Skip to main content
Log in

Exploring the nature of inter-country interactions in the process of ratifying international environmental agreements: the case of the Kyoto Protocol

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

International environmental agreements require negotiation and cooperation among countries. This paper attempts to analyze the presence and nature of inter-country interactions in the process of ratifying such agreements. We develop a theoretical argument based on the notions of strategic substitutability and strategic complementarity and study the interactions among three different peer types: geographic neighbors, trading partners and green investment projects partners (in our case, clean development mechanism projects partners). We test for the presence of interactions by taking into account a temporal dimension, which constitutes a methodological contribution. To this end, we introduce spatially lagged endogenous variables into a parametric survival model and apply the proposed framework to the Kyoto Protocol ratification process. Our data sample covers 164 countries for the period 1998 to 2009. We find evidence that, while countries’ ratification decisions are basically strategic substitutes, they become strategic complements once we focus on the ratification decisions of specific peers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The green development projects considered in this paper are the projects contemplated by the clean development mechanism.

  2. Beron et al. (2003) used several matrices to take interactions into account. However, they run a cross-sectional analysis. In addition, the focus of their study was the Montreal Protocol, and we are not convinced that participation in this treaty can be analyzed as cooperative behavior. Indeed, Murdoch and Sandler (1997) explain that the use of CFC substitutes was probably economically profitable.

  3. Among many other newspaper articles, see Osborn (2001) and Rohter and Revkin (2004).

  4. Indeed, we are attempting to understand why countries participate in the KP, not to explain their level of participation, which would have been measured by the decrease in greenhouse gas emissions pledged by the countries. For a study of the level of participation in IEAs, see, for example, Bratberg et al. (2005). Note also that the nature of interactions can be different at the ratification stage and at the participation level stage of an IEA, as shown by Murdoch et al. (2003).

  5. The country does not ignore the participation of other countries, but does not consider that the ratification decision has an impact on other domains, such as trade, as developed further in the paper.

  6. LRTAP stands for Long Range Transboundary Air Pollution.

  7. According to Barrett (2011:1866), leakages occur because the reduction in emissions from some countries will lead to a change in comparative advantages, which will cause other countries to increase their emissions. He defines the leakage rate as follows: “Suppose there are N countries, and that n of these take actions to limit their emissions. The reduction in emissions by the n countries is x (measured in tons), but these actions cause emissions in the Nn other countries to increase by X. The leakage rate is then X/x.”

  8. In the end, the parties reached a compromise. New Zealand ratified on the 19th of December 2002 while the new parliament was elected on the 27th of July. However, as stated on the New Zealand Ministry for the Environment’s official website, “New Zealand’s commitment under the KP is to return emissions to 1990 levels on average over the commitment period (2008–2012).” It therefore amounts to a ratification but only with a commitment to keep emissions at 1990 levels, whereas most other ratifying countries committed to reduce their emissions more dramatically.

  9. Note that strategic complementarity may also occur in cutting greenhouse gas emissions, as shown by Copeland and Taylor (2005).

  10. This mechanism works by the following principle. A developed country that ratifies the KP gets registered as an Annex 1 country and consequently receives emission reduction targets. To meet these targets, a country can decrease its carbon emissions on its own territory or resort to a flexibility mechanism, such as the CDM. The main rules governing this mechanism were defined at the seventh Conference of the Parties to the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) held in Marrakesh in 2001 (Lecocq and Ambrosi 2007). The principle is to finance an emissions-reduction project in a developing country, which can lead to the creation of saleable certified emission reduction credits (each credit is equivalent to one metric ton of CO2).

  11. See Dechezleprêtre et al. (2008, 2009) for a finer-grained study of the characteristics of these technological transfers.

  12. The CEPII is the French Center for Research and Studies on the World Economy. Their distance database can be found at: http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/distances.htm.

  13. We use export data from the UN Comtrade database: X ij is the mean of the available bilateral exports for the sample period.

  14. UNEP-Risø is the United Nations Environment Program research center located in Risø, Denmark.

  15. The projects are not registered in the CDM pipeline before ratification by the developed country. However, projects can be in the preparation phase, and we assume that a developing country is able to identify the source of funding. Therefore we consider the number of CDM projects to be a proper weighting factor.

  16. http://www.freedomhouse.org/.

  17. Technically, we are dealing with single spell data (only one ratification per country), and with a right-censored sample (some countries had not yet ratified the KP at the end of the studied period).

  18. See Lancaster (1992), Box-Steffensmeier and Jones (2004), Kleinbaum and Klein (2005) and Cleves et al. (2010) for good introductions to duration models, which the literature variously terms as transition data, survival models or event-history analysis.

  19. Two factors can explain the 2002 peak in ratifications. First, the European Union ratified the KP on May 31 2002 (meaning that 15 countries ratified simultaneously). Second, the Marrakesh Accords were adopted in 2001. During these accords, the member countries allowed the implementation of the CDM, following which we observed the ratification of countries that now are major CDM hosts, such as Brazil (August 23 2002), India (August 26 2002) and China (August 28 2002).

  20. Note that the latter is the counterpart of the error term in standard regression. These two terms will be used interchangeably throughout the rest of the paper.

  21. The Akaike information criterion is defined as AIC=−2lnL+2(α+β), where L is the log-likelihood of the estimation, α is the number of explanatory variables and β is the number of specific distributions.

  22. The inverse-Gaussian distribution is used for the frailty parameters, selected for its mathematical tractability. The frailty is assumed to have mean 1 and variance θ for model identifiability.

  23. To give perspective, an example of the interpretation of the magnitude of the coefficient in traditional survival models is given.

  24. The online Appendices can be accessed at: supplementary_material.

  25. To give perspective, in traditional survival models, the magnitude of the coefficient would be read as follows: an increase in the democracy level by 1—from “Non-Free” to “Partly-Free” or from “Partly-Free” to “Free”—is associated with a 55 % increase in the hazard (see Cleves et al. 2010:131 & 234). However, as stated in Sect. 3.4, coefficients in spatial models cannot be interpreted directly.

  26. Our variable allows us only to distinguish between autocratic and democratic countries. As mentioned, see the work of Fredriksson and Wollscheid (2007) for an interesting development of the “environment—political regime” relationship.

  27. An additional robustness check implemented but not reported is a change in the definition of ratification year. Ratification of the KP is officially validated on a specific date. Therefore, when two countries have ratified the protocol during year t, there could be 364 days between their ratifications. It is thus useful to take a different definition of ratification year. We therefore considered that a country ratifies at time t if it ratified between the 1st of July of year t−1 and the 30th of June of year t. We then re-estimated the same equations presented in Table 2 of the paper. Our results are robust to this change.

  28. However, note that the results of column (3) in Table 3 should be taken with caution. Since EU countries are the main financiers of CDM projects, only four credit buyers (Canada, Japan, Norway and Switzerland) are left in the sample when we drop them.

  29. The online Appendices can be accessed at: supplementary_material.

References

  • Anselin, L. (1988). Studies in operational regional science. Spatial econometrics: methods and models. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Anselin, L. (2006). Spatial econometrics. In T. C. Mills & K. Patterson (Eds.), Palgrave handbook of econometrics: Vol. 1: Econometric theory (1st ed., pp. 901–969). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, S., Gelfand, A. E., & Carlin, B. P. (2003). Monographs on statistics and applied probability: hierarchical modeling and analysis for spatial data (1st ed.). London: Chapman and Hall/CRC.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2003). Environment and statecraft: the strategy of environmental treaty-making. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2006). Climate treaties and “breakthrough” technologies. American Economic Review—Paper and Proceeding, 96(2), 22–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2009). The coming global climate-technology revolution. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 53–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett, S. (2011). Rethinking climate change governance and its relationship to the world trading system. World Economy, 34(11), 1863–1882.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2010). A comparison of international and domestic sources of global governance dynamics. British Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 509–538.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beron, K. J., Murdoch, J. C., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). Why cooperate? Public goods, economic power, and the Montreal Protocol. Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 286–297.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Box-Steffensmeier, J. M., & Jones, B. S. (2004). Analytical methods for social research: event history modeling: a guide for social scientists (1st ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Boyd, E., Hultman, N., Roberts, J. T., Corbera, E., Cole, J., Bozmoski, A., Ebeling, J., Tippman, R., Manna, P., Brown, K., & Liverman, D. M. (2009). Reforming the CDM for sustainable development: lessons learned and policy futures. Environmental Science & Policy, 12, 820–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bratberg, E., Tjøtta, S., & Øines, T. (2005). Do voluntary international environmental agreements work? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 50(3), 583–597.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner, J. (2003). Strategic interaction among governments: an overview of empirical studies. International Regional Science Review, 26(2), 175–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case, A. C., Rosen, H. S., & Hines, J. (1993). Budget spillovers and fiscal policy interdependence: evidence from the States. Journal of Public Economics, 52(3), 285–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cleves, M., Gould, W., Gutierrez, R., & Marchenko, Y. (2010). An introduction to survival analysis using Stata (3rd ed.). College Station: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. D. (1992). Political institutions and pollution control. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(3), 412–421.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2005). Free trade and global warming: a trade theory view of the Kyoto Protocol. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 49(2), 205–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornes, R., & Sandler, T. (1996). The theory of externalities, public goods, and club goods (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Darmofal, D. (2009). Bayesian spatial survival models for political event processes. American Journal of Political Science, 53(1), 241–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechezleprêtre, A., Glachant, M., & Ménière, Y. (2008). The clean development mechanism and the international diffusion of technologies: an empirical study. Energy Policy, 36(4), 1273–1283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dechezleprêtre, A., Glachant, M., & Ménière, Y. (2009). Technology transfer by CDM projects: a comparison of Brazil, China, India and Mexico. Energy Policy, 37(2), 703–711.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dubin, R. (1995). Estimating logit models with spatial dependence. In L. Anselin & R. J. G. M. Florax (Eds.), New directions in spatial econometrics (pp. 229–242). Berlin: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Dubin, R. (1997). A note on the estimation of spatial logit models. Geographical Systems, 4(2), 181–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ederington, J. (2002). Trade and domestic policy linkage in international agreements. International Economic Review, 43(4), 1347–1368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eldar, O. (2008). Vote-trading in international institutions. European Journal of International Law, 19(1), 3–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esty, D. C. (2001). Bridging the trade-environment divide. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(3), 113–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Folmer, H., Mouche, P. V., & Ragland, S. (1993). Interconnected games and international environmental problems. Environmental & Resource Economics, 3(4), 313–335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (1999). The importance of trade for the ratification of the 1992 climate change convention. In Trade, global policy, and the environment (World Bank Discussion Paper 402). Washington: World Bank Publications.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (2000). Ratification of the 1992 climate change convention: what determines legislative delay? Public Choice, 104(3–4), 345–368.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G., Neumayer, E., & Ujhelyi, G. (2007). Kyoto Protocol cooperation: does government corruption facilitate environmental lobbying? Public Choice, 133(1), 231–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fredriksson, P. G., & Wollscheid, J. (2007). Democratic institutions versus autocratic regimes: the case of environmental policy. Public Choice, 130(3), 381–393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1984). The public choice view of international political economy. International Organization, 38(1), 199–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glazer, A., & Proost, S. (2008). Informational benefits of international environmental agreements. Open access publications from Katholieke Universiteit Leuven (Number 123456789/183997).

  • Gleditsch, K., & Ward, M. (2001). Measuring space: a minimum distance database and applications to international studies. Journal of Peace Research, 38(6), 739–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gutierrez, R. G. (2002). Parametric frailty and shared frailty survival models. Stata Journal, 2(1), 22–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guzman, A. T. (2008). How international law works: a rational choice theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hoel, M., & Schneider, K. (1997). Incentives to participate in an international environmental agreement. Environmental & Resource Economics, 9(2), 153–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleinbaum, D. G., & Klein, M. (2005). Survival analysis: a self-learning text. Berlin: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, T. (1992). Econometric society monographs: the econometric analysis of transition data. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lecocq, F., & Ambrosi, P. (2007). The clean development mechanism: history, status, and prospects. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 1(1), 134–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • LeSage, J., & Dominguez, M. (2012). The importance of modeling spatial spillovers in public choice analysis. Public Choice, 150(3–4), 525–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lockwood, B., & Migali, G. (2009). Did the single market cause competition in excise taxes? Evidence from EU countries. Economic Journal, 119(536), 406–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., & Sandler, T. (1997). The voluntary provision of a pure public good: the case of reduced CFC emissions and the Montreal Protocol. Journal of Public Economics, 63(3), 331–349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., Sandler, T., & Sargent, K. (1997). A tale of two collectives: sulphur versus nitrogen oxides emission reduction in Europe. Economica, 64(254), 281–301.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murdoch, J. C., Sandler, T., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). The participation decision versus the level of participation in an environmental treaty: a spatial probit analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 87(2), 337–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumayer, E. (2002a). Do democracies exhibit stronger international environmental commitment? A cross-country analysis. Journal of Peace Research, 39(2), 139–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neumayer, E. (2002b). Does trade openness promote multilateral environmental cooperation? World Economy, 25(6), 815–832.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborn, A. (2001). Europe should now push Kyoto. The Guardian, April 6.

  • Paulsson, E. (2009). A review of the CDM literature: from fine-tuning to critical scrutiny? International Environmental Agreement: Politics, Law and Economics, 9(1), 63–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rohter, L., & Revkin, A. C. (2004). Cheers, and concern, for new climate pact. The New York Time, December 13.

  • Rose, A. K., & Spiegel, M. M. (2009). Noneconomic engagement and international exchange: the case of environmental treaties. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 41(2–3), 337–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandler, T. (1998). Global and regional public goods: a prognosis for collective action. Fiscal Studies, 19(3), 221–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, B. A., & Elkins, Z. (2004). The globalization of liberalization: policy diffusion in the international political economy. American Political Science Review, 98(1), 171–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spagnolo, G. (1999). Issue linkage, delegation, and international policy cooperation. SSRN eLibrary.

  • Tollison, R. D., & Willett, T. D. (1979). An economic theory of mutually advantageous issue linkages in international negotiations. International Organization, 33(04), 425–449.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Von Stein, J. (2008). The international law and politics of climate change: ratification of the United Nations Framework Convention and the Kyoto Protocol. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(2), 243–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2001). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data (1st ed.). Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, J. (2004). New-Zealand and the Kyoto Protocol: ideals, interests and politics. New Zealand International Review, 29(3), 6–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhang, J., & Wang, C. (2011). Co-benefits and additionality of the clean development mechanism: an empirical analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 62(2), 140–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are indebted to two anonymous referees and to the Editor in Chief of this journal William F. Shughart II, for their numerous and valuable comments. We would also like to thank Céline Agoutin, Simone Bertoli, Pascale Combes-Motel, Nelly Exbrayat, Shannon Harvey, Franck Lecocq, Peter Reed, Matthias Rieger, Grégoire Rota-Graziosi, and the participants of the 2011 Economic Development PhD seminar held in Orleans (France) for their useful comments and inputs. All remaining errors are our own. We would also like to thank the “Conseil Regional d’Auvergne” for providing financial support.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alexandre Sauquet.

Electronic Supplementary Material

Below are the links to the electronic supplementary material.

(PDF 192 kB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Sauquet, A. Exploring the nature of inter-country interactions in the process of ratifying international environmental agreements: the case of the Kyoto Protocol. Public Choice 159, 141–158 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0033-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0033-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation