Skip to main content
Log in

Absorptive capacity and R&D tax policy: Are in-house and external contract R&D substitutes or complements?

  • Published:
Small Business Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Firms fund research and development (R&D) to generate commercializable innovations and to increase their ability to understand and absorb knowledge from elsewhere. This dual role and opposed incentive structure of internal R&D create a significant question for both theory and R&D policy: Is internal R&D a complement or substitute for external R&D? We develop a model and novel technique for empirically estimating R&D substitution elasticities. We focus on bio-pharmaceutical and software industries in California and Massachusetts, where tax credit rates changed differently over time for the two types of R&D, creating a natural experiment. The effective tax prices for the two R&D types differ from type to type, firm to firm, state to state, and year to year. This allows us to examine changes in the composition of firms’ R&D budgets between in-house R&D and external basic research when the relative tax prices of each category of research change. We find evidence of a substitute relationship both for a sample comprising exclusively small firms as well as for a more general distribution of firm sizes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Arora, A., & Gambardella, A. (1994). Evaluating technological information and utilizing it: Scientific knowledge, technological capability and external linkages in biotechnology. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 24(1), 91–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention. In The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton University Press.

  • Berndt, E. R. (1991). The practice of econometrics: Classic and contemporary. Reading: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (1999). Make and buy in innovation strategies: Evidence from Belgian manufacturing firms. Research Policy, 28(1), 63–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cassiman, B., & Veugelers, R. (2006). In search of complementarity in the innovation strategy: Internal R&D and external knowledge acquisition. Management Science, 52(1), 68–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cockburn, I. M., & Henderson, R. M. (1998). Absorptive capacity, coauthoring behavior and the organization of research in drug discovery. Journal of Industrial Economics, 46(2), 157–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, W. M., & Leventhal, D. A. (1990). Absorptive capacity: A new perspective on learning and innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 128–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Commerce Clearing House (CCH) (2000–2003). http://www.tax.cch.com/primesrc/bin/highwire.dll

  • David, P., Hall, B., & Toole, P. (2000). Is public R&D a complement or substitute for private R&D? A review of the econometric evidence. Research Policy, 29, 497–529.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diewert, W. E. (1971). An application of the Shephard duality theorem: A generalized Leontief production function. The Journal of Political Economy, 79(3), 481–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric Analysis (4th ed.), Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1979). Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1), 92–116.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches, Z. (1986). Productivity, R and D, and basic research at the firm level in the 1970s. The American Economic Review, 76(1), 141–54.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, B., & Wosinska, M. (1999). Effectiveness of the California R&D tax credit. Sacramento: California Council on Science and Technology.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamel, G., & Prahalad, C. K. (1994). Competing for the future. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hines, J. R. (1991). On the sensitivity of R&D to delicate tax changes: The behavior of U.S. multinationals in the 1980s. Working paper 3930. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge.

  • Hines, J. R. (1993). No place like home: Tax incentives and the location of R&D by American multinationals. Working paper 4574. National Bureau of Economic Research. Cambridge.

  • Humphrey, D., & Moroney, J. (1975). Substitution among capital, labor, and natural resource products in American manufacturing. Journal of Political Economy, 83(1), 57–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe, A. B. (1996). Economic analysis of research spillovers: Implications for the advanced technology program. NIST grant/contract report 97–708. National Institute of Standards and Technology. Gaithersburg.

  • Kmenta, J. (1967). On estimation of the CES production function. International Economic Review, 8(2), 180–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • KPMG International. 1997–1999. Corporate tax rate surveys. http://www.in.kpmg.com

  • Lane, P. J., & Lubatkin, M., (1998). Relative absorptive capacity and inter-organizational learning. Strategic Management Journal, 19(5), 417–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mansfield, E. (1980). Basic research and productivity increases in manufacturing. The American Economic Review, 70(5), 863–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mowery, D. C., & Oxley, J. E. (1995). Inward technology transfer and competitiveness: The role of national innovation systems. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19, 67–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Science Foundation (2000). Division of science resources studies. In Research and Development in Industry: 1998. NSF 01—305. Arlington, VA.

  • National Science Foundation (1993, 1995, 1997, 1999, 2001, 2003). Surveys of industrial research and development. http://www.nsf.gov/statistics/industry/

  • Nelson, R. (1959). The simple economics of basic scientific research. Journal of Political Economy, 67(3), 297–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicholls-Nixon, C. (1993). Absorptive capacity and technological sourcing: Implications for the responsiveness of established firms. Purdue University Dissertation. West Lafayette.

  • Paff, L. (2004). Does the alternate incremental credit affect firm R&D? Technovation, 24, 41–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paff, L. (2002). The effectiveness of state-level R&D tax credits: An evaluation based on 10-K and Compustat data. Bethlehem: Lehigh University Dissertation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paff, L., & Watkins, T. A. (2006). What is the after-tax price of R&D? An inter-state comparison based on R&D tax credits, corporate tax rates, and income apportionment, using firm-level data. Eastern Economic Association annual conference. Philadelphia, February 24–26.

  • Pavitt, K. (2001). Public policies to support basic research: What can the rest of the world learn from US theory and practice? (And what they should not learn). Industrial and Corporate Change, 10(3), 761–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technical change. Journal of Political Economy, 98, S71–S102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenberg, N. (1990). Why do firms do basic research (with their own money)? Research Policy, 19(2), 165–74.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salter, A. J., & Martin, B. R. (2001). The economic benefits of publicly funded basic research: A critical review. Research Policy, 30(3), 509–32.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santoro, M., & Chakrabarti, A. (2002). Firm size and technology centrality in industry–university interactions. Research Policy, 31(7), 1163–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Securities and Exchange Commission. (1999). EDGAR database. http://www.sec.gov/edgar.shtml

  • Solow, R. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. Review of Economic Statistics, 39(3), 312–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steele, L. (1989). Managing technology. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tassey, G. (1997). The economics of R&D policy. Westport: Quorum Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece, D. J., & Pisano, G. (1994). The dynamic capabilities of firms: An introduction. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(3), 537–56.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa, H. (1964). Duality principles in the theory of cost and production. International Economic Review, 5(2), 216–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van den Bosch, F. A. J., van Wijk, R. A., & Volberda, H. W. (2003). External knowledge, absorptive capacity, and firm performance. In M. Easterby-Smith & M. Lyles (Eds.), Companion to organisational learning and knowledge. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watkins, T. A. (1991). A technological communications costs model of R&D consortia as public policy. Research Policy, 20(2), 87–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seeming unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57(298), 348–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lolita Anna Paff.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Watkins, T.A., Paff, L.A. Absorptive capacity and R&D tax policy: Are in-house and external contract R&D substitutes or complements?. Small Bus Econ 33, 207–227 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9094-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-007-9094-6

Keywords

JEL Classifications

Navigation