Skip to main content

Reason and Rationality in Organization Studies: Employee Motivation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Venture Work
  • 395 Accesses

Abstract

The chapter examines the literature that contrasts reason and rationality, wherein the former is defined as the human cognitive faculty being responsive to social, cultural, and behavioral conditions wherein the individual acts and makes decisions. When enacting reason, concepts such as norms, beliefs, and values are included in, for example, decision-making. In contrast, rationality is a term reserved for calculative and instrumental thinking wherein factors that cannot be accommodated by current calculative practices are either excluded or simplified to the point wherein they are lending themselves to numerical operations and metrics. Reason and rationality are thereafter discussed in terms of their value and role in social and economic activities, including, for example, the domain of venture work, dependent on both these human cognitive faculties. For instance, to tolerate ambiguities and uncertainty at work, one of the core features of any innovative or entrepreneurial pursuit, the capacity to construct meaningful images of work is helpful to impose a structure and a direction on everyday work.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In probability theory, ergodicity means that a behavior is averaged over time (i.e., a system displays a certain degree of predictability over repeated empirical observations). In economic theory, individual cases are seen as being evidence of a behavior that will be repeated over time, say, as in the case of preferences and choices, where an individual, for example, once demonstrating a preference for strawberry and chocolate ice-cream makes the same choices repeatedly over time. Critics of this assumption claim for instance that preferences are neither endogenous (i.e., unaffected by the choices of other human actors or other external factors), nor of necessity are consistent over time. That is, the preference for strawberry and chocolate ice-cream at one decision point may therefore be complemented by a choice of, for example, vanilla and pecan nut ice-cream at a second observation, indicating that preferences are unstable, thus making preferences and choices “non-ergodic.”

  2. 2.

    Collins (1981) stresses that abstract concepts (“grand theories” in Mills’ 1959, vocabulary) need to be substantiated by empirical material to make sense: “Sociological concepts can be made fully empirical only by grounding them in a sample of the typical micro-events that make them up. The implication is that the ultimate empirical validation of sociological statements depends upon their microtranslation” (Collins 1981: 988. Emphasis in the original).

References

  • Amadae, S. M. (2003). Rationalizing capitalist democracy: The Cold War origins of rational choice liberalism. Chicago/London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnoldi, J. (2016). Computer algorithms, market manipulation and the institutionalization of high frequency trading. Theory, Culture & Society, 33(1), 29–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, J. M., Grant, A. M., & Johnson, V. (2010). When callings are calling: Crafting work and leisure in pursuit of unanswered occupational callings. Organization Science, 21, 973–994.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein, L. (1992). Opting out of the legal system: Extralegal contractual relations in the diamond industry. The Journal of Legal Studies, 21(1), 115–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, M. M., & Stout, L. A. (2001). Director accountability and the mediating role of the corporate board. Washington University Law Review, 79(2), 403–449.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bunderson, J. S., & Thompson, J. A. (2009). The call of the wild: Zookeepers, callings, and the double-edged sword of deeply meaningful work. Administrative Science Quarterly, 54(1), 32–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buturovic, Z., & Tasic, S. (2015). Kahneman’s failed revolution against economic orthodoxy. Critical Review, 27(2), 127–145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardon, M. S., Post, C., & Forster, W. R. (2017). Team entrepreneurial passion: Its emergence and influence in new venture teams. Academy of Management Review, 42(1), 283–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charny, D. (1990). Nonlegal sanctions in commercial relationships. Harvard Law Review, 104(2), 393–467.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, J. (2017). The power of economists within the state. Redwood City: Stanford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Citron, D. K., & Pasquale, F. A. (2014). The scored society: Due process for automated predictions. Washington Law Review, 89(1), 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collins, R. (1981). On the microfoundations of macrosociology. American Journal of Sociology, 86(5), 984–1014.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coombs, N. (2016). What is an algorithm? Financial regulation in the era of high-frequency trading. Economy and Society, 45(2), 278–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Correll, S. J., Ridgeway, C. L., Zuckerman, E. W., Jank, S., Jordan-Bloch, S., & Nakagawa, S. (2017). It’s the conventional thought that counts: How third-order inference produces status advantage. American Sociological Review, 82(2), 297–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. J. (2000). The market that antitrust built: Public policy, private coercion, and railroad acquisitions, 1825 to 1922. American Sociological Review, 65(5), 631–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F., & Kelly, E. L. (2007). How to stop harassment: Professional construction of legal compliance in organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 112(4), 1203–1243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, L. (1992). Legal ambiguity and symbolic structures: Organizational meditation of civil rights law. American Journal of Sociology, 97(6), 1531–1576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, L. B., Uggen, C., & Erlanger. Howard S. (1999). The endogeneity of legal regulation: Grievance procedures as rational myth. American Journal of Sociology, 105(2), 406–454.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erickson, P., Klein, J. L., Daston, L., Lemov, R., Sturm, T., & Gordin, M. D. (2013). How reason almost lost its mind: The strange career of Cold War rationality. Chicago/London: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fourcade, M. (2009). Economists and societies: Discipline and profession in the United States, Britain, and France, 1890s to 1990s. Princeton/London: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fourcade, M., & Healy, K. (2017). Seeing like a market. Socio-Economic Review, 15(1), 9–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fourcade, M., Ollion, E., & Algan, Y. (2015). The superiority of economists. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 29(1), 89–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fukuyama, F. (2016). Governance: What do we know, and how do we know it? Annual Review of Political Science, 19, 89–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, D. P., & Shapiro, I. (1994). Pathologies of rational choice theory: A critique of applications in political science. New Haven/London: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsh, C. E. (2009). The strength of weak enforcement: The impact of discrimination charges, legal environments, and organizational conditions on workplace segregation. American Sociological Review, 74(2), 245–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hyman, L. (2011). Debtor nation: The history of America in red ink. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Johns, F. (2016). Global governance through the pairing of list and algorithm. Environment and Planning D: Society and Space, 34(1), 126–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jolls, C., Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. R. (1998). A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Review, 50, 1471–1550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kar, R. (2016). Contract as empowerment. The University of Chicago Law Review, 83(2), 759–834.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keys, B. J., Mukherjee, T., Seru, A., & Vig, V. (2009). Did securitization lead to lax screening? Evidence from subprime loans. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, 307–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lang, A. T. F. (2013). The legal construction of economic rationalities. Journal of Law and Society, 40(1), 155–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, A.-C., Lenglet, M., & Seyfert, R. (2016). Cultures of high-frequency trading: Mapping the landscape of algorithmic developments in contemporary financial markets. Economy and Society, 45(2), 149–165.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenglet, M., & Mol, J. (2016). Squaring the speed of light? Regulating market access in algorithmic finance. Economy and Society, 45(2), 201–229.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liu, Y., & Grusky, D. B. (2013). The payoff to skill in the third industrial revolution. American Journal of Sociology, 118(5), 1330–1374.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Macaulay, S. (1963). Non-contractual relations in business: A preliminary study. American Sociological Review, 28(1), 55–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mead, G. H. (1934). Mind, self, and society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mills, C. W. (1959). The sociological imagination. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, J. B. (1995). Rational choice theory as social physics. Critical Review, 9(1–2), 155–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neyland, D. (2015). On organizing algorithms. Theory, Culture and Society, 32(1), 119–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Offer, A., & Söderberg, G. (2016). The Nobel factor: The prize in economics, social democracy, and the market turn. Princeton/London: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pasquale, F. (2015). The black box society: The secret algorithms that control money and information. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pedriana, N., & Stryker, R. (2004). The strength of a weak agency: Enforcement of Title VII of the 1964 Civil Rights Act and the expansion of state capacity, 1965–1971. American Journal of Sociology, 110(3), 709–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polillo, S. (2011). Money, moral authority, and the politics of creditworthiness. American Sociological Review, 76(3), 437–464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Posner, E. A. (1996). Law, economics, and inefficient norms. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 144(5), 1697–1744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reynaud, B. (2017). Forms of trust and conditions for their stability. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 41(1), 127–1145.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rizzo, M. J., & Whitman, D. G. (2009). The knowledge problem of new paternalism. Brigham Young University Law Review, 905(4), 905–968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rona-Tas, A., & Hiss, S. (2010). The role of ratings in the subprime mortgage crisis: The art of corporate and the science of consumer credit rating. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 30A, 115–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schabram, K., & Maitlis, S. (2017). Negotiating the challenge of a calling: Sensemaking in animal shelter work. Academy of Management Journal, 60(2), 584–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selznick, P. (1959). The sociology of law. Journal of Legal Education, 12, 521–531.

    Google Scholar 

  • Selznick, P. (1963). Legal institutions and social controls. Vanderbilt Law Review, 17, 79–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmel, G. (1978). The philosophy of money. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simmons, O. S. (2015). Delaware’s global threat. Journal of Corporation Law, 41(1), 217–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, D. G. (2002). Critical resource theory of fiduciary duty. Vanderbilt Law Review, 55, 1399–1497.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steiner, C. (2012). Automate this: How algorithms came to rule our world. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sullivan, T. A., Warren, E., & Westbrook, J. L. (2006). Less stigma and more financial distress: An empirical analysis of the extraordinary increase in bankruptcy filings. Stanford Law Review, 59(1), 213–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2003). Libertarian paternalism. The American Economic Review, 93(2), 175–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Totaro, P., & Ninno, D. (2014). The concept of algorithm as an interpretative key of modern rationality. Theory, Culture and Society, 31(4), 29–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Troyer, L., & Younts, C. W. (1997). Whose expectations matter? The relative power of first-order and second-order expectations in determining social influence. American Journal of Sociology, 103(3), 692–732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilde, O. (2016). Only dull people are brilliant at breakfast. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Willer, R., Kuwabara, K., & Macy Michael, W. (2009). The false enforcement of unpopular norms. American Journal of Sociology, 115(2), 451–490.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wittgenstein, L. (1953). Remarks in the foundations of mathematics (G. H. von Wright, R. Rhees & G. E. M. Anscombe, Ed., & G. E. M. Anscombe, Trans.). Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, A. L., Zammuto, R. F., & Liesch, P. W. (2017). Maintaining the value of a profession: Institutional work and moral emotions in the emergency department. Academy of Management Journal, 60(1), 200–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wrzesniewski, A., & Dutton, J. E. (2001). Crafting a job: Revisioning employees as active crafters of their work. Academy of Management Review, 26, 179–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zarsky, T. (2016). The trouble with algorithmic decisions: An analytic road map to examine efficiency and fairness in automated and opaque decision making. Science, Technology, & Human Values, 41(1), 118–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziewitz, M. (2016). Governing algorithms: Myth, mess, and methods. Science, Technology, & Human Values, 41(1), 3–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Styhre, A. (2019). Reason and Rationality in Organization Studies: Employee Motivation. In: Venture Work. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-03180-0_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics