Skip to main content

Term Structure, Market Expectations of the Short Rate, and Expected Inflation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
New Methods in Fixed Income Modeling

Part of the book series: Contributions to Management Science ((MANAGEMENT SC.))

  • 843 Accesses

Abstract

Based on the classic Gaussian dynamic term structure model \( {\mathbb{A}}_{0} \left( 3 \right) \), we rotate the model to a special representation, the so called “Companion Form Realization”, in which the state variables comprise the short rate and its related expectations. This unique feature makes the representation very useful in analyzing the response of the yield curve to the shocks in the short rate and its related expectations, and monitoring market expectations. Using the estimated model, we quantify a variety of yield responses to the changes in these important state variables; and also give an “unsurprising” pattern in which changes in state variables have little impact on the long end of the yield curve. Estimated state variables have strong explanatory power for expected inflation. Three case studies of the unconventional monetary policies are presented.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The expected inflation mentioned here is in the sense Haubrich et al. (2012) and Potter (2012). The data is publicly available at http://www.clevelandfed.org/research/data/inflation_expectations/index.cfm.

  2. 2.

    \( mV \) is chosen to be \( \left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {3\,{\text{month}}} & {2\,{\text{year}}} & {10\,{\text{year}}} \\ \end{array} } \right]^{{ \intercal }} \) in the empirical analysis.

  3. 3.

    Here is the link: https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h15/data.htm.

  4. 4.

    There are some noticeable exceptions after 2009. These discrepancies might be due to the distortion at the short end of the yield curve which has been artificially set to “zero” since 2009. This distorted nominal short rate can barely reflect the real economic fluctuation. By fitting to the whole yield curve, the model implied short end of the yield curve could be more consistent with the real economy, therefore, gives a better description of the actually nominal short rate.

  5. 5.

    Here we assume the easing is conducted via a conventional monetary policy, e.g., setting the Fed funds rate’s targets.

  6. 6.

    The downward impact on the short end would be bounded by the zero lower bound.

  7. 7.

    Since the data used to estimate the expected inflation provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland includes the TIPS data, and the 10-year TIPS are most liquid, the 10-year expected inflation is relatively free of estimation errors.

  8. 8.

    Notice that \( \Delta X_{2,t}^{1} \) and \( \Delta X_{3,t}^{1} \) are not directly included in the regressions, instead residual \( \xi_{t} \) is used in the regressions to avoid the multicollinearity issue and have meaningful interpretations for coefficients.

References

  • Andersson, M., Dillén, H., & Sellin, P. (2006). Monetary policy signaling and movements in the term structure of interest rates. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53, 1815–1855.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang, A., Bekaert, G., & Wei, M. (2008). The term structure of real rates and expected inflation. The Journal of Finance, 63, 797–849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brace, A., Gatarek, D., & Musiela, M. (1997). The market model of interest rate dynamics. Mathematical Finance, 7, 127–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooke, M., Cooper, N., & Scholtes, C. (2000). Inferring market interest rate expectations from money market rates. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, November 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collin-Dufresne, P., Goldstein, R. S., & Jones, C. S. (2008). Identification of maximal affine term structure models. The Journal of Finance, 63, 743–795.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cook, T., & Hahn, T. (1989). The effect of changes in the federal funds rate target on market interest rates in the 1970s. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24, 331–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cwik, P. F. (2005). The inverted yield curve and the economic downturn. New Perspectives on Political Economy, 1, 1–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dai, Q., & Singleton, K. J. (2000). Specification analysis of affine term structure models. Journal of Finance, 55, 1943–1978.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffee, G. R. (2002). Term premia and interest rate forecasts in affine models. The Journal of Finance, 57, 405–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellingsen, T., & Söderström, U. (2001). Monetary policy and market interest rates. The American Economic Review, 91, 1594–1607.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. A., & Lown, C. S. (1994). An indicator of future inflation extracted from the steepness of the interest rate yield curve along its entire length. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 517–530.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geiger, F. (2011). The yield curve and financial risk premia: Implications for monetary policy. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gürkaynak, R. S., Sack, B., & Swanson, E. (2005). The sensitivity of long-term interest rates to economic news: Evidence and implications for macroeconomic models. The American Economic Review, 95, 425–436.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haubrich, J., Pennacchi, G., & Ritchken, P. (2012). Inflation expectations, real rates, and risk premia: Evidence from inflation swaps. Review of Financial Studies, 25, 1588–1629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heidari, M., & Wu, L. (2009). A joint framework for consistently pricing interest rates and interest rate derivatives. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44, 517–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joyce, M., Relleen, J., & Sorensen, S. (2008). Measuring monetary policy expectations from financial market instruments. Bank of England Working Papers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koop, G., Pesaran, M. H., & Potter, S. M. (1996). Impulse response analysis in nonlinear multivariate models. Journal of Econometrics, 74, 119–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuttner, K. N. (2001). Monetary policy surprises and interest rates: Evidence from the Fed funds futures market. Journal of Monetary Economics, 47, 523–544.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, H., Ye, X., & Yu, F. (2016a). A unified HJM approach to non-markov gaussian dynamic term structure models: International evidence.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, H., Ye, X., & Yu, F. (2016b). Unifying Gaussian dynamic term structure models from an HJM perspective.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F. S. (1990a). The information in the longer maturity term structure about future inflation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105, 815–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F. S. (1990b). What does the term structure tell us about future inflation? Journal of Monetary Economics, 25, 77–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin, F. S. (2007). The economics of money, banking, and financial markets. Pearson Education.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piazzesi, M. (2005). Bond yields and the Federal Reserve. Journal of Political Economy, 113, 311–344.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Potter, S. M. (2012). Improving the measurement of inflation expectations. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Speech.

    Google Scholar 

  • Söderlind, P., & Svensson, L. (1997). New techniques to extract market expectations from financial instruments. Journal of Monetary Economics, 40, 383–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ye, X. (2015). A new approach to measuring market expectations and term premia. Journal of Fixed Income, 24, 22–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank the participants at WB/BIS Joint Fourth Public Investors’ Conference for their helpful comments. All errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiaoxia Ye .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: State Variables as the Forward Curve Characteristics

This section shows that the state variables \( Z_{t} \) and \( X_{t}^{h} \) can precisely be interpreted as some characteristics of the forward curve.

In what follows, \( \Delta t \) denotes the limit of a time interval which approaches to zero infinitely. For convenience, the notation of \( lim \) is dropped.

$$ \begin{aligned} Z_{2,t} & = \frac{{{\mathbb{E}}_{t}^{{\mathbb{Q}}} \left( {Z_{1,t + \Delta t} } \right) - Z_{1,t} }}{\Delta t} = \frac{{r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{\Delta t} + \frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {\Delta t} \right)}}{\Delta t} \approx \frac{{r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{\Delta t}, \\ Z_{3,t} & = \frac{{{\mathbb{E}}_{t}^{{\mathbb{Q}}} \left( {Z_{2,t + \Delta t} } \right) - Z_{2,t} }}{\Delta t} \\ & = \frac{{\frac{{r\left( {t,2\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right)}}{\Delta t} - \frac{{r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{\Delta t}}}{\Delta t} + \frac{{\frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {\Delta t} \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {2\Delta t} \right)}}{\Delta t} - \frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {\Delta t} \right)}}{\Delta t}}}{\Delta t} \\ & = \frac{{r\left( {t,2\Delta t} \right) - 2r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) + r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{{\left( {\Delta t} \right)^{2} }} + \frac{{ - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) + 2{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {\Delta t} \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {2\Delta t} \right)}}{{\left( {\Delta t} \right)^{2} }} \\ & \approx \frac{{r\left( {t,2\Delta t} \right) - 2r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) + r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{{\left( {\Delta t} \right)^{2} }}. \\ \end{aligned} $$

Given the parameter estimates, we have:

$$ \frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {1/12} \right)}}{1/12} = 0.016\,{\text{bp}},\; \frac{{ - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) + 2{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {1/12} \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( {1/6} \right)}}{{\left( {1/12} \right)^{2} }} = 0.337\,{\text{bp}}. $$

Comparing to the magnitudes of \( Z_{2,t} \) and \( Z_{3,t} \), these error terms are negligible. Therefore it is clear that \( Z_{2,t} \) and \( Z_{3,t} \) represent the slope and curvature of the forward curve \( r\left( {t,x} \right) \) at \( x = 0 \), respectively.

$$ \begin{aligned} X_{2,t}^{h} & = \frac{{{\mathbb{E}}_{t}^{{\mathbb{Q}}} \left( {Z_{1,t + h} } \right) - Z_{1,t} }}{h} = \frac{{r\left( {t,h} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{h} + \frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( h \right)}}{h} \approx \frac{{r\left( {t,h} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{h}, \\ X_{3,t}^{h} & = \frac{{{\mathbb{E}}_{t}^{{\mathbb{Q}}} \left( {Z_{2,t + h} } \right) - Z_{2,t} }}{h} = \frac{{{\mathbb{E}}_{t}^{{\mathbb{Q}}} \left( {\frac{{r\left( {t + h,\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t + h,0} \right)}}{\Delta t}} \right) - \frac{{r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{\Delta t}}}{h} \\ & = \frac{{\frac{{r\left( {t,\Delta t + h} \right) - r\left( {t, h} \right)}}{\Delta t} - \frac{{r\left( {t,\Delta t} \right) - r\left( {t,0} \right)}}{\Delta t}}}{h}. \\ \end{aligned} $$

As shown in Fig. 17, \( \frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( h \right)}}{h} \) (evaluated at the parameter estimates) is no more than five bps even when \( h = 10\,{\text{year}} \); for \( h < 2\,{\text{year}} \), this error is less than one bp. So, \( \frac{{{\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( 0 \right) - {\varvec{\Theta}}^{*} \left( h \right)}}{h} \) is negligible too.

Fig. 17
figure 17

Size of the error term: \( \frac{{\varvec{\varTheta}^{ *} \left( 0 \right) -\varvec{\varTheta}^{ *} \left( h \right)}}{h} \)

Therefore, \( X_{2,t}^{h} \) represents the slope between \( r\left( {t,h} \right) \) and \( r\left( {t;0} \right) \) and \( X_{3,t}^{h} \) represents the difference between slopes at \( r\left( {t,h} \right) \) and \( r\left( {t,0} \right) \).

Appendix 2: Expected Inflation and Short Rate Expectations

Although the strong linkage between the expected inflation and the slope of the yield curve or forward curve or term spreads has been mentioned in many of previous studies, see, e.g., Ang et al. (2008) and Söderlind and Svensson (1997); in this appendix, we again empirically verify the strong relationship between the long term expected inflation and short rate expectations to support the points about the expected inflation made in this article. The 10-year expected inflation data used here are estimated by the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland according to a model proposed in Haubrich et al. (2012) and Potter (2012),Footnote 7 and publicly available at https://www.clevelandfed.org/our-research/indicators-and-data/inflation-expectations.aspx In what follows, the expected inflation is denoted by \( \pi^{e} \).

Table 3 Expected inflation versus state variables regression results

Form Table 3, we can see \( \Delta X_{2,t}^{1} \)(\( \Delta X_{3,t}^{1} \)) alone can explain about 50% (26%) of the variation in \( \Delta \pi^{e} \); \( \Delta X_{2,t}^{1} \) and \( \Delta X_{3,t}^{1} \) together can explain about 60% of the variation.Footnote 8 and as expected \( \Delta \pi^{e} \) is positively related to \( \Delta X_{2,t}^{1} \), i.e., the slop of the forward curve (the coefficient in front of \( \Delta X_{2,t}^{1} \) is 0.23 with 5% significance). We can also see that the change of the short rate (\( \Delta {\text{Z}}_{1,t} \)) can barely explain any variation in \( \Delta \pi^{e} \), as the \( R^{2} \) of the regression is only 0.2% and the coefficient is insignificant. However, interestingly, it is noted that the short rate (\( Z_{1,t} \)) per se is able to explain the level of the expected inflation (\( \pi^{e} \)) up to 66%. These observations tell us that the change of the expected inflation from one period to another is primarily driven by the changes of the market expectations, and in the long run the level of the expected inflation is mainly affected by the short rate. These observations are also presented in Fig. 18.

Fig. 18
figure 18

Dynamics of expected inflation and its changes versus state variables

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Luo, J., Ye, X. (2018). Term Structure, Market Expectations of the Short Rate, and Expected Inflation. In: Mili, M., Samaniego Medina, R., di Pietro, F. (eds) New Methods in Fixed Income Modeling. Contributions to Management Science. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-95285-7_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics