Skip to main content
Log in

Are distance measures effective at measuring efficiency? DEA meets the vintage model

  • Published:
Journal of Productivity Analysis Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper I develop a model of capacity expansion that accounts for differences in the productivity of the installed capital due to technical progress exhibited by the ex ante production function. A putty-clay set-up is assumed, meaning flexible input coefficients and substitution possibilities ex ante, but fixed input coefficients ex post. Based on the model, I generate a capacity distribution of DMUs (vintages) describing an industry with a homogeneous output and perform an efficiency analysis employing data envelopment analysis, a popular non-parametric method for estimating efficiency. The results show that in some circumstances older vintages might appear on the efficiency frontier, unlike some newer vintages that are found to be inefficient, despite benefiting from the advancement of the technology.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Førsund (2010) discusses different concepts of production function in the context of a vintage model which allows for input substitutability before investment, but no such possibilities after investment is realized.

  2. The authors of this paper eventually resort to dynamic clustering, which might alleviate the problem of putty-clay capital installments.

  3. Through ‘vintage effect’ I would like to define all the differences existent between installed capital at different moments in time, especially regarding productivity. This requires the model to specifically account for each vintage.

  4. “If it is assumed (…) that labor and already existing capital are substitutable for each other, then in principle capital should never be idle unless its marginal value product has fallen to zero. (…) Otherwise it would pay to use more capital with the current input of labor; the extra product would provide at least some quasi-rent. Yet we believe there to be such a thing as idle capacity in periods of economic slack. The paradox is easily resolved in a model which permits virtual substitution of labor and capital before capital goods take concrete form, but not after”, Solow (1962b, p. 78).

  5. This assumption practically implies that DMUs are able to adequately predict the available (accumulated or potential) demand, which in turn implies knowledge about the rate of demand growth and about the market shares of other producers.

  6. Although we would be closer to reality by introducing scrapping into the model, the model would become increasingly intractable. For example, one would need to use information about output price, and we want to avoid this.

  7. See the Appendix 2 for details.

  8. There is a wide range of capacity distributions that can be simulated based solely on the parameters underlined in this paper, namely the rate of output demand growth, the rate of technological progress, and the output elasticity of factors.

  9. The concavity of the objective function ensures the uniqueness of the optimal solution.

References

  • Abel BA, Eberly CJ (1999) The effects of irreversibility and uncertainty on capital accumulation. J Monet Econ 44:339–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albrecht JW, Hart AG (1983) A putty-clay model of demand uncertainty and investment. Scand J Econ 85(3):393–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Appa G, e Costa CAB, Chagas MP, Ferreira FC, Soares JO (2010) DEA in X-factor evaluation for the Brazilian Electricity Distribution Industry. Lond Sch Econ. http://www.lse.ac.uk/management/documents/WP-10-121.pdf

  • Banker RD, Charnes A, Cooper WW (1984) Some models for estimating technical and scale inefficiencies in data envelopment analysis. Manag Sci 30:1078–1092

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartelsman E, Doms M (2000) Understanding productivity: lessons from longitudinal microdata. J Econ Lit 38(3):569–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caballero RJ, Pindyck RS (1996) Uncertainty, investment and industry evolution. Int Econ Rev 37:641–662

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell RJ (1998) Entry, exit, embodied technology, and business cycles. Rev Econ Dyn 1:371–408

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charnes A, Cooper WW, Rhodes E (1978) Measuring the efficiency of decision making units. Eur J Oper Res 2:429–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund F (2010) Dynamic efficiency measurement. Indian Econ Rev 45(2):125–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Førsund F, Hjalmarsson L (1987) “Analyses of Industrial Structure: A putty-clay approach” the industrial institute for economic and social research. Almqvist & Wicksell International, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Førsund F, Hjalmarsson L (1988) Choice of technology and long run technical change in energy intensive industries. Energy J 9(3):79–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Førsund F, Hjalmarsson L (1992) Best-practice and average practice: technique choice and energy demand in a vintage model. In: Sterner T (ed) International energy economics. Chapman and Hall, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Førsund F, Hjalmarsson L, Summa T (1996) The interplay between the micro frontier and short-run industry production functions. Scand J Econ 98(3):365–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hjalmarsson L (1973) Optimal structural change and related concepts. Swed J Econ 75:176–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hjalmarsson L (1974) The size distribution of establishments and firms derived from an optimal process of capacity expansion. Eur Econ Rev 5:123–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Houthakker HS (1955) The Pareto distribution and the Cobb–Douglas production function in activity analysis. Rev Econ Stud 22(3):27–31

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen L (1959) Substitution versus fixed production coefficients in the theory of economic growth: a synthesis. Econometrica 27:157–176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen L (1967) Some problems of pricing and optimal choice of factor proportions in a dynamic setting. Economica 34(2):131–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen L (1972) Production functions. an integration of micro and macro, short run, and long run aspects. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Heshmati A, Hjalmarsson L (1997) Temporal patterns of technical efficiency: results from competing models. Int J Ind Organ 15(5):597–616

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manne AS (1961) Capacity expansion and probabilistic growth. Econometrica 29(4):632–649

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps ES (1963) Substitution, fixed proportions, growth and distribution. Int Econ Rev 4(3):265–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter WEG (1960) Productivity and technical change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1962a) Substitution and fixed proportions in the theory of capital. Rev Econ Stud 29(3):207–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1962b) Technical progress, capital formation, and economic growth. Am Econ Rev 52(2):76–86

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Constantin Belu.

Additional information

This paper has greatly benefited from comments and suggestions provided by Lennart Hjalmarsson and I wish to dedicate it to his memory. He was an accomplished scientist and a dear friend. I thank an anonymous reviewer for its many suggestions which arguably improved the paper. The views expressed in this paper are solely mine and do not necessarily reflect the views of my current employers.

Appendices

Appendix 1

When firms expect exponential wage growth, with growth parameter a, then:

$$C_{t} = w_{K} \left( t \right) \cdot K_{t} + \sum\limits_{s = t}^{\infty } {w_{L} \left( s \right)L_{t} \cdot e^{ - rt} } .$$
(8)

However, now w(t) = w 0 · e at, a ≥ 0, where a is the rate of wage growth.

Then the cost the firms face is:

$$C_{t} = w_{K} (t) \cdot K_{t} + L_{t} \sum\limits_{s = t}^{\infty } {w_{0} \cdot e^{(a - r)t} } = w_{K} (t) \cdot K_{t} + w_{0} \cdot L_{t} \frac{{e^{(a - r)t} }}{{1 - e^{(a - r)} }},$$
(9)

where a − r < 0 <=> a < r.

Hence, for the relation above to exist, it is required that the rate of wage growth is always smaller than the discount rate.

Appendix 2

The optimisation programme associated with the investment decision at time t is:

$$\begin{aligned} & \mathop {\hbox{min} }\limits_{{K_{t} ,L_{t} }} C_{t} = w_{K} (t) \cdot K_{t} + \sum\limits_{s = t}^{\infty } {w_{L} (s) \cdot L_{t} \cdot e^{ - rt} } \\ & such \, as \\ & A_{0} \cdot e^{\delta \cdot t} \cdot K_{t}^{\alpha } \cdot L_{t}^{\beta } = Q_{0} \cdot e^{gt} (1 - e^{ - g} ). \\ \end{aligned}$$
(10)

Since

$$\sum\limits_{s = t}^{\infty } {(e^{ - r} )^{s} = \frac{{e^{ - rt} }}{{1 - e^{ - r} }}}$$
(11)

and

$$w_{L} (s) = w_{L} (t),\quad {\text{for}}{\kern 1pt} \, s > t,$$
(12)

the optimisation programme becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} & \mathop {\hbox{min} }\limits_{{K_{t} ,L_{t} }} C_{t} = w_{K} (t) \cdot K_{t} + w_{L} (t) \cdot L_{t} \cdot \frac{{e^{ - rt} }}{{1 - e^{ - r} }} \\ & such \, as \\ & A_{0} \cdot e^{\delta \cdot t} \cdot K_{t}^{\alpha } \cdot L_{t}^{\beta } = Q_{0} \cdot e^{gt} (1 - e^{ - g} ) \\ \end{aligned}$$
(13)

First-order conditions for optimality implyFootnote 9:

$$w_{K} \left( t \right) = \alpha \cdot A_{0} \cdot e^{\delta \cdot t} \cdot K_{t}^{\alpha - 1} \cdot L_{t}^{\beta }$$
(14)
$$w_{L} (t) \cdot \frac{{e^{ - rt} }}{{1 - e^{ - r} }} = \beta \cdot A_{0} \cdot e^{\delta \cdot t} \cdot K_{t}^{\alpha } \cdot L_{t}^{\beta - 1}$$
(15)
$$A_{0} \cdot e^{\delta \cdot t} \cdot K_{t}^{\alpha } \cdot L_{t}^{\beta } = Q_{0} \cdot e^{gt} \left( { 1 - e^{ - g} } \right).$$
(16)

Following this we can write:

$$\frac{{w_{K} (t)}}{{w_{L} (t)}} \cdot \frac{{1 - e^{ - r} }}{{e^{ - rt} }} = \frac{\alpha }{\beta } \cdot \frac{{L_{t} }}{{K_{t} }}.$$
(17)

Substituting L t with \(\frac{{w_{K} (t)}}{{w_{L} (t)}} \cdot \frac{{1 - e^{ - r} }}{{e^{ - rt} }} \cdot \frac{\beta }{\alpha } \cdot K_{t}\), it follows that:

$$K_{t}^{\alpha + \beta } = \frac{{Q_{0} }}{{A_{0} }} \cdot e^{(g - \delta - r\beta ) \cdot t} \cdot \left( {\frac{\alpha }{\beta } \cdot \frac{{w_{L} (t)}}{{w_{K} (t)}}} \right)^{\beta } \cdot \frac{{(1 - e^{ - g} )}}{{(1 - e^{ - r} )^{\beta } }}.$$
(18)

Hence, the optimal instalment will be:

$$K_{t}^{*} = \left( {\frac{{Q_{0} }}{{A_{0} }}} \right)^{1/\varepsilon} \cdot e^{{\left( {\frac{g - \delta - r\beta }{\varepsilon }} \right) \cdot t}} \cdot \left( {\frac{\alpha }{\beta } \cdot \frac{{w_{L} (t)}}{{w_{K} (t)}}} \right)^{\beta/\varepsilon} \cdot \frac{{(1 - e^{ - g} )^{1/\varepsilon}}}{{(1 - e^{ - r} )^{\beta/\varepsilon}}},\quad {\text{where}}\,\,\varepsilon { = }\alpha { + }\beta.$$
(19)

Similarly:

$$L_{t}^{*} = \left( {\frac{{Q_{0} }}{{A_{0} }}} \right)^{{{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \varepsilon }}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$\varepsilon $}}}} \cdot e^{{\left( {\frac{g - \delta - r\alpha }{\varepsilon }} \right) \cdot t}} \cdot \left( {\frac{\beta }{\alpha } \cdot \frac{{w_{K} (t)}}{{w_{L} (t)}}} \right)^{{{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$\alpha $} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {\alpha \varepsilon }}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$\varepsilon $}}}} \cdot \frac{{(1 - e^{ - g} )^{{{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$1$} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {1 \varepsilon }}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$\varepsilon $}}}} }}{{(1 - e^{ - r} )^{{{\raise0.7ex\hbox{$\alpha $} \!\mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {\alpha \varepsilon }}\right.\kern-0pt} \!\lower0.7ex\hbox{$\varepsilon $}}}} }}.$$
(20)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Belu, C. Are distance measures effective at measuring efficiency? DEA meets the vintage model. J Prod Anal 43, 237–248 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0438-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11123-015-0438-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation