Skip to main content
  • 1966 Accesses

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. Reply Comments of Center for Media Education, et al., Inquiry Concerning the Deployment of Advanced Telecommunications Capability to America Americans in a Reasonable and Timely Fashion, and Possible Steps to Accelerate Such Deployment Pursuant to Section 706 of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 98–146, October 10, 1998; Petition to Deny Consumers Union, et al., Joint Application of AT&T Corporation and Tele-Communications Inc. For Approval of Transfer of Control of Commission Licenses and Authorizations, Federal Communications Commission, CS Docket No. 98-178, October 28, 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Consumer Federation of America, Texas Office of People’s Counsel, and Consumers Union, “Reply Comments,” before the Federal Communications Commission, In The Matter of Deployment of Wireline Services Offering Advanced Telecommunications Capability, Etc., CC Docket Nos. 98-147, 98–11, 98–26, 98–32, 98–78, 98–91, CCB/CPD Docket No. 98–15, RM 9244, October 18, 1998. Comments of CU, et al., Inquiry Concerning High-Speed Access to the Internet Over Cable and Other Facilities, GEN Docket No. 00-185 (filed December 1, 2001); “Comments of Arizona Consumer Council, Center For Digital Democracy, Citizen Action of Illinois, Citizens Utility Board of Oregon, Consumer Action, The Consumer Federation of America, Consumers Union, Democratic Processes Center, Florida Consumer Action Network, Illinois PIRG, Massachusetts Consumer Coalition, Media Access Project, New Jersey Citizen Action, Texas Consumer Association, Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel, USAction,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers Computer HI Further Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review-Review of Computer III and ONA Safeguards And Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Dockets Nos. 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002, (hereinafter Wireline Proceeding); Reply Comments, July 1, 2001; “Comments of Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel, Consumer Federation of America, Consumers Union,” In the Matter of Inquiry Concerning High Speed Access to the Internet over Cable and Other Facilities, Federal Communications Commission, GN Docket No. 96-262, December 12, 1999, January 12, 2000; “Comments of Texas Office of Consumer Counsel, Consumer Federation of America, In the Matter of Inquiry Concerning High-Speed Access to the Internet Over Cable and Other Facilities; Declaratory Ruling; Appropriate Regulatory Treatment for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Cable Facilities, Federal Communications Commission, GN Dockets Nos. 00-185, CS Dockets No. 02-52, March 15, 2002; “Comments and Reply Comments of The Consumer Federation of America, Texas Office of Public Utility Counsel, Consumers Union, and Center For Digital Democracy,” In the Matter of Review of the Section 251 Unbundling, Obligations of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers, Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Deployment of Wireline Services Offering Advanced Telecommunications Capability, Federal Communications Commission, CC Dockets Nos. 01–338, 96–98, 98–147, April 5, 2002; Reply Comments, July 1, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  3. “Amicus Curiae Brief of Citizens’ Utility Board of Oregon, Consumer Action, Consumer Federation of America, The Utility Reform Network (TURN) and Utility Consumer Action Network,” AT&T v. Portland, 216 F.3d 871 (9th Cir. 2000); “Opening Brief of Consumer Federation of America, Consumers Union and Center for Digital Democracy,” Brand X Internet Service, et a., v. Federal Communications Commission, October 10, 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  4. United States v. AT&T and MediaOne, Amended Complaint, Case No. 1:00CV001176 (RCL) (D.C. Cir. May 26, 2000).

    Google Scholar 

  5. Boardwatch, various issues.

    Google Scholar 

  6. “Report and Order on Remand and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking,” In the Matter of Review of Section 251 Unbundling Obligations of Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers, Implementation of the Local Competition Provision of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, Deployment of Wireline Services Offering Advanced Telecommunications Capability, CC Docket Nos. 01–338, 96–98, 98–147, August 21, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Support for open communications networks in the Internet age has been a pillar of consumer group policy. See Mark Cooper, Expanding the Information Age for the 1990s: A Pragmatic Consumer View (American Association of Retired Persons and Consumer Federation of America, January 11, 1990). This was the first in a series of reports that analyzed the effects of decentralized, open networks, prior to the dramatic commercial success of the Internet (see Mark Cooper, Developing the Information Age in the 1990s: A Pragmatic Consumer View [Consumer Federation of America, June 8, 1992], “Delivering the Information Age Now,” Telecom Infrastructure: 1993, Telecommunications Reports, 1993, The Meaning of the Word Infrastructure [Consumer Federation of America, June 30, 1994]).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Cited in James B. Speta., A Common Carrier Approach to Internet Interconnection, 54 Federal Communications Law Journal 254 (2002) (hereinafter Speta).

    Google Scholar 

  9. Odlyzko, Andrew, Pricing and Architecture of the Internet: Historical Perspectives from Telecommunications and Transportation (Digital Technology Center, University of Minnesota, 2003), notes price discrimination between classes of goods but not in access to the network. He also notes the central role of government policy in establishing rights of access and setting rates. See also Hal Varian, Markets for Public Goods (Ann Arbor, January 2003); D. Davis, Shine Your Light on Me, December 23, 2002, available at: <http://Dsquareddiest.blogpost.org/2002_12_22_dsquareddigest_archives.html#86435321>.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Hockett v. State Indiana (1886), cited Speta, Common Carrier, at 262.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Cited in Kahn, Alfred, The Economics of Regulation: Principles and Institutions (MIT Press, 1988), at 55.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Morgan Stanley Dean Witter, The Digital Decade, April 6, 1999, at 177–178.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Earl W. Comstock, and John Butler, Access Denied: The FCC’s Failure to Implement Open Access as Required by the Communications Act, Jouranal of communications law and Policy (Winter 2000).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Lawrence Lessig, The Future of Ideas (Random House, 2001), at 148 (hereinafter Lessig, Future), emphasizes the break with the computer inquiries in approach to advanced telecommunications services.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Mark A. Lemley and Lawrence Lessig, The End of End-to-End: Preserving the Architecture of the Internet in the Broadband Era. UCLA Law Review 48, 925, 935 (2001) (hereinafter Lemley and Lessig, End of End-to-End) (written as a direct response to James P. Speta, Written Ex Parte, Application for Consent to the Transfer of Control of Licenses of MediaOne Group, Inc. to AT&T Corp. FCC Docket No. 99-251, 1999). See also James B. Speta, The Vertical Dimension of Cable Open Access, 71 University of Colorado Law Review 975 (2000) (hereinafter, Speta, The Vertical Dimension); Phil Weiser, Paradigm Changes in Telecommunications Regulation, University of Colorado Law Review 71 (2000) at 819 (responding to an earlier piece by Lemley and Lessig, Written Ex Parte, Application for Consent to Transfer Control of Licenses of MediaOne Group Inc. to AT&T Corp., FCC Docket No. 99-251 (1999) available at: <http://cyber.law.harvard.edu/works/lessig/filing/lem-les.doc.html> (hereinafter Lemley and Lessig).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Lemley and Lessig, supra note 16, at 936.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Speta, The Vertical Dimension, supra note 16, at 975; Phil Weiser, Paradigm Changes in Telecommunications Regulation, 71 University of Colorado Law Review 819 (2000).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Mark Cooper, Open Communications Platforms: The Physical Infrastructure as the Bedrock of Innovation and Democratic Discourse in the Internet Age, 2 Journal on Telecommunications & High Technology Law 177 (2003). Also available at: <http://cyberlaw.stanford.edu/blogs/cooper/archives/070a.pdf>.

    Google Scholar 

  19. F.M. Scherer, and David Ross, Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance (3d ed., Houghton Mifflin, 1990), at 18.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Id., at 19.

    Google Scholar 

  21. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Lawrence Lessig, Code and Other Laws of Cyberspace (Basic Books, 1999), at 166–167

    Google Scholar 

  24. See Yochai Benkler, From Consumers to Users: Shifting the Deeper Structures of Regulation Toward Sustainable Commons and User Access, Federal Communications Law Journal 52 (2000), at 561; Yochai Benkler, Intellectual Property and the Organization of Information Production, 22 International Review of Law and Economics 81 (2002), available at: <http://www.law.nyu.edu/benklery/IP&Organization.pdf>.

    Google Scholar 

  25. National Research Council, Realizing the Information Future, 1994, at 43.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Id., at 43.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Id. at 44.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Phillip Evans, and Thomas S. Wurster, Blown to Bits: How the New Economics of Information Transforms Strategy (Harvard Business School Press, 2000), at 17; Manual Castells, The Internet Galaxy (Oxford University Press, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  29. Lee W. McKnight, Internet Business Models: Creative Destruction as Usual, in Lee W. McKnight, Paul M. Vaaler, and Raul L. Katz (eds.), Creative Destruction: Business Survival Strategies in the Global Internet Economy (MIT Press, 2001), at 45.

    Google Scholar 

  30. “Comments of the High Tech Broadband Coalition,” In the Matter of Appropriate Regulatory Treatment for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Cable Facilities, CC Docket No. 96-45, June 17, 2002, at 7–9; see also “Reply Comments of the High Tech Broadband Coalition,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet over Wireline Facilities, CC Docket No. 02-33, July 1, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Janet Abbate, Inventing the Internet (MIT Press, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  32. Marjorie S. Blumenthal, and David D. Clark, Rethinking the Design of the Internet: The End-to-End Argument vs. The Brave New World, in Benjamin M. Compain and Shane Greenstein, Communications Policy in Transition (MIT Press, 2001) (hereinafter Blumenthal and Clark).

    Google Scholar 

  33. David P. Reed, Jerome Saltzer and David D. Clark, End-to-End Arguments in System Design, ACM Transactions on Computer Systems 2:4 (1984); Active Networking and End-to-End Arguments, May 15, 1998.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Mark Cooper, Open Access to the Broadband Internet: Technical and Economic Discrimination in Closed, Proprietary Networks, 71 University of Colorado Law Review 10–11 (2000); Mark N. Cooper, and Christopher Murray, Technology, Economics and Public Policy To Create An Open Broadband Internet, The Policy Implications of End-to-End, Stanford Law School, December 1, 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Lessig, Future, supra note 15, at 23 (noting that Berners-Lee, Tim, Weaving the Web: The Original Design and Ultimate Destiny of the World Wide Web by its Inventor [Harper Collins, 1999], at 129–30, identified four layers: transmission, computer, software and content).

    Google Scholar 

  36. Carl Shapiro, and Hal Varian, Information Rules (Harvard Business School Press, 1999) (hereinafter Shapiro and Varian) at 9–15; Richard N. Langlois, Technology Standards, Innovation, and Essential Facilities: Toward a Schumpeterian Post-Chicago Approach, in Jerry Ellig (ed.), Dynamic Competition & Public Policy: Technology, Innovations, and Antitrust Issues (2001), at 193, 207, available at: <http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=204069> (last visited Jan. 24, 2003) (calling platforms “system products” — “Most cumulative technologies are in the nature of system products, that is, products that permit or require the simultaneous functioning of a number of complementary components”) (hereinafter Langlois).

    Google Scholar 

  37. Michael L. Katz and Carl Shapiro, System Competition and Network Effects, 8 Journal of Economic Perspectives 93, 105–06 (1994) (hereinafter Katz and Shapiro, System Competition), argue that competition between incompatible systems is possible, depending on consumer heterogeneity. Paul Belleflamme, Stable Coalition Structures with Open Membership and Asymmetric Firms, 30 Games and Economic Behavior 1, 1–3 (2000); and Berd Woeckener, The Competition of User Networks: Ergodicity, Lock-ins, and Metastability, 41 Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 85, 86–87 (2000), reach a similar conclusion in a different theoretic framework. Bresnahan, Timothy F. and Shane Greenstein, Technological Competition and the Structure of the Computer Industry, 47 Journal of Industrial Economics 1, 5–8 (1999) (hereinafter Bresnahan and Greenstien), envision a great deal of competition within the layers of a platform and across layers in relatively short periods of time. The description of IBM’s mainframe platform provided by Franklin M. Fisher, The IBM and Microsoft Cases: What’s the Difference?, 90 American Economic Review 180, 183 (1999), stresses both these points. See also Daniel L. Rubinfeld, Antitrust Enforcement in Dynamic Network Industries, 43 Antitrust Bulletin 859, 873–75 (1998) (hereinafter Rubinfeld); Willow A. Sheremata, New Issues in Competition Policy Raised by Information Technology Industries, 43 Antitrust Bulletin 547, 573–74 (1998) (hereinafter Sheremata, New Issues in Competition); Timothy Bresnahan, The Economics of the Microsoft Case (available from the author); Steven C. Salop, and R. Craig Romaine, Preserving Monopoly: Economic Analysis, Legal Standards, and Microsoft, George Mason Law Review (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  38. Shapiro and Varian, supra note 37, at 22–23.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Brian R. Gaines, The Learning Curve Underlying Convergence, Technology Forecasting and Social Change, Jan./Feb. 1998, at 30–31; W. Brian Arthur, Positive Feedbacks in the Economy, Scientific American, Feb. 1990, at 95; see also W. Brian Arthur, Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns and Lock-in by Historical Events, 99 Economic Journal (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  40. Daniel L. Rubinfeld, and John Hoven, Innovation and Antitrust Enforcement, in Jerry Ellig (ed.), Dynamic Competition and Public Policy: Technology, Innovation, and Antitrust Issues (Cambridge University Press, 2001), at 65, 75–76.

    Google Scholar 

  41. T. Randolph Beard, George S. Ford and Lawrence J. Spiwak, Why ADCo? Why Now: An Economic Exploration into the Future of Industry Structure for the “Last Mile” in Local Telecommunications Markets (Phoenix Center, November 2001); Computer Science and Telecommunications Board, National Research Council, Broadband, Bringing Home the Bits (National Academy Press, 2002) (hereinafter Bits), at 23, 152–154; Anupam Banerjee, and Marvin Sirvu, Towards Technologically and Competitively Neutral Fiber to the Home (FTTH) Infrastructure, Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, 2003; Newman, Stagg, Broad-band Access Platforms for the Mass Market, Telecommunications Policy Research Conference, 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Melissa A. Schilling, Technological Lockout: An Integrative Model of the Economic and Strategic Factors Driving Technology Success and Failure, 23 Academic Management Review 267, 268, 270 (1998) (hereinafter Shilling); Willow A. Sheremata, Barriers to Innovation: A Monopoly, Network Externalities, and the Speed of Innovation, 42 Antitrust Bulletin 937, 941, 964, 967 (1997) (hereinafter Sheremata, Barriers to Innovation); Robin Cowan, Tortoises and Hares: Choice Among Technologies of Unknown Merit, 101 Economics Journal 807, 808 (1991); Dominique Foray, The Dynamic Implications of Increasing Returns: Technological Change and Path Dependent Efficiency, 15 International Journal of Industrial Organization 733, 748–49 (1997); Joseph Farrell, and Garth Saloner, Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, 16 Rand Journal of Economics 70, 70–83 (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  43. Jeffrey Church, and Neil Gandal, Complementary Network Externalities and Technological Adoption, 11 International Journal of Industrial Organization 239, 241 (1993); Chou Chien-fu and Oz Shy, Network Effects Without Network Externalities, 8 International Journal of Industrial Organization 259, 260 (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  44. Shepherd, William G., The Economics of Industrial Organization (Prentice Hall, 1985), at 289-90.

    Google Scholar 

  45. See Langlois, supra note 37, at 52, “The owner of a dominant standard may thus want to manipulate the standard in ways that close off the possibilities for a competitor to achieve compatibility. This has a tendency to retard the generational advance of the system.”

    Google Scholar 

  46. David B. Yoffie, CHESS and Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence, in David B. Yoffie (ed.), Competing in the Age of Digital Convergence (Harvard Business School Press, 1997) (hereinafter Yoffie) at 21; see also Bresnahan and Greenstein, supra note 38, at 36–37; Katz and Shapiro, System Competition, supra note 38, at 103.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Schilling, supra note 43, at 280-81.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Michael Katz, and Carl Shapiro, Antitrust and Software Markets, in Jeffrey A. Eisenach & Thomas M. Lenard (eds.), Competition, Innovation and The Microsoft Monopoly: Antitrust and The Digital Marketplace, (Kluwer Academic, 1999), at 424 (hereinafter Katz and Shapiro, Antitrust and Software).

    Google Scholar 

  49. See generally, Id.; Jay Pil Choi, Network Externalities, Compatibility Choice and Planned Obsolescence, 42 Journal of Industrial Economics 167(1994).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Robin Mansell, Strategies for Maintaining Market Power in the Face of Rapidly Changing Technologies, 31 Journal of Economic Issues 969, 970 (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  51. Schilling, supra note 43, at 274.

    Google Scholar 

  52. Sheremata, Barriers to Innovation, supra note 43, at 965.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Shapiro and Varian, supra note 38.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Bresnahan and Greenstein, supra note 38, at 36–37; Joseph Farrell, and Michael L. Katz, The Effect of Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law on Compatibility and Innovation, 43 Antitrust Bulletin 645, 650 (1998); Katz and Shapiro, System Competition, supra note 38, at 109–12; Matutes, Carmen and Pierre Regibeau, Mix and Match: Product Compatibility Without Network Externalities, 19 Rand Journal of Economics 221–233 (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  55. Mark A. Lemley, and David McGowan, Could Java Change Everything? The Competitive Propriety of a Proprietary Standard, 43 Antitrust Bulletin 715 (1998) (hereinafter Lemley and McGowan, Could Java); Mark A. Lemley, and David McGowan, Legal Implications of Network Effects, 86 California Law Review 479, 516–18 (1998) (hereinafter Lemley & McGowan, Legal Implications).

    Google Scholar 

  56. See Id. See also Franklin M. Fisher, Innovation and Monopoly Leveraging, in Jerry Ellig (ed.), Dynamic Competition and Public Policy: Technology, Innovation, and Antitrust Issues, (Cambridge University Press, 2001), at 138.

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Joseph Farrell, and Garth Saloner, Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product Preannouncements, and Predation, 76 American Economic Review 940, 948–51 (1986); Michael L. Katz & Carl Shapiro, Product Introduction with Network Externalities, 40 Journal of Industrial Economics 55, 73 (1992); Richard Makadok, Can First-Mover and Early-Mover Advantages Be Sustained in an Industry with Low Barriers to Entry/Imitation?, 19 Strategic Management Journal 683, 685–86 (1998) (hereinafter Makadok); Ulrich Witt, ‘Lock-in’ vs. ‘Critical Masses’ — Industrial Change Under Network Externalities, 15 International Journal of Industrial Organization 753, 768–69 (1997); Robin Mansell, Strategies for Maintaining Market Power in the Face of Rapidly Changing Technologies, 31 Journal of Economic Issues 969, 970 (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  58. See Schilling, supra note 43, at 267, 276.

    Google Scholar 

  59. See Sheremata, New Issues in Competition, supra note 38, at 573-74; Glenn A. Woroch, et al., Exclusionary Behavior in the Market for Operating System Software: The Case of Microsoft, in David Gabel & David F. Weiman (eds.), Opening Networks to Competition: The Regulation and Pricing of Access (Kluwer Academic, 1998), at 221.

    Google Scholar 

  60. See Sheremata, New Issues in Competition, supra note 38, at 560-61; see also Charles H. Ferguson, High Stakes, No Prisoners: A Winner’s Tale of Greed and Glory in the Internet Wars (Three Rivers Press, 1999), at 307; Lemley & McGowan, Could Java, supra note 56, at 715, 732–33.

    Google Scholar 

  61. See Joseph Farrell, and Michael L. Katz, The Effects of Antitrust and Intellectual Property Law on Compatibility and Innovation, 43 Antitrust Bulletin 609, 643-50 (1998); Sheremata, New Issues in Competition, at 547, 573–74.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See Makadok, supra note 58, at 685.

    Google Scholar 

  63. See Yoffie, supra note 47, at 1, 27; see also Robert E. Dansby, and Cecilia Conrad, Commodity Bundling, 74 American Economic Review 377 (1984).

    Google Scholar 

  64. See Carmen Matutes, and Pierre Regibeau, Compatibility and Bundling of Complementary Goods in a Duopoly, 40 Journal of Industrial Economics 37 (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  65. See Id.; see also Joseph P. Guiltinan, The Price Bundling of Services: A Normative Framework, Journal of Marketing, April 1987, at 74; Lester Telser, A Theory of Monopoly of Complementary Goods, 52 Journal of Business 211 (1979); Richard Schmalensee, Gaussian Demand and Commodity Bundling, 57 Journal of Business S211 (1984).

    Google Scholar 

  66. See Jay Pil Choi, Network Externality, Compatibility Choice, and Planned Obsolescence, 42 Journal of Industrial Economics (1994), at 167, 171–73.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See Glenn Ellison & Drew Fudenberg, The Neo-Luddite’s Lament: Excessive Upgrades in the Software Industry, Rand Journal of Economics (2000); Drew Fudenberg and Jean Tirole, Upgrades, Trade-ins, and Buybacks, 29 Rand Journal of Economics 235, 235–36 (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  68. See Id., at 176–77; K. Sridhar Moorthy, Market Segmentation, Self Selection, and Product Lines Design, 3 Marketing Science 256 (1985); Marcel Thum, Network Externalities, Technological Progress, and the Competition of Market Contract, 12 International Journal of Industrial Organization 269 (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  69. See Id., at 19–24; see also Katz and Shapiro, Antitrust and Software, supra note 49, at 70–80; Lansuz A. Ordover, and Robert D. Willig, Access and Bundling in High Technology Markets, in Jeffrey A. Eisenach & Thomas M. Lenard (eds.), Competition, Innovation and The Microsoft Monopoly: Antitrust and The Digital Marketplace (Kluwer Academic, 1999); Rubinfeld, supra note 38, at 877–81; Steven C. Salop, Using Leverage to Preserve Monopoly, in Jeffrey A. Eisenach & Thomas M. Lenard (eds.), Competition, Innovation and The Microsoft Monopoly: Antitrust and The Digital Marketplace (Kluwer Academic, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  70. The video side is discussed at length in Mark Cooper, Cable Mergers and Monopolies: Market Power in Digital Media and Communications Networks (Economic Policy Institute, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  71. Controlling Your Network — A Must for Cable Operators (Cisco, 1999), New Revenue Opportunities for Cable Operators From Streaming-Media Technology (Cisco, 1999); Dawson, Fred, The Interactive Digital Network: More than Just a Set-Top Decision (Cisco, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  72. As a variety of industry commenters who found themselves on the receiving end of cable industry discrimination and exclusion expressed their concern from the earliest days of the commercial high speed Internet. AT&T Canada Long Distance Services, “Comments of AT&T Canada Long Distance Services Company,” before the Canadian Radio-Television and Telecommunications Commission, Telecom Public Notice CRTC 96-36: Regulation of Certain Telecommunications Service Offered by Broadcast Carriers, February 4, 1997. The AT&T policy on open access after it became a cable company was first offered in a Letter to Chairman Bill Kennard, dated December 6, 1999, signed by David N. Baker, Vice President Legal & Regulatory Affairs; Mindspring Enterprises; James W. Cicconi, General Council and Executive Vice President, AT&T Corp.; and Kenneth S. Fellman, Esq., Chairman, FCC Local & State Government Advisory Committee. Virtually no commercial activity took place as aresult of the letter, which was roundly criticized. Subsequently their policy was described in Goodman, Peter S., AT&T Puts Open Access to a Test, Washington Post, November 23, 2000 (hereinafter Goodman). AT&T continues to complain that the Regional Bell Operating Companies are continuing to impede competitors from gaining nondiscriminatory access to advanced services unbundled network elements. See, for example, “Affidavit of Al Finnell on Behalf of AT&T Communications of California,” before the Public Utilities Commission of the State of California, Notice of Intent to File Section 271 Application of SBC Communications Inc., Pacific Bell, and Pacific Bell Communications Inc., for Provision of In-region, In-terLATA Services in California, August 11, 1999, at 42–53; America Online, Inc., “Open Access Comments of America Online, Inc.,” before the Department of Telecommunications and Information Services, San Francisco, October 27, 1999 (hereinafter AOL). At the federal level, AOL’s most explicit analysis of the need for open access can be found in “Comments of America Online, Inc.,” In the Matter of Transfer of Control of FCC Licenses of MediaOne Group, Inc. to AT&T Corporation, Federal Communications Commission, CS Docket No. 99-251, August 23, 1999 (hereinafter AOL, FCC). America Online continues to reiterate these arguments, see “Comments of AOL TimeWarner, Inc.,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter AOL, 2002); Jerry A. Hausman, J. Gregory Sidak, and Hal J. Singer, Residential Demand for Broadband Telecommunications and Consumer Access to Unaffiliated Internet Content Providers, Yale Journal on Regulation 18 (2001). John B. Hayes, Jith Jayaratne, and Michael L. Katz, An Empirical Analysis of the Footprint Effects of Mergers Between Large ILECS, April 1, 1999, at 1; citing “Declaration of Michael L. Katz and Steen C. Salop,” submitted as an attachment to Petition to Deny of Spring Communications Company L.P, in “Ameritech Corp. and SBC Communications, Inc., for Consent to Transfer of Control,” CC Docket. No. 98-141 (filed Oct. 15, 1998) and Petition to Deny of Spring Communications Company L.P, in “GTE Corporation and Bell Atlantic Corporation for Consent to Transfer of Control,” CC Docket No. 98-184 (filed Nov. 23, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  73. NorthNet, Inc., An Open Access Business Model For Cable Systems: Promoting Competition & Preserving Internet Innovation On A Shared, Broadband Communications Network, Ex Parte, Application of America Online Inc. & Time Warner, Inc. for Transfers of Control, FCC, CS Docket No. 00-30, October 16, 2000 (hereinafter NorthNet).

    Google Scholar 

  74. Blumenthal and Clark, supra SHANE GREENSTEIN, Communications Policy in Transition, (MIT Press, 2001) note 33, at 24.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Earthlink, the first ISP to enter into negotiations with cable owners for access has essentially given up and is vigorously seeking an open access obligation, see Ex Parte Letter from Earl W. Comstock and John W. Butler Regarding the Application of America Online, Inc. and Time Warner Inc. for Transfer of Control, Federal Communications Commission, Docket No. CS 0030, October 18, 2000 (hereinafter Earthlink).

    Google Scholar 

  76. A New Model for AOL May Influence Cable’s Future, New York Times, August 26, 2002, at C.1; Dan Gilmore, AOL Capitulates, Gives Up Struggle for ‘Open Access,’San Jose Mercury News, September 1, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  77. Tim Wu and Lawrence Lessig, Ex Parte Submission in CS Docket No. 02-52, August 22, 2003, at 7–8.

    Google Scholar 

  78. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  79. The Federal Communications Commission has been presented with a mountain of specific evidence of anticompetitive behavior by wire owners. Notwithstanding the grant of entry into long distance, many of these problems still afflict the provision of DSL service, as recent testimony in Texas (the second state in which an incumbent RBOC was granted entry) attest; see “Response of Cbeyond, Inc.,” Ten Questions to Begin the Committee’s Inquiry Into State Broadband Policy, Committee on State Affairs, April 3, 2002 (hereinafter Cbeyond); “Response of IP Communications,” Ten Questions to Begin the Committee’s Inquiry Into State Broadband Policy, Committee on State Affairs, April 3, 2002 (hereinafter IP Communications); “Response of Hometown Communications,” Ten Questions to Begin the Committee’s Inquiry Into State Broadband Policy, Committee on State Affairs, April 3, 2002 (hereinafter Hometown); “Response of Texas CLEC Coalition,” Ten Questions to Begin the Committee’s Inquiry Into State Broadband Policy, Committee on State Affairs, April 3, 2002 (hereinafter TxCLEC); “Reply Comments of the California ISP Association, Inc., Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in the Matter of the Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 95-20, 98-10, April 30, 200 (hereinafter CISPA, 2001b); “Reply Comments of the Texas Internet Service Providers Association, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in the Matter of the Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 95-20, 98-10, April 30, 200 (hereinafter TISPA, 2001a); “Reply Comments of the Commercial Internet Exchange Association, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in the Matter of the Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 95-20, 98-10, April 30, 2000 (hereinafter CIX, 2001a); “Comments of the Information Technology Association of America,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broad-band Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter ITAA, 2002); “Comments of the IP Communications Corporation,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter IPCommunications, 2002); “Comments of the Public Service Commission of the State of Missouri,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter MOPSC, 2002); “Joint Comments of NASUCA, et al.,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter NASUCA, 2002); “Comments of Ad Hoc Telecommunications Users Committee,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter Ad Hoc, 2002); “Comments of the New Mexico Information Professionals Association of America,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter NMIPA, 2002); “Comments of Cox Communications, Inc.,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter Cox, 2002); “Comments of Brand X,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services: 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter Brand X, 2002); “Comments of the New Hampshire ISP Association,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter NHISP, 2002); “Comments of Ruby Ranch Cooperative Association,” In the matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter Ruby Ranch, 2002; “Comments of Earthlink, Inc.,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter Earthlink, 2002); “Comments of U.S. LEC Corp.,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Accessto the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter US LEC, 2002); “Comments of Big Planet, Inc.,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereinafter Big Planet, 2002); “Joint Comments of Cbeyond and Nuvox,” In the Matter of Review of Regulatory Requirements for Incumbent LEC Broadband Telecommunications Services, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 01-337, March 1, 2002 (hereinafter CBeyond, 2002).

    Google Scholar 

  80. Steven J. Vaughn-Nichols, DSL Spells Trouble for Many ISPs, Smart Reseller, February 24, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  81. “Comments of DirecTV Broadband, Inc,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002, at 8–10 (hereinafter DirecTV) ITAA 2002, supra note 83, at 11.

    Google Scholar 

  82. NMIPA 2002, supra note 83, at 5.

    Google Scholar 

  83. TISPA, 2001a, supra note 83, at 18.

    Google Scholar 

  84. AOL, supra note 74, at 6, 8; AdHoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 26; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 13, 15.

    Google Scholar 

  85. TISPA, 2001a, supra note 83, at 27.

    Google Scholar 

  86. TISPA, 2001a, supra note 83, at 33.

    Google Scholar 

  87. “Initial Comments of the California ISP Association, Inc.,” Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in the Matter of the Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 95-20, 98-10, DA 01-620, April 16, 2001 (hereafter CISPA, 2001a), at 27–28; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 10–11.

    Google Scholar 

  88. TISPA, 2001b, supra note 83, at 17.

    Google Scholar 

  89. Cox, 2002, supra note 83, at 6.

    Google Scholar 

  90. AdHoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 27; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 16.

    Google Scholar 

  91. CISPA, 2001b, supra note 83, at 7.

    Google Scholar 

  92. AdHoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 24; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 899.

    Google Scholar 

  93. AdHoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 22; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 12, 13.

    Google Scholar 

  94. AdHoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 23; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 15. TISPA, 2001a, supra note 83, at 22, 23, 31; CISPA, 2001a, supra note 93, at 10–14; DirectTV, supra note 86, at 8.

    Google Scholar 

  95. IAC, at 9; AOL, supra note 74, at 6, 8.

    Google Scholar 

  96. IgLou, Questionable Marketing Practices.

    Google Scholar 

  97. AOL, supra note 74, at 6, 8; ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 6, 15.

    Google Scholar 

  98. Cisco, Streaming Media, at 9; M.J. Richter, Everything’s Coming Up Convergence, Telephony, June 28, 1999, at 30 (quoting Rich Aroian, Vice President of Marketing and Strategic Alliances, Saville Systems).

    Google Scholar 

  99. TISPA, 2001a, supra note 83, at 22; CISPA, 2001a, supra note 91, at 21–22, 31–32; NMIPA, 2002, supra note 83, at 6.; AdHoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 27, ITAA, 2002, supranote 83, at 16.

    Google Scholar 

  100. Seth Schiesel, Start-Up Leads Phone Cause in Battle for Internet Access, N.Y. Times, May 17, 1999, at C-4.

    Google Scholar 

  101. Todd Spangler, Crossing the Broadband Divide, PC Magazine, February 12, 2002 (hereinafter Spangler); Yale Braunstein, Market Power and Price Increases in the DSL Market, July 2001 (hereinafter Braunstein); Sam Ames, Study: Broadband Fees Climbed in 2001, CNet News, January 17, 2002, viewed on November 29, 2005, available at: <http://news.com.com/2100-1033-818013.html> (hereinafter Ames).

    Google Scholar 

  102. Terry S. Harvill, ICC Commissioner Blasts SBC, Chicago Sun Times, April 23, 2001; see also, Shawn Young, et al., How Effort to Open Local Phone Markets Helped the Baby Bells, Wall Street Journal, February 11, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  103. Brand X, 2002, supra note 83, at 2; DirectTV, supra note 86, at 8; CIX, 2001a, supra note 83, at 8.

    Google Scholar 

  104. Telephone companies achieve the margin difference by offering high volume ISPs massive volume discounts that aggregate business across state lines, without any cost justification for such a discount (see ITAA, 2002, supra note 83, at 21; DirectTV, supra note 86, at 9).

    Google Scholar 

  105. Brian Ploskina, and Dana Coffield, Regional Bells Ringing Up Higher DSL Rates, Interactive Week, February 18, 2001; Braunstein, supra note 106.

    Google Scholar 

  106. Doug Ashton, The Future of Telecommunications Investment, Columbia Institute for Tele-Information, March 3, 2001 (noting lack of new services); Tim Horan, Communications Services: Industry Restructuring, Columbia Institute for Tele-Information, March 3, 2001 (noting lack of competitors and lack of services); Bits, supra note 42, at 15, 58 (noting service quality and lack of a killer application).

    Google Scholar 

  107. Cable Industry Comment, Banc of America Securities, May 7, 2001; Ames, supra note 106.

    Google Scholar 

  108. CISPA, 2001a, supra note 91, at 7; DirecTV, supra note 85, at 5; “Comments of Cbeyond, et al.,” In the Matter of Appropriate Framework for Broadband Access to the Internet Over Wireline Facilities, Universal Service Obligations of Broadband Providers, Computer III Remand Proceedings: Bell Operating Company Provision of Enhanced Services; 1998 Biennial Regulatory Review — Review of Computer II and ONA Safeguards and Requirements, Federal Communications Commission, CC Docket No. 02-33, 95-20, 98-10, May 3, 2002 (hereafter Cbeyond, et al., 2002), at 27-28.

    Google Scholar 

  109. Bits, supra note 42, at 21, 152–154.

    Google Scholar 

  110. Ad Hoc, 2002, supra note 83, at 18–19.

    Google Scholar 

  111. Craig Kuhl, Writing the Business Case for VDSL, CED, April 2000. Extensive documentation of the technology difference is provided in Mark Cooper, Transforming the Information Superhighway into a Private Toll Road (Consumer Federation of America, October 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  112. Thomas G. Hazlett, and George Bittlingmayer, The Political Economy of Cable “Open Access” (Joint Center Working Paper No. 01-06, May 2001), at 3–4.

    Google Scholar 

  113. Spangler, supra note 106 (noting pricing and service quality problems); Banc of America; Plosinka and Coffield.

    Google Scholar 

  114. Christopher Stern, Comcast Loss Has an Upside, Washington Post, May 2, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

  115. Brown, 2001, “Excite@Home’s 35 percent cut of subscriber fees to operate the service equaled roughly $13 to $14 monthly per subscriber. In contrast, Burke said Comcast could run the service for $7 to $8 per month.”

    Google Scholar 

  116. Lemley and Lessig, supra note 16, at 943-44. One should not think of ISPs as providing a fixed and immutable set of services. Right now, ISPs typically provide customer support as well as an Internet protocol (IP) address that channels the customer’s data. Competition among ISPs focuses on access speed and content. The benefits of this competition in the Internet’s history should not be underestimated. The ISP market has historically been extraordinarily competitive. This competition has driven providers to expand capacity and to lower prices. Also, it has driven providers to give highly effective customer support. This extraordinary build-out of capacity has not been encouraged through the promise of monopoly protection. Rather, the competitive market has provided a sufficient incentive, and the market has responded.

    Google Scholar 

  117. Steven A. Augustino, The Cable Open Access Debate: The Case for A Wholesale Market, 8 George Mason Law Review (2000), at 663.

    Google Scholar 

  118. Traditional economic discussions identify public goods and public infrastructure driven primarily by externalities (see, for example, John Taylor, Economics [Houghton Mifflin, 1998], Chapter 15), but the discussion inevitably leads to consideration of regulation of natural monopolies wherein public policy seeks to impose socially responsible behavior on private firms (see Id., Chapter 16; W. Kip Viscusi, John M. Vernon, and Joseph E. Harrington, Jr., Economics of Regulation and Antitrust [MIT Press, 2001], Chapters 11–14).

    Google Scholar 

  119. Peter Huber, Antitrust’s Real Legacy, Wall Street Journal, December 26, 2002.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2006 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this paper

Cite this paper

Cooper, M. (2006). The Importance of Open Networks in Sustaining the Digital Revolution. In: Lenard, T.M., May, R.J. (eds) Net Neutrality or Net Neutering: Should Broadband Internet Services be Regulated. Springer, Boston, MA . https://doi.org/10.1007/0-387-33928-0_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics