Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Fiscal deficit and inflation linkages in India: tracking the transmission channels

  • Research Paper
  • Published:
Journal of Social and Economic Development Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Fiscal deficit and inflation are the two major macroeconomic problems confronting the Indian economy. Although it had manifested in various degrees earlier, these problems escalated after the recent global financial crisis. It has always been criticized that fiscal deficit will adversely impact the level of inflation. This critique has been proved and validated by many existing studies in the context of India. This paper strives to track the channels of transmission through which fiscal deficit has passed on and impacted the level of inflation in India. Based on theoretical and empirical literature, this study identifies four transmission channels, namely consumption expenditure channel, money supply channel, import channel and interest rate channel. By adopting structural vector autoregression model, it has been found that the fiscal deficit transmission mechanism is clearly evident with regard to consumption channel, money supply channel and import channel but not the interest rate channel.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Data source RBI (2015)

Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The results of ADF unit root test and KPSS unit root test are presented in Appendix 1.

References

  • Almeida Marcelo (2012) The transmission mechanism of fiscal policy in an open economy under the VAR framework. School of Economics Discussion Paper, University of Surrey, Surrey

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach AJ, Gorodnichenko Y (2011) Measuring output response to fiscal policy. NBER Working Paper No. 16311, NBER, Cambridge

  • Balakrishnan Pulapre (1997) Public finance- policy issues for India. Oxford University Press, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Ball RJ (1964) Inflation and theory of money. George Allen and Unwin Ltd, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Perotti R (2002) An Empirical characterisation of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. Q J Econ 117(4):1329–1368

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Business Line (2000, September 23) Narasimham-Tarapore Committee Report- Breaking New Ground in Monetary Policy, The Hindu Business Line, Financial Daily, India

  • Caldara D, Kamps C (2008) What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks? A VAR based comparative analysis. ECB Working Paper No. 877, European Central Bank

  • Chakraborty L (2012) Determination of interest rate in India: empirical evidence on fiscal deficit-interest links and financial crowding out. NIPFP Working Paper No. 112, NIPFP, New Delhi

  • Curwen PJ (1976) Inflation. The Macmillan Press Ltd, London

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Das S (2004) Effects of fiscal deficits on real interest rate. Econ Polit Week 39(12):1299–1310

    Google Scholar 

  • Enders Walter (2004) Applied econometric time series. Wiley, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Goyal R (2004) Does higher fiscal deficit lead to higher interest rates? An empirical analysis. Econ Polit Week 39(21):2128–2133

    Google Scholar 

  • Goyal A, Sharma B (2015) Government expenditure in India: composition, cyclicality and multipliers. IGIDR Working Paper No. 32. IGIDR, Mumbai

  • Gupta AS, Gupta RS (2014) Is India ready for inflation targeting? IGIDR Working Paper No. 19, IGIDR, Mumbai

  • Haldrup N, Jansson M (2005) Improving size and power in unit root testing. Working Paper No. 2. Department of Economics, University of Aarhus, Denmark

  • Heller PS (1980) Impact of inflation on fiscal policy in developing countries. IMF Staff Papers, 27(4), IMF

  • Jain R, Kumar P (2013) Size of government expenditure multipliers in India: a structural VAR analysis. RBI Working Paper No. 7, Department of Economic and Policy Research, RBI, Mumbai

  • Khundrakpam JK, Goyal R (2008) Is the government deficit in India still relevant for stabilisation? Reserve Bank India Occas Pap 29(3):1–21

    Google Scholar 

  • Khundrakpam JK, Pattanaik S (2010) Fiscal stimulus and potential inflationary risks- an empirical assessment of fiscal deficit and inflation relationship in India. J Econ Integr 25(4):703–721

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lozano Ignacio (2008) Budget deficit, money growth and inflation: evidence from the Columbian case. Borradores De Economia 537:1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Lutkepohl H, Kratzig M (2004) Applied time series econometrics. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Milo P (2012) The impact of the budget deficit on the currency and inflation in the transition economies. J Cent Bank Theory Pract 25–57

  • Mohanty D, John J (2014) Determinants of inflation in India. J Asian Econ. doi:10.1016/j.asieco.2014.08.002

    Google Scholar 

  • Mountford A, Uhliq H (2008) What are the effects of fiscal policy shocks? NBER Working Paper No. 14551, NBER, Cambridge

  • Parida PC, Mallik H, Mathiyazhagan MK (2001) Fiscal deficits, money supply and price level: empirical evidence from India. J Indian Sch Polit Econ 13(4):583–593

    Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R (2007) In search of the transmission mechanism of fiscal policy. NBER Working Paper No. 13143, NBER, Cambridge

  • Raj J, Khundrakpam J, Das D (2011) An empirical analysis of monetary and fiscal policy interaction in India. RBI Working Paper No-15, Department of Economic and Policy Research, RBI, Mumbai

  • Renu K (2001) Capital flows and their macroeconomic effects in India. ICRIER Working Paper No. 64, ICRIER, New Delhi

  • Reserve Bank of India (2002) Report on currency and Finance. 2000–01. RBI, Mumbai

  • Reserve Bank of India (2012) Fiscal and monetary coordination. Report on Currency and Finance 2009–2012. RBI, Mumbai

  • Reserve Bank of India (2015) Handbook of statistics on Indian economy. RBI, Mumbai

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh C, Das R, Baig J (2015). Money, output and prices in India. IIMB Working Paper No. 497, IIMB, Bangalore

  • Yadav S, Upadhyay V, Sharma S (2010) Impact of fiscal policy shocks on the Indian economy. MPRA Working Paper No. 34071, MPRA

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to K. Gayithri.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) and Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin (KPSS) unit root tests

ADF unit root test indicates that except inflation variable all other variables have unit root in the level as the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. However, in the first difference all variables become stationary (Tables 3, 4).

Table 3 Augmented Dickey–Fuller unit root test
Table 4 Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin (KPSS) unit root test

The KPSS test value is presented in level and first difference form, and along with that 5% critical value is also presented. KPSS unit root test indicates that except for the inflation variable all other variables have unit root in the levels and it becomes stationary in the first difference.

Appendix 2: Description of restrictions imposed on the matrix

Transmission Channel 2: Fiscal deficit − Per Capita Income − Consumption Exp − Imports − Inflation

As it was observed from Eqs. (3) and (4), the relationship between structural shocks and the reduced form shocks is given by

$$ u_{t} = A^{ - 1} e_{t} \,{\text{and}}\,e_{t} = Au_{t} $$

In order to track the transmission mechanism 2, matrix A has been restricted as upper triangular matrix with ones on main diagonal and it looks as follows:

$$ \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {u_{t}^{ \inf } } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnimports}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnCE}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnPcGDP}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnGFD}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 & {A_{12} } & {A_{13} } & {A_{14} } & 0 \\ 0 & 1 & {A_{23} } & {A_{24} } & {A_{25} } \\ 0 & 0 & 1 & {A_{34} } & {A_{35} } \\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 & {A_{45} } \\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {e_{t}^{ \inf } } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnimports}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnCE}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnPcGDP}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnGFD}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

where vector containing the u t represents reduced form shocks and vector containing e t represents structural form shocks. A is the matrix of contemporaneous relations. inf is inflation, dlnimports is the first difference of natural log of imports, dlnCE is first difference of natural log of consumption expenditure,\( {\text{dlnPcGDP}} \) is first difference of natural log of per capita GDP, and dlnGFD is the first difference of natural log of gross fiscal deficit. The restriction implies that first variable, namely inflation, is depended on imports, consumption expenditure and per capita income. Consumption expenditure depends on per capita income and may also directly get affected by changes in fiscal deficit, and finally, per capita income is depended on fiscal deficit. The restriction entails that fiscal deficit would affect per capita income and consumption expenditure. Per capita income will influence the consumption expenditure, and it in turn affects imports. Inflation is depended on imports, consumption expenditure and also per capita income.

Transmission Channel 3: Fiscal Deficit – Money Supply – Inflation

For transmission channel 3, matrix \( A \) has been restricted as follows:

$$ \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {u_{t}^{ \inf } } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnMS}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnGFD}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 & {A_{12} } & 0 \\ 0 & 1 & {A_{23} } \\ {A_{31} } & 0 & 1 \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {e_{t}^{ \inf } } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnMS}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnGFD}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

where inf is inflation, dlnMS is the first difference of natural log of money supply (M3), and dlnGFD is the first difference of natural log of gross fiscal deficit. The restriction implies that first variable, namely inflation, is depended on money supply and the money supply depends on fiscal deficit. The restriction entails that fiscal deficit would affect money supply, which in turn affects inflation. It is also been checked whether inflation has any impact on fiscal deficit, which is being captured by A 31.

Transmission Channel 4: Fiscal Deficit − Interest Rate − Capital Inflow − Money Supply − Inflation

For transmission channel 4, A matrix has been restricted as follows:

$$ \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {u_{t}^{ \inf } } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnMS}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlncapflow}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dIR}} } \\ {u_{t}^{\text{dlnGFD}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] = \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} 1 & {A_{12} } & {A_{13} } & {A_{14} } & 0 \\ 0 & 1 & {A_{23} } & {A_{24} } & {A_{25} } \\ 0 & 0 & 1 & {A_{34} } & {A_{35} } \\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 & {A_{45} } \\ 0 & 0 & 0 & 0 & 1 \\ \end{array} } \right]\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {e_{t}^{ \inf } } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnMS}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlncapflow}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dIR}} } \\ {e_{t}^{\text{dlnGFD}} } \\ \end{array} } \right] $$

where inf is inflation, dlnMS is the first difference of natural log of money supply, dlncapflow is first difference of natural log of capital inflow,\( {\text{dIR}} \) is first difference of interest rate, and dlnGFD is the first difference of natural log of gross fiscal deficit. The restriction implies that first variable, namely inflation, is depended on money supply, capital inflow and per capita income. Money supply depends on capital inflow and interest rate. And finally, interest rate depends on shocks in fiscal deficit. The restriction entails that fiscal deficit would affect interest rate. The interest rate affects the capital flow and which in turn affects the money supply. Inflation is expected to getting affected by shocks in money supply, capital flow and also interest rate (Fisher equation shows the relation between inflation and interest rate).

Appendix 3: Diagnostic checks for model 1 (transmission mechanism 1)

In a time series analysis it is important to check whether the errors are serial correlated or not. And it is also important to check whether the model is dynamically stable. The serial correlation check has been done using the Lagrange multiplier test.

The Langrage multiplier (LM) test is better and advanced than the Durbin–Watson serial correlation test. LM test can be used to test higher-order ARMA (autoregressive and moving average) errors. The null hypothesis is that there is no serial correlation up to a particular lag. If the p value is significant, then one can reject the null hypothesis and accept the alternative hypothesis. But here (see Table 5) the p values are insignificant, and hence, we cannot reject the null hypothesis. The LM test indicates that there is no serial correlation among the error terms.

Table 5 Serial correlation LM test of Model 1

If the estimated ARMA structure is stationary, then all the AR roots should lie within the unit root circle. If any of the AR root is outside the unit root circle, then the model is not stationary and hence dynamically not stable. However, the inverted AR roots here (see Fig. 6) are within the unit root circle, and hence, the model can be said as stable.

Fig. 6
figure 6

Dynamic stability test of Model 1

Appendix 4: Diagnostic checks for model 2 (transmission mechanism 2)

The probability value (see Table 6) is insignificant and hence accepts the null hypothesis of no serial correlation. Hence, the serial correlation LM test indicates that there is no serial correlation among the error terms.

Table 6 Serial correlation LM test of Model 2

If any of the AR root is outside the unit root circle, then the model is not stationary and hence dynamically not stable. However, the inverted AR roots here (see Fig. 7) are within the unit root circle, and hence, the model can be said as stable.

Fig. 7
figure 7

Dynamic stability test of Model 2

Appendix 5: Diagnostic checks for model 3 (transmission mechanism 3)

The probability value (see Table 7) is insignificant and hence accepts the null hypothesis of no serial correlation. Hence, the serial correlation LM test indicates that there is no serial correlation among the error terms.

Table 7 Serial correlation LM test for Model 3

If any of the AR root is outside the unit root circle, then the model is not stationary and hence dynamically not stable. However, the inverted AR roots here (see Fig. 8) are within the unit root circle, and hence, the model can be said as stable.

Fig. 8
figure 8

Dynamic stability test of Model 3

Appendix 6: Diagnostic checks for model 4 (transmission mechanism 4)

The probability value (see Table 8) is insignificant and hence accepts the null hypothesis of no serial correlation. Hence, the serial correlation LM test indicates that there is no serial correlation among the error terms.

Table 8 Serial correlation LM test of Model 4

If any of the AR root is outside the unit root circle, then the model is not stationary and hence dynamically not stable. However, the inverted AR roots here (see Fig. 9) are within the unit root circle, and hence, the model can be said as stable.

Fig. 9
figure 9

Dynamic stability test of Model 4

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Anantha Ramu, M.R., Gayithri, K. Fiscal deficit and inflation linkages in India: tracking the transmission channels . J. Soc. Econ. Dev. 19, 1–24 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40847-017-0042-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40847-017-0042-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation