Skip to main content

If the Representative Agent is Used, Should He Be Believed? Aggregation, Welfare and the Role of Microfoundations in Quantitative Economic Policy

  • Chapter
Quantitative Economic Policy

Part of the book series: Advances in Computational Economics ((AICE,volume 20))

  • 614 Accesses

Abstract

One of the most pervasive trends in modern macroeconomics is the use of microeconomic theory to derive the behavioural equations of a macroeconomic model. This is frequently accomplished by the invocation of a single “representative agent”, whose own optimising decisions are then scaled up to represent the aggregate behaviour of all consumers in the economy. On the positive side, these strong assumptions permit the marriage of micro and macroeconomic analysis, with the behaviour of the economy at aggregate level directly explicable in terms of individual optimising behaviour. In addition, the preferences of the representative agent are often used to rank different policy outcomes. In the words of Woodford (2001):

“An important advantage of using a model founded on private-sector optimisation to analyze the consequences of alternative policy rules is that there is a natural welfare criterion in the context of such a model, provided by the preferences of private agents that are displayed in the structural relations that determine the effects of alternative policies.” This usage of microfounded models to provide a welfare-metric evaluation marks an important new step in quantitative economic policy. Previously, the task of economic theory was typically confined to the positive role of quantifying the likely effects of various policies. The normative task of ranking policy outcomes, or of specifying the “optimal policy”, was left to the policymaker, who would simply choose according to his own volition from the menu of possible outcomes given by the positive economic analysis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  • Altissimo F, Siviero S, Terlizzese D (2002) How deep are the deep parameters? Annales D’Économie et de Statistique 67/68:207–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Barreto H, Howland M (1998) The treatment of aggregation in modern economic analysis. HES Conference, Montreal

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O (1985) Debt, deficits, and finite horizons. Journal of Political Economy 93:223–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boland L (1979) A critique of Friedman’s critics. Journal of Economic Literature 17:503–502

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J, Mankiw G (1991) Consumption, income and interest rates: Reinterpreting the time series evidence. In: Blanchard O, Fischer S (eds) NBER Macroeconomics Annual. MIT Press, Harvard

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane J (1991) The sensitivity of tests of the intertemporal allocation of consumption to near-rational alternatives. American Economic Review 79:319–337

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G (1974) Excess demand functions. Journal of Mathematical Economics 1:15–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolling L, Gianelli A, Statile G (2003) The tests of time: Readings in the development of physical theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1953) The methodology of positive economics. In: Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoover K (2004) Milton Friedman’s stance: The methodology of causal realism. Mimeo, Duke University

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirman A (1992) Whom or what does the representative individual represent? Journal of Economic Perspectives 6:117–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis J (2004) Income distribution, aggregation and the macroeconomy. PhD Thesis, University of Wales, Cardiff

    Google Scholar 

  • Mäki U (2003) The methodology of positive economics (1953) does not give us the methodology of positive economics. Journal of Economic Methodology 10:495–505

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mäki U (eds) (2005) The methodology of positive economics. Milton Friedman’s essay fifty years later. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas R (1987) Models of business cycles. Basil Blackwell, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantel R (1974) On the characterization of aggregate excess demand. Journal of Economic Theory 7:348–353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer T (1993) Friedman’s methodology of positive economics: A soft reading. Economic Inquiry 31:213–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave A (1981) Unrealistic assumptions in economic theory: The F-twist untwisted. Kyklos 34:377–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran M, Pierse RG, Kumar M (1991) Econometric analysis of aggregation in the context of linear prediction models. Econometrica 57:861–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1963) Discussion. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 53:231–236

    Google Scholar 

  • Schultz G (1936) Secular trends and cyclical behaviour of income distribution in the US, 1944–65. In: Soltow L (eds.) Six papers on the size distribution of wealth and income. National Bureau of Economic Research, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein H (1973) Do Walras’ identity and continuity characterize the class of community excess demand functions? Journal of Economic Theory 6:345–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sonnenschein H (1974) Excess demand functions. Econometrica 40:549–563

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Theil H (1971) Principles of econometrics. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford R (2001) Inflation stabilization and welfare. NBER Working Paper No 223, National Bureau of Economic Research

    Google Scholar 

  • Yaari M (1965) Uncertain lifetime, life insurance, and the theory of the consumer. The Review of Economic Studies 32:137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2008 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Lewis, J. (2008). If the Representative Agent is Used, Should He Be Believed? Aggregation, Welfare and the Role of Microfoundations in Quantitative Economic Policy. In: Neck, R., Richter, C., Mooslechner, P. (eds) Quantitative Economic Policy. Advances in Computational Economics, vol 20. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-74684-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics