)

Let y d(t) denote the yearly discoveries (TL/year), dC d(t)/dt, then by differentiating Equation (5) we obtain,

$$ y_{\rm d}(t) = \frac{2b_{\rm t}^2URR\left(1+{\rm tanh } (b_{\rm t}(t-t_{\rm t}))\right)} {\left(2b_{\rm t}+tb_{\rm t}+\hbox{ln}\left(\frac{{\rm cosh}(b_{\rm t}(t-t_{\rm t}))} {{\rm cosh}(b_{\rm t}t_{\rm t})}\right)\right)^2}. $$
(6)

Let URR l denote the size of the lth reservoir (TL), which is assumed to be found in the year t l . Now since we assume that the amount of oil found each year is found in a single reservoir, we have

$$ URR_l=y_{\rm d}(t_l). $$

Reservoir Production

To determine the production curve from a reservoir, we will assume that oil production is related to the number of wells drilled, and the production per well. Let \(C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t)\) denote the cumulative production from the lth reservoir (TL). Let w l (t) denote the number of wells in operation at time t. The function w l (t), will be defined by

$$ w_{l}(t) = w_{l_{\rm T}} +(1-w_{l_{\rm T}})e^{-k_{w_{l}}\left(\frac{C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t)}{URR_{l}}\right)}, \quad t\geq t_l $$
(7)

where \(k_{w_{l}}\) is a proportionality constant and \(w_{l_{\rm T}}\) is the total number of wells in operation assuming \(C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t)\) increases to infinity. The boundary condition \(C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t_l)=0\) implies w l (t l ) = 1, hence initially there is only one well built. As cumulative production increases, the number of wells exponentially changes from 1 well to \(w_{l_{\rm T}}\) wells. The total number of wells built is not \(w_{l_{\rm T}}\) but \(w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}\) which is defined as

$$ w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}} = \left\lceil w_{l_{\rm T}}-(w_{l_{\rm T}}-1)e^{-k_{w_{l}}} \right\rceil . $$

Let’s assume that every well in the lth reservoir extracts a total of \(URR_{l}/w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}\) (TL) of oil. Let the ith well start production in the \(t_{l_i}\hbox{th}\) year, where \(t_{l_i}\) is the year such that \(\left\lceil w_{l}(t_{l_i}-1)\right\rceil < i \leq \left\lceil w_{l}(t_{l_i})\right\rceil\) (initially \(t_{l_1}=t_l).\) Let \(C_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}\) denote the cumulative production from well i. Production for an individual well is assumed to be the idealized well explained in Arps (1945). In this case, there is no water injection, and oil production in the ith well, \(P_{l_{i}},\) is proportional to the pressure in the ith well, \(Pr_{{l_i}}.\) Further the pressure in the well is proportional to the remaining amount of oil in the ith well, \((URR_{l}/w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}-C_{p_{l_{i}}}(t-t_{l_i})),\) as shown in Equations (8) and (9) (Arps, 1945):

$$ P_{l_i}(t) = k_{1_{l_i}} Pr_{l_i}(t), $$
(8)
$$ Pr_{l_i}(t) = k_{2_{l_i}} \left( URR_{l}/w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}-C_{p_{l_{i}}}(t)\right). $$
(9)

\(k_{1_{l_i}}\) and \(k_{2_{l_i}}\) are proportionality constants. Equations (8) and (9) can be combined to obtain

$$ P_{l_i}(t) = k_{1_{l_i}}k_{2_{l_i}} \left(URR_{l}/w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}-C_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}(t)\right). $$

Now, \(dC_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}(t)/dt = P_{l_i}(t),\) hence

$$ \frac{dC_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}(t)}{dt} = k_{{\rm p}_{l_i}} \left(URR_{l}/w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}-C_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}(t)\right), $$
(10)

where \(k_{{\rm p}_{l_i}}=k_{1_{l_i}}k_{2_{l_i}},\) and \( C_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}(t_{l_i})=0.\) Now Equation (10) is solved to obtain

$$ C_{{\rm p}_{l_{i}}}(t) = \frac{URR_{l}}{w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}}\left[1-e^{-k_{{\rm p}_{l_i}}(t-t_{l_i})}\right], $$

and differentiating obtains the production curve

$$ P_{l_i}(t) = k_{{\rm p}_{l_i}}\frac{URR_{l}}{w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}}e^{-k_{{\rm p}_{l_i}}(t-t_{l_i})}. $$

Let the initial production of the ith well, in the lth reservoir be \(P_{0_{l_i}},\,\, (P_{l_i}(t_{l_i})=P_{0_{l_i}} \, \forall i)\) then the production curve for the ith well is (Arps, 1945)

$$ P_{l_i}(t) = P_{0_{l_i}} e^{-P_{0_{l_i}}w_{l_{{\rm T}_{\rm act}}}(t-t_{l_i})/URR_{l}}. $$

Hence the cumulative production for the lth reservoir, \(C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t),\) is determined iteratively by

$$ C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t+1) =C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t)+ \sum_{i=1}^{\left\lceil w_{l}(t)\right\rceil}\left(\frac{P_{l_i}(t)+P_{l_i}(t+1)}{2}\right), $$
(11)

with the initial condition \(C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t_l)=0.\) The world’s cumulative production, C p(t), is the sum of the cumulative production of the reservoirs,

$$ C_{\rm p}(t) = \sum_{l} C_{{\rm p}_{l}}(t) $$

For convenience we will assume that all wells in all reservoirs have the same initial production, P 0, that is \(P_0=P_{0_{l_i}},\) and \(k_{\rm w}=k_{{\rm w}_{l}}.\)

Results and Discussion

Bauquis (2003) indicates that URR estimates for conventional oil have remained constant at between 2 and 3 trillion barrels (318–477 TL) for the time period of 1973–2000. A pessimistic case will assume that the URR is 318 TL (2 trillion barrels); the optimistic case will assume the URR to be 477 TL (3 trillion barrels). A third, ideal case is also made where the URR is determined from the actual backdated discoveries data from Wells (2005b). We have several constants which need to be defined. For the discovery model we have URR, t t and b t, for the number of wells model, k w, and \(w_{l_{\rm T}}\) and for the production of a well we need P 0. The variables for the discovery model were calculated by fitting the model to the actual data from Wells (2005b) using the coefficient of determination, R 2 (for more details see Appendix B). The cumulative discoveries as a function of time is shown in Fig. 1.

Figure 1
figure 1

The modeled cumulative discoveries as a function of time (the year 1860 is assumed as the start year t = 0.)

In order to determine valid estimates for k w, \(w_{l_{\rm T}},\) and P 0, it was necessary to find some data. The best literature found to date is from EIA (2007), which has incomplete well and production data for all U.S. states. By analyzing the EIA (2007) data, we assumed P 0 = 18.3 ML/year, k w = 10.7 and \(w_{l_{\rm T}}=0.072 URR_{l}/P_0 ,\) respectively (for more details see Appendix C). With the constants determined, the world model is shown in Fig. 2; and compared to actual production data from BP (2006), DeGolyer and MacNaughton Inc. (2006), CAPP (2006), Williams (2003), and Moritis (2005).

Figure 2
figure 2

The production model compared to the actual data

The resulting model of production matches the production data with a reasonable precision up to the 1979 oil crisis (year 119 in Fig. 2) with an R 2 value in all three cases of greater than 0.98. The theoretical models when fitted to the asymmetric exponential model, have a slightly positive rate difference of Δr ≈ 0.02 year−1, which agrees with the statistical analysis of Brandt (2007), who indicated a median rate difference of Δr = 0.05 year−1 (Appendix A). The theoretical models are approximately symmetrical and have R 2 values of greater than 0.95 when compared to Hubbert curves with the same URR fitted to production data prior to 1979, with the ideal case compared to the Hubbert curve having an R 2 value of 0.995.

The theoretical model was amended by use of a technique in Mohr and Evans (2007) to account for the 1979 oil crisis. The method in Mohr and Evans (2007) has four key components. First, the original theoretical curve is used to model oil production prior to the anomaly (1979 oil crisis). Second, simple linear or lower-order polynomials are fitted to the production data from the anomaly to the present day. Third, a polynomial is used to extend the recent production trend, and smoothly rejoin the original theoretical model in the future. Fourth, the model returns to the original theoretical model, shifted a certain distance into the future to ensure the area under the graph (URR) is the same. Modifying the theoretical production curve using the method in Mohr and Evans (2007) allowed for the 1979 oil crisis to be factored (Appendix D). The amended model, Fig. 3, indicates that the ideal case will peak in 2013, at 13.3 GL/d (83.5 mb/d). The optimistic case peaks in 2025 at 14.1 GL/d (88.8 mb/d), and the pessimistic case peaks in 2010, at 13 GL/d (81.8 mb/d).

Figure 3
figure 3

Results of the modified model compared to the actual production data

Whilst the theoretical model matches the data with reasonable accuracy up to the 1979 oil crisis, R 2 > 0.98, there are several gross simplifications. The assumption that P 0 and k w are constants for all wells and reservoirs is too simplistic. Also, instead of modeling four U.S. states and using these values to estimate P 0 and k w, it would be better to use a set of reservoir data, to determine the average P 0 and k w for each reservoir. Unfortunately, such data are not found.

Conclusion

A model has been developed to model oil production using simple theoretical logic. The model accurately replicates the actual discovery and production trends, whilst remaining theoretical. The model produces a bell curve, which is slightly asymmetric with a slightly larger rate of increase compared to the rate of decrease (Δr ≈ 0.02 year−1). The model validates Hubbert’s empirical model which indicates that oil production follows a symmetric bell curve. The amended theoretical model indicates that conventional oil production will peak somewhere between 2010 and 2025, with the ideal case peaking in 2013, at 13.3 GL/d (83.5 mb/d).