Skip to main content

Export Growth and Capitalist Development in Colombia in the Nineteenth Century

  • Chapter
Disparities in Economic Development since the Industrial Revolution
  • 55 Accesses

Abstract

Two basic methodological conceptions derived from the Latin American Dependency School are taken as the starting-point of our work. First of all, it is conceived that the question of the historical origins of international economic inequalities should be primarily posed as the question of the historical origin of different socio-economic structures, and not as a question of the divergent quantitative growth of the same underlying economic variables. It is only by understanding how these different structures arose that we can hope to understand the specific laws of motion that tend to produce what are commonly conceived as ‘international economic inequalities’. Secondly, it is conceived that the historical origins of the socio-economic formations which are usually called ‘underdeveloped’, ‘dependent’ or ‘peripheral’ capitalist formations are not independent of the historical process by which the advanced capitalist nations have reached maturity. Rather, one must conceptualise advanced and dependent capitalism as arising out of the same historical process. From the point of view of the study of dependent capitalist formations, this implies that one must search for a basic dependence of their laws of motion on their articulation within the world capitalist economy.

Basic support for this research has been provided by a Tinker Foundation Fellowship.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  • Sergio Elias Ortiz (ed.), Escritos de dos economistas coloniales (Bogotá, 1965) pp. 125–7, 130.

    Google Scholar 

  • See also David Bushnell, El Régimen de Santander en la Gran Colombia (Bogotá, 1966) pp. 19–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabriel Giraldo Jaramillo (ed.), Relaciones de Mando de los Virreyes de la Nueva Granada: Memorias Económicas (Bogotá, 1954) p. 165;

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaime Jaramillo Uribe, Ensayos sobre Historia Social Colombian (Bogotá, 1968) pp. 71–5;

    Google Scholar 

  • Germán Colmenares, Cali: terratenientes, mineros y comerciantes, siglo XVIII (Cali, 1975) pp. 76–7, chs 3 and 4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Juan A. Villamarin, ‘Haciendas en la Sabana de Bogotá, Colombia, en la época colonial’, in Haciendas, Latifundios y Plantaciones en América Latina (Mexico, 1975) p. 373;

    Google Scholar 

  • Margarita Gonzalez, El Resguardo en el Nuevo Reino de Granada (Bogotá, 1970) pp. 72–3;

    Google Scholar 

  • Orlando Fals Borda, El Hombre y la Tierra en Boyacá (Bogotá, 1973) pp. 82–3;

    Google Scholar 

  • Juan Friede, El Indio en la lucha por la tierra (Bogotá, 1972) pp. 91–7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bushnell, op. cit., pp. 113–17; José Manuel Restrepo, Historia de la Neuva Granada, Tomo I (Bogotá, 1952) pp. 137–8, 141, 145, 164, 179.

    Google Scholar 

  • For a development of the idea of the ‘Spirit of Capitalism’ in Bogotá, see Frank R. Safford, Commerce and Enterprise in Central Colombia, 1821–1870 (Ph D thesis, Columbia University, 1965) ch. 2. For a characterisation of the capitalists of the time, see the analysis of the concept of ‘producer-speculator’ in section 3 below.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giraldo Jaramillo (ed.), op. cit., pp. 64–5, 75–6, 122, 177; Anthony McFarlane, ‘El Comercio exterior del virreinato de la Nueva Granada’, Anuario Colombiano de Historia Social y de la Cultura, 1971–2, pp. 94–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • For forceful expressions of free trade thought, see the writings of Antonio de Narvaez and José Ignacio de Pombo in Ortiz (ed.), op. cit., especially pp. 41–60, 123–34, 137–44, and Pedro Fermin de Vargas, Pensamientos Políticos (Bogotá, 1968) pp. 19–20, 94–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank R. Safford, Aspectos del siglo XIX en Colombia (Medellín, 1977) pp. 237–9, and Commerce ..., ch. 4;

    Google Scholar 

  • Luis Ospina Vásquez, Industria y Protección en Colombia, 1810–1930 (Bogotá, 1955) ch. III.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calculated from the 1835 (Fernando Gomez, ‘Los Censos colombianos antes de 1905’, in Miguel Urrutia and Mario Arrubla, Compendio de estadisticas históricas de Colombia (Bogotá, 1970) Table 3 and 1912 (Official Publication)) population censuses. In intermediate periods, calculations are in the 1.3–1.8 per cent range. According to Fernando Gomez (Análisis de los censor de población en el siglo XIX (thesis, U. de los Andes, 1969) ch. 3) a consistency analysis of the 1835, 1843, 1851 and 1870 censuses gives a population growth of 1.7 per cent.

    Google Scholar 

  • In 1801–10, legal gold production was $ 2.3 million a year (José Manuel Restrepo, ‘Memoria sobre amonedación de oro y plata en la Nueva Granada’, in Historia de la Nueva Granada, (Bogotá, 1963) Vol. II pp. 455, 459). On the other hand, in its highest point (1802–4), merchandise exports through Cartagena were $ 784.500 a year (Semanario del Nuevo Reino de Granada (Bogotá, 1942) Vol. 1, p. 230). However, this was a period between two international wars and the value of exports can thus be considered exceptional (Ortiz, (ed.), op. cit., pp. 72–4, 95–9). Excluding illegal gold production, but including merchandise exports through all Colombian ports, however, total exports were probably no less than $ 3 million.

    Google Scholar 

  • Safford, Commerce ..., chs. 5 and 6; Luis Eduardo Nieto Arteta, Economía y cultura en la historia de Colombia (Bogotá, 1973) chs 17, 18, 20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alle M. Sievers, The Mystical World of Indonesia: Culture and Economic Developmentin Conflict (Baltimore, 1974) pp. 104–5, 142.

    Google Scholar 

  • John Parker Harrison, The Colombian Tobacco Industry, from Government Monopoly to Free Trade, 1778–1876 (PhD thesis, University of California, 1951) pp. 290–1, 296–7; Safford, Commerce ..., pp. 241–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Salomón Kalmanovitz, Desarrollo de la Agricultura en Colombia (Bogotá, 1978) p. 18;

    Google Scholar 

  • Absalón Machado, El Café: de la aparcería al capitalismo (Bogotá, 1977) ch. 4, p. 338.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nevertheless, Mariano Arango (Café e Industria, 1850–1930 (Bogotá, 1977) p. 125) claims that labour productivity was very similar in both forms of production.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mariano Arango, ‘Comentarios al Trabajo de Absalón Machado’, in El Agro en el desarrollo histórico colombiano (Bogotá, 1977) pp. 233–40; Safford, Aspectos ..., pp. 274–5.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Paul Bairoch Maurice Lévy-Leboyer

Copyright information

© 1981 Paul Bairoch and Maurice Lévy-Leboyer

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ocampo, JA. (1981). Export Growth and Capitalist Development in Colombia in the Nineteenth Century. In: Bairoch, P., Lévy-Leboyer, M. (eds) Disparities in Economic Development since the Industrial Revolution. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-04707-9_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics