Skip to main content

Institutional and Methodological Background for the Analysis of Investment Incentives

  • Chapter
Real Options and Investment Incentives
  • 1030 Accesses

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. The valuation literature on investments as well as whole companies has extensively analyzed problems under uncertainty. For textbook treatments see, e.g., Luenberger (1998), pp. 137–474; Copeland & Weston (1988), pp. 77–355; Brealey & Myers (1996), pp. 141–314; Franke & Hax (1999), pp. 287–354; Damodaran (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  2. For these and further examples of subsequent decision making see, e.g. Brealey & Myers (1996), pp. 255–264; Damodaran (2002), pp. 772–816.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Of course, there is no general rule how the distribution of investment decision rights depends on the size of a company. Even in some very large divisionalized companies, approval of major investment decisions by the board of directors is required. This can be seen as a mixed system of a combined central and decentral decision-making, which is quite common in corporate practice. See Stanley & Block (1984); Petty, et al. (1975).

    Google Scholar 

  4. See Magee (1964); Wilson (1969); Laux (1971); Hax & Laux (1972).

    Google Scholar 

  5. This idea has been expressed in Myers (1977) and relies on methods that have initially been developed and used for the valuation of financial options (Black & Scholes (1973); Merton (1973)). For an extensive review of this literature see Dixit & Pindyck (1994); Trigeorgis (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  6. For comprehensive reviews of different aspects of this literature see, e.g., Lambert (2001); Antle & Fellingham (1997); Gibbons (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  7. See Rogerson (1997) and Reichelstein (1997). Dutta & Reichelstein (2002a) summarize results of this literature for a variety of business transactions.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See, e.g., the models by Rogerson (1997); Reichelstein (1997); Reichelstein (2000); Antle & Eppen (1985); Zhang (1997); Bernardo, et al. (2001); Harris & Raviv (1996); Harris & Raviv (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  9. Textbook treatments of these topics also follow this classification. The valuation problems are treated mainly in corporate finance or valuation textbooks without taking the view of decentral decision making within organizations. See, e.g., Brealey & Myers (1996); Copeland & Weston (1988); Luenberger (1998); Schmidt (1990). On the other hand, problems of decentral decision making are described mainly in textbooks on managerial accounting. Here however, more complex investment structures are completely neglected. See, e.g., Ewert & Wagenhofer (2003); Hansen & Mowen (2000); Horngren & Foster (1991); Küpper (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  10. See, e.g., Brennan & Trigeorgis (2000); Bromwich & Walker (1998); Trigeorgis (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  11. Recent work includes Antle, et al. (2000); Antle, et al. (2001); Arya & Glover (2001); Arya, et al. (2001); Arya & Glover (2002); Crasselt (2003a); Crasselt (2003b); Dutta (2001); Grenadier & Wang (2003); Mittendorf (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  12. See, e.g., Trigeorgis (1996), pp. 2–3; Amram & Kulatilaka (1999), pp. 10–11; Friedl (2000), p. 23.

    Google Scholar 

  13. See Hansen & Mowen (2000); pp. 518–519.

    Google Scholar 

  14. For a classification of possible interdependencies see Küpper (2001), pp. 32–34.

    Google Scholar 

  15. See Milgrom & Roberts (1992), pp. 546–552.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See, e.g., Baldenius & Reichelstein (2002); Baldenius, et al. (2002); Anctil & Dutta (1999); Göx (2000); Pfeiffer (2002). For an overview, see Wagenhofer (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  17. See, e.g., Küpper (2001), pp. 309–312; Hansen & Mowen (2000), pp. 516–517.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Ewert & Wagenhofer (2003), pp. 459 make an additional distinction for responsibility centers with respect to the input side by distinguishing cost centers and expense centers.

    Google Scholar 

  19. A survey by Reece & Cool (1982) yielded the result that from a sample of 620 of the largest American companies 74% have at least two investment centers. It is not entirely clear, though, if the definition of investment center in this survey was the same as in this work.

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Melumad & Reichelstein (1987). For a model analyzing this question in the context of capital investment decision rights, see Baiman & Rajan (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Additional incentive problems might arise between shareholders and central management (see, e.g., Jensen & Meckling (1976); Fama (1980); Fama & Jensen (1983)) as well as between divisional managers and the divisional employees.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See, e.g., Dutta & Reichelstein (2002b); Dutta & Reichelstein (2002c); Hofmann (2001), pp. 141–179.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Antle & Fellingham (1997) provide a comprehensive review of this literature.

    Google Scholar 

  24. See Dutta & Reichelstein (2002a); Laux (1999), pp. 285–316; Pfaff (1998); Pfeiffer (2003); Reichelstein (1997); Rogerson (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  25. See Schiller (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  26. See also Lambert (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  27. See Küpper (2001), pp. 313–406.

    Google Scholar 

  28. See, e.g., Hofmann (2001), p. 162.

    Google Scholar 

  29. See Eccles & White (1988), p. S19.

    Google Scholar 

  30. See, e.g., Copeland & Weston (1988), p. 26.

    Google Scholar 

  31. See, e.g., Zhang (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  32. See, e.g., Lorie & Savage (1955); Weingartner (1977); Brealey & Myers (1996), pp. 101–105. For a survey on external capital rationing see Matson (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  33. One of the basic result in information economics is the revelation principle, which states that any implementable allocation between a principal and an agent can also be implemented by using a direct revelation mechanism that induces the agent to tell the truth. For the revelation principle, see in particular Myerson (1979). For additional incentive problems within budgeting procedures see Hofmann (2001), pp. 54–55.

    Google Scholar 

  34. See, e.g., Jensen & Meckling (1976). An alternative but related view is that the manager has a preference for controlling a larger budget, which is sometimes referred to as the desire for empire building, see Arya, et al. (1999); Baldenius (2002); Harris & Raviv (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  35. For mechanisms for independent divisions, see, e.g., Weitzman (1976); Osband & Reichelstein (1985); Kirby, et al. (1991); Reichelstein (1992); Trauzettel (1999), pp. 193–217. The Groves-mechanism (see Groves (1973) and Groves & Loeb (1979)) can be applied for multi-divisional firms with dependencies between divisions.

    Google Scholar 

  36. See Ewert & Wagenhofer (2003), pp. 574–576.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See Gitman & Forrester Jr. (1977); Ferreira & Brooks (1988); Fremgen (1973).

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Antle & Eppen (1985); Antle & Fellingham (1990); Antle & Fellingham (1995); Antle, et al. (1999); Harris, et al. (1982); Harris & Raviv (1996); Harris & Raviv (1998); Sappington (1983). For a selective review see Antle & Fellingham (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  39. See Antle & Eppen (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  40. See Myerson (1979); Harris & Townsend (1981).

    Google Scholar 

  41. See, e.g., Fudenberg & Tirole (1992), pp 243–318; Laffont & Tirole (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  42. See also Laffont & Tirole (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  43. Poterba & Summers (1995), p. 43.

    Google Scholar 

  44. See Ross (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  45. See Gitman & Forrester Jr. (1977).

    Google Scholar 

  46. See Ferreira & Brooks (1988) and Fremgen (1973).

    Google Scholar 

  47. For a justification of this objective, see, e.g., Brealey & Myers (1996), pp. 17–27; Schmidt (1990), pp. 27–28.

    Google Scholar 

  48. See in particular the early contribution by Hart (1940).

    Google Scholar 

  49. For comprehensive treatments of this topic see Dixit & Pindyck (1994); Trigeorgis (1996); Copeland & Antikarov (2001); Hommel, et al. (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  50. General requirements for performance measures are depicted for instance in Hax (1989), pp. 163–168; Laux (1995), p. 156; Küpper (1998), pp. 527–528; Küpper (2001), pp. 227–229. Observability is discussed in detail by Riegler (2000), p. 37.

    Google Scholar 

  51. See Küpper (2001), p. 228.

    Google Scholar 

  52. For a discussion of their relative advantages see Reichelstein (2000); Wagenhofer & Riegler (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  53. For a similar differentiation see Banker & Datar (1989), p. 22.

    Google Scholar 

  54. See Holmström (1979), pp. 83–84.

    Google Scholar 

  55. For a detailed description of the informativeness principle see Budde (2000), pp. 44 et seqq.

    Google Scholar 

  56. There are a lot more than these three types of performance measures, like for instance return on investment (RoI), or cash value added (CVA). I restrict attention to the choice between these three measures, because the recent theoretical debate has largely focused on these measures, see, e.g., Pfeiffer (2003); Reichelstein (2000); Wagenhofer (2003). For an overview, see Hachmeister (2002), pp. 1388–1393; Hebertinger (2001), pp. 65–194.

    Google Scholar 

  57. This assumption is consistent with the clean surplus relation, see, Ohlson (1995); Feltham & Ohlson (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  58. This equivalence result is also known under the term Preinreich-Lücke-Theorem, see Preinreich (1937); Lücke (1955).

    Google Scholar 

  59. A survey on the theoretical literature on residual income can be found in Bromwich & Walker (1998). Practitioners are marketing residual income measures under different labels, the most prominent of which is probably Economic Value Added (see Stewart III (1991); Hostettler (1997); O’Hanlon & Peasnell (1998); Stern, et al. (2001)). A survey of capital budgeting practices of the Fortune 1000 companies indicated that 53,9% are using EVA at least sometimes, see Ryan & Ryan (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  60. For a discussion of possible reasons see Green, et al. (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  61. For a detailed criticism see Solomons (1965), pp. 134 et seqq.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See Reichelstein (1997), p. 168; Baldenius, et al. (1999), p. 59.

    Google Scholar 

  63. See Reichelstein (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  64. Stern et al. (2001), p. 21 propose to include R&D expenses in the balance sheet and amortize it “over the period of years during which these research outlays are expected to have an impact.”

    Google Scholar 

  65. See, e.g., Christensen, et al. (2002), p. 6; Egginton (1995), p. 203; Rogerson (1997), p. 785; Velthuis (2003), p. 121.

    Google Scholar 

  66. Busse von Colbe (2002), p. 6 and Küpper (2002), p. 52–53 propose the use of market values as asset base for regulated industries. For a critical discussion see Pedell (2003), p. 6–22.

    Google Scholar 

  67. See, e.g., Anthony & Govindarajan (2000), p. 256; Hilton, et al. (2000), p. 839; Horngren, et al. (1999), p. 663–664. For an early discussion see Rudolph (1986), pp. 892–898.

    Google Scholar 

  68. See, Stern et al. (2001); pp. 19–20; Horngren et al. (1999), pp. 664–666.

    Google Scholar 

  69. See Christensen et al. (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  70. A criticism of using the WACC can also be found in Velthuis (2003), pp. 123–128.

    Google Scholar 

  71. See, e.g., Bushman & Indjejikian (1993); Bushman, et al. (2000); Christensen et al. (2002); Feltham & Xie (1994); Reichelstein (1997); Dutta & Reichelstein (2002b).

    Google Scholar 

  72. See, e.g., Jensen (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  73. See Milgrom & Roberts (1992), p. 221.

    Google Scholar 

  74. See also Taggart Jr. (1987) and Kester & Taggart Jr. (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  75. See Baldenius (2002) for a model, which combines performance-based compensation with private benefits of controlling larger projects. The latter is quite similar to a desire for slack.

    Google Scholar 

  76. See, e.g., Antle & Eppen (1985); Harris & Raviv (1996); Harris & Raviv (1998); Bernardo et al. (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  77. For an overview over applications of principal-agent models in different areas of business research see Jost (2001b).

    Google Scholar 

  78. See Laffont & Martimort (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  79. See Hart & Holmström (1987); Brousseau & Glachant (2002).

    Google Scholar 

  80. See Arrow (1985), p. 38; Jost (2001a), pp. 23–31.

    Google Scholar 

  81. Antle & Fellingham (1997), p. 905, argue that “given the variety of institutions available for risk sharing (banks, insurance companies, casinos), the possibility exists that it may not be economically insightful to resolve the risk sharing problem in a capital investment setting.”

    Google Scholar 

  82. See Holmström (1979).

    Google Scholar 

  83. See Grossman & Hart (1983); Rogerson (1985); Jewitt (1988). See also Mirrlees (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  84. See Spremann (1987); Holmström & Milgrom (1987); Wagenhofer & Ewert (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  85. For a detailed general criticism of agency-theory see Meinhövel (1999), pp. 107–170.

    Google Scholar 

  86. See, e.g., Lambert (2001) pp. 77–79.

    Google Scholar 

  87. Recent papers on these issues include Indjejikian & Nanda (1999); Dutta & Reichelstein (2002c); Sliwka (2002); Christensen, et al. (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  88. Reichelstein (1997), p. 157.

    Google Scholar 

  89. See, e.g., Rogerson (1997); Reichelstein (1997); Gillenkirch & Schabel (2001); Dutta & Reichelstein (2002a).

    Google Scholar 

  90. See Holmström (1979), p. 83–84.

    Google Scholar 

  91. An example for such a reason is the need for providing operational incentives in addition to investment incentives, which can be addressed by the steepness of the compensation function. See Dutta & Reichelstein (2002b) for a formalization of this argument.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2007 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

(2007). Institutional and Methodological Background for the Analysis of Investment Incentives. In: Real Options and Investment Incentives. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-48268-0_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics