Skip to main content

The dynamics of interest group evaluations of Congress

  • Chapter
Empirical Studies in Comparative Politics

Abstract

We apply a dynamic spatial model to interest group ratings of the members of Congress over the period 1959–1981. Spatial distances between an interest group and the members of Congress are assumed to be monotonic with the ratings. Our pooled cross-sectional time-series data set consists of 203,387 ratings by 59 interest groups. We restrict the spatial coordinates of the interest groups and members of Congress to be polynomial functions of time. Two significant dimensions are recovered: the first dimension, which accounts for approximately 75% of the variance, represents liberal-conservative positions on economic issues; the second dimension, which accounts for approximately an additional 5% of the variance, represents liberal-conservative positions on social issues. Nearly all the interest groups and most members of Congress are ideologically consistent. They are either liberal on both dimensions or conservative on both.

This work was supported by a grant from the National Science Foundation. An earlier version of this paper was presented at the “Information and Politics Conference”, Austin, Texas, 13–15 February 1986. Minor differences in results between this paper and the earlier version reflect the addition of the 1981 data and improvements to the algorithm used for the two- and three-dimensional scalings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. American Economic Review 78: 796–806.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck, N. (1983). Time-varying parameter regression models. American Journal of Political Science 27: 557–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernhardt, M. D. and Ingberman, D. (1985). Candidate reputations and the incumbency effect. Journal of Public Economics 27: 47–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bullock, C. S. III. (1981). Congressional voting and the 1982 congressional elections. Journal of Politics 45: 767–770.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cahoon, L. S., Melvin. J., Hinich, M.J. and Ordeshook, P. C. (1978). A statistical multidimensional scaling model based on the spational theory of voting. In P. C. Wang (Ed.), Graphical representation of multidimensional data, 243–278. New York:

    Google Scholar 

  • Academic Press. Calvert, R. L. (1985). Robustness of the multidimensional voting model: Candidates’ motivations, uncertainty, and convergence. American Journal of Political Science 26: 69–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Defays, D. (1978). A short note on a method of seriation. British Journal of Mathematical and Statistical Psychology 31: 49–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dougan, W. R. and Munger, M. C. (1989). The rationality of ideology. Journal of Law and Economics 32: 119–143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Enelow, J. M. and Hinich, M. J. (1984). The spatial theory of voting: An introduction. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erikson, R. S., Wright, G. C. and McIver, J. P. (1993). Statehouse democracy: Public opinion and policy in the American States. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hibbs, D. (1977). Political parties and macroeconomic policy. American Political Science Review 71: 1467–1487.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. (1978). Some evidence on non-voting in the spatial theory of electoral competition. Public Choice 33: 83–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. J. and Munger, M. I. (1994). Ideology and the theory of political choice. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. J. and Pollard, W. (1981). A new approach to the spatial theory of electoral competition. American Journal of Political Science 25: 323–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinich, M. J. and Roll, R. (1981). Measuring nonstationarity in the parameters of the market model. Research in Finance 3: 1–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubert, L. and Arabie, P. (1986). Unidimensional scaling and combinatorial optimization. In: de Leeuw et al. (Eds.), Multidimensional data analysis. Leiden: DSWO Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingberman, D. (1985). Spatial competition with imperfectly informed voters. Mimeo. University of Pennsylvania.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalt, J. and Zupan, M. (1984). Capture and ideology in the economic theory of politics. American Economic Review 74: 279–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kernell, S. (1973). Is the Senate more liberal than the House? Journal of Politics 35: 332–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Khrebiel, K. and Rivers, D. (1985). Congressional roll call strategies: An application of a new test to minimum wage legislation. Paper presented at the 1985 annual meeting of the American Political Science Association.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ladha, K. K. (1994). A spatial model of legislative voting with perceptual error. Public Choice 68: 151–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCarty, N.M., Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1997). Income redistribution and the realignment of American Politics. Washington, DC: AEI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ordeshook, P. C. (1976). The spatial theory of elections: A review and a critique. In I. Budge, I. Crewe, and D. Farlie (Eds.), Party identification and beyond. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. (1981). Dimensions of interest group evaluation of the U.S. Senate, 1969–1978. American Journal of Political-Science 25: 49–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. (1984). Least squares metric, unidimensional unfolding. Ps_chometrika 49: 311–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. (1990). Least squares metric, unidimensional scaling of multivariate linear models. Psychometrika 55: 123–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Daniels, R. S. (1985). Ideology, party, and voting in the U.S. Congress, 1959–1980. American Political Science Review 79: 373–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1984a). U.S. presidential elections: 1968–1980. A spatial analysis. American Journal of Political Science 28: 282–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1984b). The polarization of American politics. Journal of Politics 46: 1062–1079.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1985a). A spatial model for legislative roll call analysis. American Journal of Political Science 29: 357–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1985b). The unidimensional Congress. Mimeo. Carnegie Mellon University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1987). The regional realignment of Congress, 1919–1984. In P. Galderisi and R. Simmons (Eds.), Politics in the Intermountain West: Forerunner to realignment Boulder CO: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1991). Patterns of congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science 35: 228–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poole, K. T. and Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political-economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabinowitz, G. (1976). A procedure for ordering object pairs consistent with the multidimensional unfolding model. Psychometrika 45: 349–373.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rivers, D. (1987). Inconsistency of least squares unfolding. Paper presented at the Political Methodology Meetings, Durnham, NC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1987). Modern political economy and the study of regulation. In E.E. Bailey (Ed.), Public regulation: New perspectives on institutions and politics. Cambridge MA: M.I.T. Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snyder, J. M. Jr. (1992). Artificial extremism in interest group ratings. Legislative Studies Quarterly 17: 319–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittman, D. (1983). Candidate motivation: A synthesis of alternatives. American Political Science Review 77: 142–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 1998 Springer Science+Business Media Dordrecht

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Poole, K.T., Rosenthal, H. (1998). The dynamics of interest group evaluations of Congress. In: Hinich, M.J., Munger, M.C. (eds) Empirical Studies in Comparative Politics. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4757-5127-7_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4757-5127-7_5

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Boston, MA

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-4419-5072-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-4757-5127-7

  • eBook Packages: Springer Book Archive

Publish with us

Policies and ethics