Skip to main content

Theoretical Discussion of Vertical Integration and Regulation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Vertical Integration and Regulation

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Law ((BRIEFSLAW))

  • 374 Accesses

Abstract

The core focus of this thesis is to assess the degree of regulation required to ensure the highest level of societal welfare, the lowest (consumer) prices and the most competition on markets. To properly conduct the assessment, all terms need to be defined. As a first step, the general concept of regulation is presented (Sect. 2.1). Afterwards the legal aspects of vertical integration (Sect. 2.2) and the economic aspects of vertical integration (Sect. 2.3) are outlined in order to properly situate the investigation in the body of the existing literature.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Edwards (1953), pp. 404.

  2. 2.

    Hornby and Turnbull (2010).

  3. 3.

    There is no legal consensus on whether or not regulation law refers to a particular source and field of law, see Basedow (2004), pp. 3–20; Voßkuhle (2003), pp. 266–335; Eifert (2006), § 19.

  4. 4.

    See Kühling (2004).

  5. 5.

    See Robinson (1934), pp. 104–120; Stigler (1957), pp. 1–17; Aumann (1964), pp. 39–50; Anderson (1992), Chap. 14.

  6. 6.

    See Engel and Morlok (1998); van Aken (2004), pp. 1–32; Furubotn and Richter (2010); Homann and Suchanek (2005); Denkhaus (2004), pp. 33–60.

  7. 7.

    For more information on the desirable market result according to economists, see the comprehensive body of literature on the Pareto criterium e.g. Pareto (1906).

  8. 8.

    See Hayek (1969).

  9. 9.

    Positive external effects are not considered. They are assumed to be a by-product which is a neat positive development.

  10. 10.

    See Endres (1994); Eskeland (1994), pp. 373–394; Ebert (1991/1992), pp. 154–166; Hurwicz (1995), pp. 49–74; Kahneman et al. (1990), pp. 1325–1348.

  11. 11.

    See Lyon (1996), pp. 227–247; Dehmel (2011).

  12. 12.

    See Schmalensee (1989), pp. 417–436; Niemeier (2002), pp. 37–48.

  13. 13.

    See Crew and Kleindorfer (1996), pp. 211–225.

  14. 14.

    See Taggart (1981), pp. 383–393; Solomon (1970), pp. 65–81; Sherman (1977), pp. 240–248.

  15. 15.

    See Liston (1993), pp. 25–48; Pint (1992), pp. 564–578.

  16. 16.

    See Averch and Johnson (1962), pp. 1052–1069; Spann (1974), pp. 38–52; Bailey and Coleman (1971), pp. 278–292.

  17. 17.

    See Brunekreeft (2003), Chap. 4 Price-cap regulation; Cabral and Riordan (1989), pp. 93–102; Braeutigam and Panzar (1993), pp. 191–198; Cowan (2002), pp. 167–188.

  18. 18.

    See Healy and Palepu (2001), pp. 405–440; Acharya et al. (2009), pp. 89–137; Nicolaides (1992), pp. 113–121.

  19. 19.

    See Fritsch (2011), pp. 198 ff.

  20. 20.

    See Lipsky and Sidak (1998), pp. 1187–1248; Bergman (2001), pp. 403–434; Kezsbom and Goldman (1996), pp. 1–36; Soma et al. (1998), pp. 565–614.

  21. 21.

    This is especially applicable for postal services and the telecommunications sector, see Gabrisch (1996); Elsenbast (1999).

  22. 22.

    See Égert (2009); Smith (1997).

  23. 23.

    See Montoya and Trillas (2009), pp. 113-134; Stern (1997), pp. 67–74.

  24. 24.

    See Kamps (2006), pp. 133–142; Benz (1997), pp. 419–537; Holznagel et al. (2008).

  25. 25.

    See Battis and Kersten (2003), pp. 349-357; Ladeur (2005), pp. 753–764; Schmidt-Assmann (1993), pp. 697–711.

  26. 26.

    See Rockholz (2001); Rutkowsky (1998).

  27. 27.

    See Behrendt et al. (1996), pp. 114–115.

  28. 28.

    See Kümpel and Wittig (2011); Follak (1986).

  29. 29.

    See Kingreen (2005), pp. 505–511.

  30. 30.

    See Gärditz (2005), pp. 490–497; Wieland (1995), pp 315 ff.

  31. 31.

    See Besche (2004); Forster (2007).

  32. 32.

    See Boysen et al. (2007).

  33. 33.

    See Hufen (1994), pp. 2913–2921.

  34. 34.

    See Federal German Constitutional Court Decisions 7, 377; 13, 97; 13, 181; 19, 337; 28, 374; 33, 125; 33, 303; 39, 225; 54, 301; 82, 209; 93, 235.

  35. 35.

    See Badura (2003), pp. 785–800; Wollenschläger (2013), pp. 7–16.

  36. 36.

    See Riedel (2012).

  37. 37.

    See Möllinger (2009).

  38. 38.

    See Altwicker (2011), pp. 364–378.

  39. 39.

    Art. 109 (2) GG.

  40. 40.

    Art. 23 (1) GG.

  41. 41.

    Art. 24 GG.

  42. 42.

    See ECJ, Case 26/62 van Gend en Loos.

  43. 43.

    See Ginsburg (2005), pp. 107–123.

  44. 44.

    See Gugler et al. (2017), pp. 450–478.

  45. 45.

    See Acemoglu and Johnson (2005), pp. 949–995; Doidge et al. (2007), pp. 1–39; Claessens and Yurtoglu (2013), pp. 1–33.

  46. 46.

    See Pollitt (2008), pp. 704–713; Steiner (2000), Jamasb and Pollitt (2005), pp. 11–41.

  47. 47.

    See Cave and Martin (1994), pp. 12–20.

  48. 48.

    See Cave (2007), pp. 89–103.

  49. 49.

    Usually the term “enterprise” is used. In this particular circumstance the term “fringe firms” is used as a technical term.

  50. 50.

    Usually the term “enterprise” is used. In this particular circumstance the term “dominant firm” is used as a technical term.

  51. 51.

    See Baumol et al. (1983), pp. 491–496; Scholtka (2005), pp. 2421–2425.

  52. 52.

    See Storr (2006), pp. 1017–1026.

  53. 53.

    See Säcker (2009), pp. 78–85; Brunekreeft (2003).

  54. 54.

    See Federal German Administrative Court (2001), pp. 1399–1407.

  55. 55.

    Knittel (2006), pp. 201–222.

  56. 56.

    See Semigran et al. (2017), pp. E186–E192; Granados et al. (2010), pp. 207–226.

  57. 57.

    See Stahler and Upmann (2008), pp. 611–626.

  58. 58.

    See Pünder (2006), pp. 567–599.

  59. 59.

    See Crocioni and Veljanovski (2003), pp. 28–60; Heimler (2010), pp. 879–890; Gaudin and Saavedra (2014), pp. 157–172.

  60. 60.

    See Carlton (2008), pp. 271–278; Sidak (2008), pp. 279–309; Geradin and O’Donoghue (2005), pp. 355–425; Hou (2014), pp. 43–74.

  61. 61.

    See Jung (2017), pp. 981–1020.

  62. 62.

    See Hart and Tirole (1990), p. 205.

  63. 63.

    For a comprehensive discussion on the effects of vertical integration see Riordan (1998), pp. 1232–1248; Foros and Stehen (2013), pp. 640–661; Hart and Tirole (1990), pp. 205–286; Beard et al. (2001), pp. 319–333; Edwards (1953), pp. 404–410; Riordan and Salop (1995), pp. 513–568; Siegwarth Meyer and Wang (2011), pp. 7–11.

  64. 64.

    For more information on game theory see Berninghaus et al. (2010); Strategische Spiele: eine Einführung in die Spieltheorie; Rieck (2007); Holler and Illing (2009).

  65. 65.

    See Devlin (2007), pp. 1111–1151; Watson (1998), pp. 1769–1769; Noel (2016), pp. 287–311.

  66. 66.

    See Maskin and Tirole (1988), pp. 571–599.

  67. 67.

    For the first case see Spengler (1950), pp. 347–352.

  68. 68.

    See Salinger (1988), p. 354; Riordan and Salop (1995), p. 517; Siegwarth Meyer and Wang (2011), p. 8.

  69. 69.

    See Spengler (1950), p. 352.

  70. 70.

    See Edwards (1953), p. 405; Siegwarth Meyer and Wang (2011), p. 7.

  71. 71.

    See Hart and Tirole (1990), p. 213; Yamawake et al. (2018), pp. 1028 ff.

  72. 72.

    See Kim and Nora (2018), pp. 1 ff.

  73. 73.

    See Edwards (1953), p. 410.

  74. 74.

    See Footnote 73.

  75. 75.

    See Edwards (1953), p. 408.

  76. 76.

    See Salinger (1988), p. 349.

  77. 77.

    See Salinger (1988), p. 355.

  78. 78.

    See Normann (2008), pp. 7f.

  79. 79.

    See Footnote 77.

  80. 80.

    See lately Nocke and Rey (2018), pp. 183 ff.

  81. 81.

    See Edwards (1953), p. 409.

  82. 82.

    See Edwards (1953), pp. 406 f.

  83. 83.

    See Normann (2008), p. 30; Siegwarth Meyer and Wang (2011), p. 7.

  84. 84.

    See Rey and Stiglitz (1988), p. 1.

  85. 85.

    See Rey and Stiglitz (1988).

  86. 86.

    See Rey and Stiglitz (1988), p. 4.

  87. 87.

    See Rey and Stiglitz (1988), p. 13 f.

  88. 88.

    See Deneckere et al. (1996), pp. 885–913; Shaffer (1991), pp. 120–135.

  89. 89.

    See Hart and Tirole (1990), pp. 231 f.

  90. 90.

    See Beard et al. (2001), pp. 319–333.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S (2005) Unbundling institutions. J Polit Econ 113(5):949–995

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acharya V, Philippon T, Richardson M, Roubini N (2009) The financial crisis of 2007–2009: causes and remedies. Finan Markets Institutions Instrum 18(2):89–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Altwicker T (2011) Menschenrechtlicher Gleichheitsschutz. Springer, Heidelberg

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson RM (1992) The core in perfectly competitive economies. In: Aumann H (ed) Handbook of game theory, Chapter 14. Elsevier Science Publishers, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Aumann RJ (1964) Markets with a continuum of traders. Econometrica 32(1–2):39–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Averch H, Johnson LL (1962) Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. Am Econ Rev 52(5):1052–1069

    Google Scholar 

  • Badura P (2003) Das Berufsrecht in der Rechtsprechung des Bundesverwaltungsgerichts. In: Schmidt-Aßmann E, Sellner D, Hirsch G, Kemper GH, Lehmann-Grube H (eds) Festgabe 50 Jahre Bundesverwaltungsgericht. Carl Heymanns, Cologne, pp 785–800

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailey EE, Coleman RD (1971) The effect of lagged regulation in an Averch-Johnson model. Bell J Econ Manage Sci 2(1):278–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Basedow J (2004) Wirtschaftsregulierung zwischen Beschränkung und Förderung des Wettbewerbs. In: Fuchs A, Schwintowski H-P, Zimmer D (eds) Wirtschafts- und Privatrecht im Spannungsfeld von Privatautonomie. Wettbewerb und Regulierung: Festschrift für Ulrich Immenga zum 70. Geburtstag. C. H. Beck, Munich, pp 3–20

    Google Scholar 

  • Battis U, Kersten J (2003) Die rechtlichen Rahmenbedingungen für die verhandelnde Verwaltung im Hochschulbereich. Deutsches Verwaltungsblatt 118:349–357

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol WJ, Panzar JC, Willig RD (1983) Contestable markets: an uprising in the theory of industry structure: reply. Am Econ Rev 73(3):491–496

    Google Scholar 

  • Beard TR, Kaserman DL, Mayo JW (2001) Regulation, vertical integration and sabotage. J Ind Econ 49(3):319–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behrendt S, Köplin D, Kreibich R, Rogall H, Seidemann T (1996) Logistikkonzepte zur Rücknahme und Verwertung von Fernsehgeräten. In: Behrendt S, Köplin D, Kreibich R, Rogall H, Seidemann T (eds) Umweltgerechte Produktgestaltung: ECO-Design in der elektronischen Industrie. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 114–115

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Benz A (1997) Privatisierung und Regulierung im Rundfunk. In: König B (ed) Privatisierung und staatliche Regulierung: Bahn, Post und Telekommunikation, Rundfunk. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 419–537

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergman MA (2001) The role of the essential facilities doctrine. Antitrust Bull 46(2):403–434

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berninghaus SK, Ehrhart K-M, Güth W (2010) Strategische Spiele: eine Einführung in die Spieltheorie, 3rd edn. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Besche B (2004) Wasser und Wettbewerb: Möglichkeiten und Grenzen einer Öffnung des Wassermarkts. Peter Lang, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Boysen S, Bühring F, Franzius C, Herbst T, Kötter M, Kreutz A, von Lewinski K, Meinel F, Nolte J, Schönrock S (2007) Netzwerke: 47. Assistententagung Öffentliches Recht Berlin 2007. Tagung der Wissenschaftlichen Mitarbeiterinnen und Mitarbeiter, Wissenschaftlichen Assistentinnen und Assistenten. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Braeutigam RR, Panzar JC (1993) Effects of the change from rate-of-return to price-cap regulation. Am Econ Rev 83(2):191–198

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunekreeft G (2003) Regulation and competition policy in the electricity market: economic analysis and german experience. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral LMB, Riordan MH (1989) Incentives for cost reduction under price cap regulation. J Regul Econ 1(2):93–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlton DW (2008) Should “Price Squeeze” be a recognized form of anticompetitive conduct? J Competition Law Econ 4(2):271–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cave ME (2007) Six degrees of separation operational separation as a remedy in european telecommunications regulation. Commun Strat 64:89–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Cave M, Martin I (1994) The costs and benefits of accounting separation: the Australian and British debates. Telecommun Policy 18(1):12–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Claessens S, Yurtoglu BB (2013) Corporate governance in emerging markets: a survey. Emerg Mark Rev 15:1–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cowan S (2002) Price-cap regulation. Swed Econ Policy Rev 9:167–188

    Google Scholar 

  • Crew MA, Kleindorfer PR (1996) Incentive regulation in the United Kingdom and the United States: some lessons. J Regul Econ 9(3):211–225

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dehmel F (2011) Anreizregulierung von Stromübertragungsnetzen: eine Systemanalyse in Bezug auf ausgewählte Renditeeffekte. Dissertation. Katholische Universität Eichstätt-Ingolstadt, Eichstädt-Ingolstadt

    Google Scholar 

  • Deneckere R, Marvel HP, Peck J (1996) Demand uncertainty, inventories, and resale price maintenance. Quart J Econ 111(3):885–913

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denkhaus W (2004) Die neue Institutionenökonomik und das Governancekonzept: Zum Wandel der ökonomischen Theorie und ihren Implikationen für die Verwaltungsrechtswissenschaft. In: Bungenberg M, Danz S, Heinrich H, Hünemörder O, Schmidt C, Schroeder R, Sichert A, Unroth F (eds) Recht und Ökonomik: 44. Assistententagung Öffentliches Recht Jena 2004. C. H. Beck, Munich, pp 33–60

    Google Scholar 

  • Devlin A (2007) A proposed solution to the problem of parallel pricing in oligopolistic markets. Stanford Law Rev 59(4):1111–1151

    Google Scholar 

  • Doidge C, Karolyi GA, Stulz RM (2007) Why do countries matter so much for corporate governance. J Financ Econ 86(1):1–39

    Google Scholar 

  • Ebert U (1991/1992) Pigouvian tax and market structure: the case of oligopoly and different abatement technologies. FinanzArchiv/Public Finan Anal 49(2):154–166

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards CD (1953) Vertical integration and the monopoly problem. J Mark 17(4):404–410

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Égert B (2009) Infrastructure investment in network industries: the role of incentive regulation and regulatory independence. CESifo Working paper series no. 2642

    Google Scholar 

  • Eifert M (2006) Regulierungsstrategien. In: Hoffmann-Riem W, Schmidt-Aßmann E, Voßkuhle A (eds) Grundlagen des Verwaltungsrechts. C. H. Beck, Munich, § 19

    Google Scholar 

  • Elsenbast W (1999) Universaldienst unter Wettbewerb: Ökonomische Analyse neuer regulierungspolitischer Ansätze zur Sicherstellung der postalischen Infrastruktur. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Endres A (1994) Strategien der Internalisierung externen Effekte: Pigou-Steuer und Coase-Theorem. FernUniversität Hagen, Hagen

    Google Scholar 

  • Engel C, Morlok M (1998) Öffentliches Recht als ein Gegenstand ökonomischer Forschung: Die Begegnung der deutschen Staatsrechtlehre mit der Konstitutionellen Politischen Ökonomie. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Eskeland GS (1994) A presumptive pigovian tax: complementing regulation to mimic an emission fee. World Bank Econ Rev 8(1):373–394

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Federal German Administrative Court (2001) Entbündelter Zugang zu Teilnehmerausschlussleitungen. Neue Zeitschrift für Verwaltungsrecht 20(12):1399–1407

    Google Scholar 

  • Follak K-P (1986) Kreditwesenaufsicht: Funktionssicherung durch Risikomanagement. Österreichische Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht 13

    Google Scholar 

  • Foros O, Stehen F (2013) Vertical control and price cycles in gasoline retailing. Scand J Econ 115(3):640–661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forster F (2007) Privatisierung Regulierung der Wasserversorgung in Deutschland und den Vereinigten Staaten von Amerika. Duncker & Humblodt, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch M (2011) Marktversagen und Wirtschaftspolitik: Mikroökonomische Grundlagen staatlichen Handelns, 8th edn. Franz Vahlen, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Furubotn EG, Richter R (2010) Neue Institutionenökonomik: Eine Einführung und kritische Würdigung, 4th edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gabrisch C (1996) Universaldienst in Deutschland: Neukonzeption für einen liberalisierten Telekommunikationsmarkt. Deutscher Universitätsverlag, Wiesbaden

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gärditz KF (2005) EG-Wettbewerbsrecht und Postmarktliberalisierung. Europäisches Wirtschafts- und Steuerrecht 2005(11):490–497

    Google Scholar 

  • Gaudin G, Saavedra C (2014) Ex ante margin squeeze test in the telecommunications industry: what is a reasonably efficient operation. Telecommun Policy 38(2):157–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geradin D, O’Donoghue R (2005) The concurrent application of competition law and regulation: the case of margin squeeze abuses in the telecommunications sector. J Competition Law Econ 1(2):355–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ginsburg T (2005) International substitutes for domestic institutions: bilateral investment treaties and governance. Int Rev Law Econ 25(1):107–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granados N, Gupta A, Kauffman RJ (2010) Information transparency in business-to-consumer markets: concepts, framework, and research agenda. Inf Syst Res 21(2):207–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gugler K, Liebensteiner M, Schmitt S (2017) Vertical disintegration in the European electricity sector: empirical evidence on lost synergies. Int J Ind Organ 52:450–478

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O, Tirole J (1990) Vertical integration and market foreclosure. Brookings papers: microeconomics special issue, pp 205–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1969) Freiburger Studien: gesammelte Aufsätze. Mohr, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Healy PM, Palepu KG (2001) Information asymmetry, corporate disclosure, and the capital markets: a review of the empirical disclosure literature. J Account Econ 31(1–3):405–440

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heimler A (2010) Is a margin squeeze an antitrust or regulatory violation. J Competition Law Econ 6(4):879–890

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holler MJ, Illing G (2009) Einführung in die Spieltheorie, 7th edn. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Holznagel B, Dörr D, Hildebrand D (2008) Elektronische Medien: Entwicklung und Regulierungsbedarf. Vahlen, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Homann K, Suchanek A (2005) Ökonomik: Eine Einführung, 2nd edn. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Hornby AS, Turnbull J (2010) Oxford advanced learner’s dictionary of current English, 8th edn. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Hou L (2014) The abusive nature of price squeezes in the EU. Int Rev Intellect Property Competition 45:43–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hufen F (1994) Berufsfreiheit: Erinnerung an ein Grundrecht. Neue Juristische Wochenschrift 45:2913–2921

    Google Scholar 

  • Hurwicz L (1995) What is the coase theorem. Jpn World Econ 7(1):49–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jamasb T, Pollitt M (2005) Electricity market reform in the European Union: review of progress toward liberalization & integration. Energy J 26 (Special Issue):11–41 (European Electricity Liberalisation)

    Google Scholar 

  • Jung D (2017) Art. 102 AEUV. In: Grabitz E, Hilf M, Nettesheim M (eds) Das Recht der Europäischen Union. C.H. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D, Knetsch JL, Thaler RH (1990) Experimental tests of the endowment effect and coase theorem. J Polit Econ 98(6):1325–1348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kamps K (2006) Rundfunkaufsicht: Ordnungsstrukturen im digitalen Zeitalter. In: Klumpp D, Kubicek H, Roßnagel A, Schulz W (eds) Medien, Ordnung und Information. Springer, Berlin, pp 133–142

    Google Scholar 

  • Kezsbom A, Goldman AV (1996) No shortcut to antitrust analysis: the twisted journey of the “Essential Facilities” doctrine. Columbia Bus Law Rev 1996(1):1–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim K, Nora V (2018) Does vertical integration enhance non-price efficiency: evidence from the movie theater industry. Working paper series economics. Nazarbayev University, Astana

    Google Scholar 

  • Kingreen T (2005) Ein neuer rechtlicher Rahmen für einen Binnenmarkt für Gesundheitsleistungen. Neue Zeitschrift für Sozialrecht 2005(10):505–511

    Google Scholar 

  • Knittel CR (2006) The adoption of state electricity regulation: the role of interest groups. J Ind Econ 54(2):201–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kühling J (2004) Sektorspezifische Regulierung in den Netzwirtschaften. C. H. Beck, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Kümpel S, Wittig A (2011) Bank- und Kapitalmarktrecht, 4th edn. Dr. Otto Schmidt, Cologne

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ladeur K-H (2005) Die Wissenschaftsfreiheit der „entfesselten Hochschule“: Umgestaltung der Hochschulen nach Ermessen des Staates? Die Öffentliche Verwaltung 58(18):753–764

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsky AB, Sidak JG (1998) Essential facilities. Stanford Law Rev 51(5):1187–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liston C (1993) Price-cap versus rate-of-return regulation. J Regul Econ 5(1):25–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lyon TP (1996) A model of sliding-scale regulation. J Regul Econ 9(3):227–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin E, Tirole J (1988) A theory of dynamic oligopoly, II: price competition, kinked demand curves, and edgeworth cycles. Econometrica 56(3):571–599

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Möllinger C (2009) Eigentumsrechtliche Entflechtung der Übertragungsnetze: Unter besonderer Berücksichtigung des 3. Binnenmarktpaketes für Energie. Peter Lang, Bern

    Google Scholar 

  • Montoya MA, Trillas F (2009) The measurement of regulator independence in practice: Latin America and the Caribbean. Int J Public Policy 4(1–2):113–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nicolaides P (1992) Competition among rules. World Competition 16(2):113–121

    Google Scholar 

  • Niemeier H-M (2002) Regulation of airports: the case of Hamburg airport—a view from the perspective of regional policy. J Air Transport Manage 8(1):37–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nocke V, Rey P (2018) Exclusive dealing and vertical integration in interlocking relationships. J Econ Theory 177:183–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Noel MD (2016) Pricing strategies and litigation risks: an economic analysis of the downstream petroleum industry. J Competition Law Econ 12(2):287–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Normann H-T (2008) Vertical integration, raising rivals’ costs and upstream collusion. Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods. Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods 2008/30, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto V (1906) Manuale di economia politica. Facsimile of the first edition published in Milan. Schäffer-Poeschel, Stuttgart 1992

    Google Scholar 

  • Pint EM (1992) Price-cap versus rate-of-return regulation in a stochastic-cost model. Rand J Econ 23(4):564–578

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pollitt M (2008) The arguments for and against ownership unbundling of energy transmission networks. Energy Policy 36(2):704–713

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pünder H (2006) Zertifizierung und Akkreditierung: private Qualitätskontrolle unter staatlicher Gewährleistungsverantwortung. Zeitschrift für das gesamte Handelsrecht und Wirtschaftsrecht 170:567–599

    Google Scholar 

  • Rey P, Stiglitz J (1988) Vertical restraints and producers’ competition. NBER working paper series no. 2601. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rieck C (2007) Spieltheorie: eine Einführung, 7th edn. Rieck, Eschborn

    Google Scholar 

  • Riedel D (2012) Eigentum, Enteignung und das Wohl der Allgemeinheit: Zur Ausgestaltungsgarantie der Eigentumsgewährleistung, zum Enteignungsbegriff und zur Gemeinwohlbindung der Enteignung. Duncker & Humblot, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Riordan MH (1998) Anticompetitive vertical integration by a dominant firm. Am Econ Rev 88(5):1232–1248

    Google Scholar 

  • Riordan MH, Salop SC (1995) Evaluating vertical mergers—a post Chicago approach. Antitrust Law J 63(2):513–568

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson J (1934) What is perfect competition? Q J Econ 49(1):104–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rockholz A (2001) Organisationsformen in der privaten Abfallwirtschaft. Zeitschrift für Umwelt- und Technikrecht 56

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutkowsky S (1998) Abfallpolitik in der Kreislaufwirtschaft. Erich Schmidt, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Säcker FJ (2009) Die wettbewerbsorientierte Anreizregulierung von Netzwirtschaften. Netzwirtschaften & Recht 6(2):78–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Salinger MA (1988) Vertical mergers and market foreclosure. Q J Econ 103(2):345–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee R (1989) Good regulatory regimes. Rand J Econ 20(3):417–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt-Assmann E (1993) Die Wissenschaftsfreiheit nach Art. 5 Abs. 3 GG als Organisationsgrundsatz. In: Bull HP, Seewald O, Becker B (eds.) Festschrift Thieme: Zum 70. Geburtstag. Carl Heymanns, Cologne, pp 697–711

    Google Scholar 

  • Scholtka B (2005) Das neue Energiewirtschaftsgesetz. Neue Juristische Wochenschrift 2005(34):2421–2425

    Google Scholar 

  • Semigran HL, Gourevitch R, Sinaiko AD, Cowling D, Mehrotra A (2017) Patients’ views on price shopping and price transparency. Am J Managed Care 23(6):E186–E192

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer G (1991) Slotting allowances and resale price maintenance: a comparison of facilitating practices. RAND J Econ 22(1):120–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sherman R (1977) Financial aspects of rate-of-return regulation. South Econ J 44(2):240–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sidak JG (2008) Abolishing the price squeeze as a theory of antitrust liability. J Competition Law Econ 4(2):279–309

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegwarth Meyer C, Wang Y (2011) Determining the competitive effects of vertical integration in mergers. Econ Committee Newsl 11(1):7–11

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith W (1997) Utility regulators: the independence debate, public policy for the private sector. Note no. 127. World Bank Group

    Google Scholar 

  • Solomon E (1970) Alternative rate of return concepts and their implications for utility regulation. Bell J Econ Manage Sci 1(1):65–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soma JT, Forkner DA, Jumps BP (1998) The essential facilities doctrine in the deregulated telecommunications industry. Berkeley Technol Law J 13(2):565–614

    Google Scholar 

  • Spann RM (1974) Rate of return regulation and efficiency in production: an empirical test of the Averch-Johnson thesis. Bell J Econ Manage Sci 5(1):38–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spengler JJ (1950) Vertical integration and antitrust policy. J Polit Econ 58(4):347–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahler F, Upmann T (2008) Market entry regulation and international competition. Rev Int Econ 16(4):611–626

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steiner F (2000) Regulation, industry structure, and performance in the electricity supply industry. OECD working papers. ECO/WKP(2000)11. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern J (1997) What makes an independent regulator independent? Lond Bus Sch Rev 8(2):67–74

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler GJ (1957) Perfect competition, historically contemplated. J Polit Econ 65(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storr S (2006) Soll das Recht der Regulierungsverwaltung übergreifend geregelt werden? Deutsches Verwaltungsblatt 121(16):1017–1026

    Google Scholar 

  • Taggart RA (1981) Rate-of-return regulation and utility capital structure decisions. J Finance 36(2):383–393

    Google Scholar 

  • van Aken A (2004) Vom Nutzen der ökonomischen Theorie für das öffentliche Recht: Methode und Anwendungsmöglichkeiten. In: Bungenberg M, Danz S, Heinrich H, Hünemörder O, Schmidt C, Schroeder R, Sichert A, Unroth F (eds) Recht und Ökonomik: 44. Assistententagung Öffentliches Recht Jena 2004. C. H. Beck, Munich, pp 1–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Voßkuhle A (2003) Beteiligung Privater an der Wahrnehmung öffentlicher Aufgaben und staatlicher Verantwortung. Veröffentlichungen der Vereinigung Deutscher Staatsrechtslehrer (VVDStRL) 62:266–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson R (1998) EU attempts to tackle parallel pricing of drugs. BMJ 316(7147):1769

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wieland J (1995) Der Wandel von Verwaltungsaufgaben als Folge der Postprivatisierung. Die Verwaltung 28(3):315–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Wollenschläger F (2013) Effektiver Rechtsschutz bei informationellen Maßnahmen der öffentlichen Hand am Beispiel der novellierten Informationsbefugnis im Lebensmittelrecht (§ 40 LFGB). Die Öffentliche Verwaltung 1:7–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamawake T, Yamoto S, Goi HC, Lee D-J (2018) Determinants of vertical integration: investment efficiency, product differentiation and firm size. Theor Econ Lett 8:1028–1043

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christoph Kleineberg .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Kleineberg, C. (2019). Theoretical Discussion of Vertical Integration and Regulation. In: Vertical Integration and Regulation. SpringerBriefs in Law. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-11358-2_2

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-11358-2_2

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-11357-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-11358-2

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics