Skip to main content

Themes and Counterthemes: Fluid Capital in Retrospect

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Capital, Accumulation, and Money
  • 719 Accesses

Abstract

In general, this book has involved exploration of themes related to fluid capital. More explicitly, it has examined the implications of three definitions, one relating to a concept of capital and the other two relating to two macroeconomic identities. The definition of fluid capital provides a root concept of capital from which virtually all existing notions of capital can be connected and rationalized. The two identities, in contrast, involve equalities between the value of production in current prices and the income the production generates, and between the value of goods in the pool of fluid capital and the corresponding value of claims on the same.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    As should be evident from these paragraphs, it is inappropriate in my view to measure changes in the general price level in terms of standard Laspeyres price indices. Only current-quantity weighted chain indices provide meaningful measures of inflation and deflation.

  2. 2.

    This will be true, moreover, even in situations in which the stock of money is changed exogenously, as was the case, for example, when East and West Germany merged in 1990. Because of the pegging of the two marks at close to par, there was, in effect, a once-and-for-all increase in the stock of marks, with no offsetting increase in the pool of fluid capital. Again, there is no reason to assume that the part of the increased stock of marks that sought outlet against goods would be spread proportionately.

  3. 3.

    That capital has to finance both current production and investment in produced means of production has generally been overlooked in the literature on capital theory. A notable, but partial, exception was R.G. Hawtrey in his two early volumes on the trade cycle, Good and Bad Trade (1913) and Currency and Credit (1919). Hawtrey’s focus, however, was on the general availability of money and credit, rather than the relationship of these to fluid capital.

  4. 4.

    See Appendix B.

  5. 5.

    “Right” in this context is taken to mean that the pool of purchasing power that is created is consistent with a stable general price level.

  6. 6.

    See Davidson (1978, 2009), Minsky (1975, 2008).

  7. 7.

    See “Minsky’s moment,” Buttonwood, The Economist, April 2, 2009.

References

  • Davidson, P. (1978), Money and the Real World (second edition), John Wiley and Sons, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawtrey, R.G. (1913), Good and Bad Trade: An Inquiry into the Causes of Trade Fluctuations, Longmans and Green, London (reprinted by Augustus M. Kelley, 1962).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawtrey, R.G. (1919), Currency and Credit (second edition, 1923), Longmans and Green, London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H.P. (1975), John Maynard Keynes, Columbia University Press, New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H.P. (2008), Stabilizing an Unstable Economy, McGraw-Hill, New York, (First Edition, Yale University Press, 1986).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Lester D. Taylor .

Postscript

Postscript

Except for a footnote here and there, no mention has been made to this point of the financial excesses of 2002–2007 that culminated in the late summer and fall of 2008 in the most severe global economic crisis since the Great Depression of the 1930s. We now turn to an analysis of the tumultuous events of those years, with emphasis on an extremely important characteristic of a monetary production economy that was not given adequate attention in the original text, namely, the interaction between money as a store of value and the mass phenomena of confidence and uncertainty. Establishing the importance of this interaction in conjunction with the real constraints imposed on asset values by the pool of fluid capital is the purpose of the next two chapters. However, the focus in these chapters is not on the detailed events of the crisis of 2007–2009 per se – as a number of excellent chronicles of this already exist – but rather on the development of an understanding of why financial crises are an inherent feature of an economy with money and why their occurrence is unlikely ever to be banished. As much as anything, the two chapters of this postscript represent a disquisition on Keynes’s distinction between risk and uncertainty and why this distinction is key to understanding why financial crises are an inherent feature of an economy with money.

The most popular explanation of the 2007–2008 financial meltdown was the failure of banks and other financial institutions to manage the new “risks” posed by financial innovations, specifically in the form of securities backed by sub-prime mortgages and the use of a variety of exotic financial plays and instruments to insure and hedge against default. What was collectively overlooked by financial institutions and regulators alike in the buildup to the crisis was that, while risk can reasonably be managed at a micro level, this is not the case at the macro level. Risk can be spread, but in the aggregate cannot ever be banished, particularly when it shades into and mixes with uncertainty. Keynes, in Chaps. 12 and 17 of the General Theory and (especially) in his defense of the General Theory in 1937 article in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, understood this well, but, because of the insistence in mainstream macroeconomic theory to treat uncertainty mathematically as risk, the importance of Keynes’s insights in accounting for financial crises has only been appreciated and utilized by maverick “Post-Keynesians” like Paul Davidson and the late Hyman Minsky.Footnote 6 Increasingly, however, it is coming to be understood that the events of late summer and early fall of 2008 was in fact a “Minsky moment” – a time when the conjuncture of fear (from a collapse of confidence), uncertainty, and heightened liquidity preference morphed into a perfect financial storm.Footnote 7

In the two chapters of this postscript, the following themes will be center-stage:

  1. 1.

    A sharp distinction, as emphasized by Keynes (and Knight before him), between risk and uncertainty.

  2. 2.

    The existence of two aggregate markets in an economy: a goods market and an assets market, the dynamics of which are different.

  3. 3.

    Inherent instability of asset markets because of the interaction of confidence, uncertainty, and liquidity preference.

  4. 4.

    Asset values, both real and financial, derive from the pool of fluid capital, and which in the aggregate cannot increase faster than the rate of growth of income.

  5. 5.

    The interaction of confidence, uncertainty, and liquidity preference. Crises occur when confidence evaporates in the face of uncertainty, and there is a rush by asset holders to acquire money as a store of value.

  6. 6.

    The dangers of allowing new money creation to fuel speculation and wagering in asset markets. “Casinos with banks” have no place in asset markets.

  7. 7.

    Limiting money creation by the banking system to the funding of current production and the initial finance of investment in new produced means of production.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2010 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Taylor, L.D. (2010). Themes and Counterthemes: Fluid Capital in Retrospect. In: Capital, Accumulation, and Money. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-387-98169-7_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics